Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-l7hp2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T23:02:17.516Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

A Review of Alternative Expectations Regimes in Commodity Markets: Specification, Estimation, and Hypothesis Testing Using Structural Models

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 September 2016

Diana M. Burton
Affiliation:
Department of Forest Science
H. Alan Love
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural Economics, Texas A&M University
Get access

Abstract

Price expectations play a critical role in commodity markets where producers must make input decisions well before output is realized. This paper brings together alternative expectations regimes, their estimation, and hypothesis tests for use in structural commodity models to determine their use by commodity producers. Extrapolative mechanisms and rational expectations are considered under risk neutrality and risk aversion. The assumptions implicit in the use of aggregate data in these models are made explicit. Structural models using individual survey data are discussed. While Muth's rational expectations hypothesis has found widespread acceptance in the macroeconomic literature, empirical results from industry studies indicate that commodity producers may have heterogeneous price expectations, with no single expectations hypothesis dominating. This is not surprising given that different producers possess different information and have different costs associated with information collection and processing.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © 1996 Northeastern Agricultural and Resource Economics Association 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abel, A., and Mishkin, F.S. 1983. “An Integrated View of Tests of Rationality, Market Efficiency and Short-Run Neutrality of Monetary Policy.Journal of Monetary Economics 11: 324.Google Scholar
Almon, S. 1965. “The Distributed Lag between Capital Appropriations and Net Expenditures.Econometrica 33: 178–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Antonovitz, F., and Green, R. 1990. “Alternative Estimates of Fed Beef Supply Response to Risk.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 72: 475–87.Google Scholar
Antonovitz, F., and Roe, T. 1984. “The Value of a Rational Expectations Forecast in a Risky Market: A Theoretical and Empirical Approach.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 66: 717–23.Google Scholar
Antonovitz, F., and Roe, T. 1986. “A Theoretical and Empirical Approach to the Value of the Information in Risky Markets.Review of Economics and Statistics 68: 105–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aradhyula, S.V., and Holt, M.T. 1989. “Risk Behavior and Rational Expectations in the U.S. Broiler Market.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 71: 892902.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K.J. 1978. “The Future and Present in Economic Life.Economic Inquiry 16: 157–69.Google Scholar
Askari, H., and Cummings, J.T. 1977. “Estimating Agricultural Supply Response with the Nerlove Model: A Survey.International Economic Review 18: 257–92.Google Scholar
Behrman, J.R. 1968. Supply Response in Underdeveloped Agriculture: A Case Study of Four Major Annual Crops in Thailand 1937–1963. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co.Google Scholar
Bessler, D.A. 1980. “Aggregated Personalistic Beliefs on Yields of Selected Crops Estimated Using ARIMA Processes.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 62: 666–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bessler, D.A. 1982. “Adaptive Expectations, the Exponentially Weighted Forecast, and Optimal Statistical Predictors: A Revisit.Agricultural Economics Research 34: 1623.Google Scholar
Bollerslev, T. 1986. “Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heterskedasticity.Journal of Econometrics 31: 307–27.Google Scholar
Brorsen, B.W., Chavas, J.-P., and Grant, W. 1987. “A Market Equilibrium Analysis of the Impact of Risk on the U.S. Rice Industry.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 69: 731–39.Google Scholar
Cagan, P. 1956. “The Monetary Dynamics of Hyperinflation.” In Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money, ed. Friedman, M., pp. 23117. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Carlson, J.A. 1977. “A Study of Price Forecasts.Annals of Economic and Social Measurement 6: 2756.Google Scholar
Chavas, J.-P., Pope, R.D., and Kao, R.S. 1983. “Analysis of the Role of Futures Prices, Cash Prices and Government Programs in Acreage Response.Western Journal of Agricultural Economics 8: 2733.Google Scholar
Colling, P.L., Irwin, S.H., and Zulauf, C.R. 1992. “Weak and Strong Rationality Tests of Market Analysts' Expectations of USDA Hogs and Pigs Reports.Review of Agricultural Economics 14: 263–70.Google Scholar
Davidson, R., and MacKinnon, R. 1981. “Several Tests for Model Specification in the Presence of Alternative Hypotheses.Econometrica 49: 781–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doran, H.E. 1988. “Specification Tests for the Partial Adjustment and Adaptive Expectations Models.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 70: 713–23.Google Scholar
Eales, J.S., Engel, B.K., Hauser, R.J., and Thompson, S.R. 1990. “Grain Price Expectaions of Illinois Farmers and Grain Merchandisers.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 72: 701–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckstein, Z. 1984. “A Rational Expectations Model of Agricultural Supply.Journal of Political Economy 92: 1–19.Google Scholar
Engsted, T. 1991. “A Note on the Rationality of Survey Inflation Expectations in the United Kingdom.Applied Economics 23: 1269–76.Google Scholar
Engle, R. 1982. “Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity with Estimates of the Variance of United Kingdom Inflation.Econometrica 50: 9871007.Google Scholar
Evans, G.W., and Ramey, G. 1992. “Expectation Calculation and Macroeconomic Dynamics.American Economic Review 82: 207–24.Google Scholar
Farrar, D.E. 1962. The Investment Decision under Uncertainty. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Fair, R.C., and Taylor, J.B. 1983. “Solution and Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Dynamic Nonlinear Rational Expectations Models.Econometrica 51: 1169–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feige, E.L., and Pearce, D.K. 1976. “Economically Rational Expectations: Are Innovations in the Rate of Inflation Independent of Innovations in Measures of Monetary and Fiscal Policy?Journal of Political Economy 84: 499522.Google Scholar
Fischer, A.M. 1989. “Practitioner's Corner: Unit Roots and Survey Data.Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 51: 451–63.Google Scholar
Frankel, J.A., and Froot, K.A. 1987. “Using Survey Data to Test Standard Propositions Regarding Exchange Rate Expectations.American Economic Review 77: 133–53.Google Scholar
Freund, R.J. 1956. “Introduction of Risk into a Programming Model.Econometrica 24: 253–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, B.M. 1978. “Stability and Rationality in Models of Hyperinflation.International Economic Review 19: 4564.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, B.M. 1980. “Survey Evidence on the ‘Rationality’ of Interest Rate Expectations.Journal of Monetary Economics 6: 453–66.Google Scholar
Gardner, B.L. 1976. “Futures Prices in Supply Analysis.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 57: 8184.Google Scholar
Gauger, J. 1989. “The Generated Regression Correction: Impacts upon Inferences in Hypothesis Testing.Journal of Macroeconomics 11: 383–95.Google Scholar
Giles, D.E.A., Goss, B.A., and Chin, O.P.L. 1985. “Intertemporal Allocation in the Corn and Soybean Markets with Rational Expectations.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 67: 749–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodfriend, M. 1992. “Information-Aggregation Bias.American Economic Review 82: 508–19.Google Scholar
Goodwin, T.H., and Sheffrin, S.M. 1982. “Testing the Rational Expectations Hypothesis in an Agricultural Market.Review of Economics and Statistics 64: 658–67.Google Scholar
Griliches, Z. 1967. “Distributed Lags: A Survey.Econometrica 35: 1649.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, S.J. and Stiglitz, J.E. 1976. “Information and Competitive Price Systems.American Economic Review 66: 246–52.Google Scholar
Hansen, L.P. 1982. “Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators.Econometrica 50: 1029–54.Google Scholar
Hicks, J.R. 1939. Value and Capital. London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hildreth, C.G. 1954. “Point Estimates of Ordinates of Concave Functions.Journal of the American Statistical Association 49: 598619.Google Scholar
Hoffman, D.L. 1987. “Two-Step Generalized Least Squares Estimators in Multi-Equation Generated Regressor Models.Review of Economics and Statistics 69: 336–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, D.L., and Schmidt, P. 1981. “Testing the Restrictions Implied by the Rational Expectations Hypothesis.Journal of Econometrics 15: 265–87.Google Scholar
Holden, K., Peel, D.A., and Thompson, J.L. 1985. Expectations: Theory and Evidence. New York: St. Martin's Press.Google Scholar
Holt, M.T. 1992. “A Multimarket Bounded Price Variation Model under Rational Expectations: Corn and Soybeans in the United States.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 74: 1020.Google Scholar
Holt, M.T. 1993. “Risk Response in the Beef Marketing Channel: A Multivariate Generalized ARCH-M Approach.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 75: 559–71.Google Scholar
Holt, M.T., and Aradhyula, S.V. 1990. “Price Risk in Supply Equations: An Application of GARCH Time-Series Models to the U.S. Broiler Market.Southern Economic Journal 57: 230–42.Google Scholar
Holt, M.T., and Johnson, S.R. 1989. “Bounded Price Variation and Rational Expectations in an Endogenous Switching Model of the US Corn Market.Review of Economics and Statistics 71: 605–13.Google Scholar
Huntzinger, R.L. 1979. “Market Analysis with Rational Expectations.Journal of Econometrics 10: 127–45.Google Scholar
Hurt, C.A., and Garcia, P. 1982. “The Impact of Price Risk on Sow Farrowings, 1967-78.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 64: 565–68.Google Scholar
Jacobs, R.L., and Jones, R.A. 1980. “Price Expectations in the United States: 1947-75.American Economic Review 70: 269–77.Google Scholar
Johnston, J. 1984. Econometric Methods. 3rd ed. New York: McGraw-Hill. Google Scholar
Jorgenson, D.W. 1966. “Rational Distributed Lag Functions.Econometrica 34: 135–49.Google Scholar
Judge, G.G., Griffiths, W.E., Hill, R.C., Lutkepohl, H., andGoogle Scholar
Lee, T.-C. 1985. The Theory and Practice of Econometrics. 2nd ed. New York: John Wiley & Sons. Google Scholar
Just, R.E. 1974. “An Investigation of the Importance of Risk in Farmers' Decisions.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 56: 1425.Google Scholar
Just, R.E. 1977. “Estimation of an Adaptive Expectations Model.International Economic Review 18: 629–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keane, M.P., and Runkle, D.E. 1990. “Testing the Rationality of Price Forecasts: New Evidence from Panel Data.American Economic Review 80: 714–35.Google Scholar
Knobl, A. 1974. “Price Expectations and Actual Behavior in Germany.International Monetary Fund Staff Papers 21: 83100.Google Scholar
Koyck, L.M. 1954. Distributed Lags and Investment Analysis. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Co.Google Scholar
Lovell, M.C. 1986. “Tests of the Rational Expectations Hypothesis.American Economic Review 76: 110–24.Google Scholar
Maddala, G.S. 1983. “Methods for Estimation for Models of Markets with Bounded Price Variation.International Economic Review 24: 361–87.Google Scholar
Maddala, G., and Rao, A. 1971. “Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Solow's and Jorgenson's Distributed Lag Models.Review of Economics and Statistics 53: 8088.Google Scholar
McCallum, B.T. 1976. “Rational Expectations and the Natural Rate Hypothesis: Some Consistent Estimates.Econometrica 44: 4352.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCallum, B.T. 1979. “Topics Concerning the Formulation, Estimation and Use of Macroeconomic Models with Rational Expectations.Proceedings of the Business and Economic Statistics Section, American Statistical Association, pp. 6572.Google Scholar
McElroy, M.B. 1987. “Additive General Error Models for Production, Cost, and Derived Demand or Share Systems.Journal of Political Economy 95: 737–57.Google Scholar
Mizon, G.E., and Richard, J.F. 1986. “The Encompassing Principle and Its Application to Testing Non-Nested Hypotheses.Econometrica 54: 657–78.Google Scholar
Mullineaux, D.J. 1978. “On Testing for Rationality: Another Look at the Livingston Price Expectations Data.Journal of Political Economy 86: 329–36.Google Scholar
Muth, J.F. 1960. “Optimal Properties of Exponentially Weighted Forecasts.Journal of the American Statistical Association 55: 299305.Google Scholar
Muth, J.F. 1961. “Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements.Econometrica 29: 315–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, R.G. and Bessler, D.A. 1992. “Quasi-rational Expectations: Experimental Evidence.Journal of Forecasting 11: 141–56.Google Scholar
Nerlove, M. 1958. The Dynamics of Supply: Estimation of Farmer's Response to Price. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Nerlove, M. 1967. “Distributed Lags and Unobserved Components in Economic Time Series.Ten Economic Studies in the Tradition of Irving Fisher, ed. Fellner, W., pp. 127–69. New York: John Wiley & Sons. Google Scholar
Nerlove, M. 1972. “Lags in Economic Behavior.Econometrica 51: 221–51.Google Scholar
Nerlove, M. 1983. “Expectation, Plans, and Realizations in Theory and Practice.Econometrica 51: 1251–79.Google Scholar
Nerlove, M., Grether, D.M., and Cavalho, J.L. 1979. Analysis of Economic Time Series. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Orazem, P., and Miranowski, J. 1986. “An Indirect Test for the Specification of Expectation Regimes.Review of Economics and Statistics 68: 603–9.Google Scholar
Pagan, A. 1984. “Econometric Issues in the Analysis of Regressions with Generated Regressors.International Economic Review 25: 221–47.Google Scholar
Pagan, A. and Ullah, A. 1988. “The Econometric Analysis of Models with Risk Terms.Journal of Applied Econometrics 3: 87105.Google Scholar
Pesando, J.E. 1975. “A Note on the Rationality of the Livingston Price Expectations.Journal of Political Economy 83: 849–58.Google Scholar
Pesaran, M.H. 1987. The Limits to Rational Expectations. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Phillip, D.O., and Abalu, G.O.I. 1987. “Price Expectations Formation and Revision in the Nerlovian Framework with Application to Nigerian Farmers.Journal of Agricultural Economics 38: 491–95.Google Scholar
Pierce, D.A. 1975. “Forecasting in Dynamic Models with Stochastic Regressors.Journal of Econometrics 3: 349–74.Google Scholar
Pollak, R.A., and Wales, T.J. 1991. “The Likelihood Dominance Criteria: A New Approach to Model Selection.Journal of Econometrics 47: 227–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pope, R.D. 1978. “The Expected Utility Hypothesis and Demand-Supply Restrictions.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 60: 619–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Revankar, N.S. 1980. “Testing the Rational Expectations Hypothesis.Econometrica 48: 1347–63.Google Scholar
Roe, T. and Antonovitz, F. 1985. “A Producer's Willingness to Pay for Information under Price Uncertainty: Theory and Application.Southern Economic Journal 52: 382–91.Google Scholar
Runkel, D.E. 1991. “Are Farrowing Intentions Rational Forecasts?American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73: 594600.Google Scholar
Sandmo, A. 1971. “On the Theory of the Competitive Firm under Price Uncertainty.American Economic Review 61: 6573.Google Scholar
Sargent, T.J. 1982. “Beyond Demand and Supply Curves in Macroeconomics.American Economic Review Proceedings 72: 382–89.Google Scholar
Schmidt, P., and Waud, R.N. 1973. “The Almon Lag Technique and the Monetary Versus Fiscal Policy Debate.Journal of the American Statistical Association 68: 1119.Google Scholar
Schroeter, J., and Azzam, A. 1991. “Marketing Margins, Market Power, and Price Uncertainty.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73: 990–99.Google Scholar
Seale, J.L., and Shonkwiler, J.S. 1987. “Rationality, Price Risk, and Response.Southern Journal of Agricultural Economics 19: 111–18.Google Scholar
Shideed, K.H., and White, F.C. 1989. “Alternative Forms of Price Expectations in Supply Analysis for U.S. Corn and Soybeans Acreages.Western Journal of Agricultural Economics 14: 281–92.Google Scholar
Shonkwiler, J.S., and Emerson, R.D. 1982. “Imports and the Supply of Winter Tomatoes: An Application of Rational Expectations.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 64: 634–41.Google Scholar
Shonkwiler, J.S., and Hinckley, S. 1985. “A Generalized Supply Response/Factor Demand Model and Its Application to the Feeder Cattle Market.Western Journal of Agricultural Economics 10: 245–53.Google Scholar
Shonkwiler, J.S., and Maddala, G.S. 1985. “Modeling Expectations of Bounded Prices: An Application to the Market for Com.Review of Economics and Statistics 67: 697702.Google Scholar
Taylor, J.B. 1979. “Estimation and Control of a Macroeconomic Model with Rational Expectations.Econometrica 47: 1267–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tegene, A., Huffman, W.E., and Miranowski, J.A. 1988. “Dynamic Corn Supply Functions: A Model with Explicit Optimization.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 70: 103–11.Google Scholar
Traill, B. 1978. “Risk Variables in Econometric Supply Response.Journal of Agricultural Economics 24: 5361.Google Scholar
Turnovsky, S.J. 1970. “Empirical Evidence on the Formation of Price Expectations.Journal of the American Statistical Association 65: 1441–54.Google Scholar
Wallis, K.F. 1980. “Econometric Implications of the Rational Expectations Hypothesis.Econometrica 48: 4971.Google Scholar
Wegge, L.L., and Feldman, M., 1983. “Identifiability Criteria for Muth-Rational Expectations Models.Journal of Econometrics 21: 245–54.Google Scholar
Wickens, M.R. 1982. “The Efficient Estimation of Econometric Models with Rational Expectations.Review of Economic Studies 49: 5567.Google Scholar
Zarnowitz, V. 1992. Business Cycles: Theory, History, Indicators and Forecasting. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Zeldes, S. 1989. “Consumption and Liquidity Constraints: An Empirical Investigation.Journal of Political Economy 97: 305-46.Google Scholar