Article contents
The Structured Dependence of the Elderly as a Recent Development: Some Sceptical Historical Thoughts
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 14 November 2008
Abstract
There has recently emerged in the writings of those who have adopted an overtly ‘radical’ approach to social work and the welfare state, a coherent interpretation of how the status of older persons is lowered in the course of the development of industrial capitalism. The focus in these recent writings is on the social creation of dependent status and the structural determinants of the competitive relationship between elderly individuals and younger adults in the labour market. This paper reviews the arguments of this school of thought arguing firstly that it fails to take sufficient account of the longer term population history of England, suggesting that the contrast between the middle and later twentieth century and the nineteenth century is apparently so marked largely because of the atypicality of the latter period when high fertility and rapid demographic growth produced an historical minimum for the proportion of the elderly in the total population. A second failure in this recent radical or marxist research is that it also does not take sufficient account of the kinship system in north west Europe which appears to have created a situation of structured dependency of the elderly on the collectivity irrespective of the specific mode of production. Pre-industrial north west Europeans exhibited a striking contrast in this particular cultural trait with many, indeed most non-industrial societies outside Western Europe or regions populated by emmigrants from that area.
- Type
- Research Article
- Information
- Copyright
- Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1984
References
NOTES
1 See for example, Gough, I., The Political Economy of the Welfare State, London, Macmillan, 1979;CrossRefGoogle ScholarPhillipson, C., Capitalism and the Construction of Old Age, London, Macmillan, 1982;CrossRefGoogle ScholarTownsend, P., ‘The structured dependency of the elderly: a creation of social policy in the twentieth century’, Ageing and Society, I (1981)Google Scholar, and Walker, A., ‘Towards a Political Economy of Old Age’, Ageing and Society, I (1981).Google Scholar
2 Townsend, P., ‘The structured dependency of the elderly’, p. 5.Google Scholar
3 Gough, I., The Political Economy of the Welfare State, pp. 44–5.Google Scholar
4 Phillipson, C., Capitalism and the Construction of Old Age, especially chapters 3 and 5.Google Scholar
5 Phillipson, , op. cit. pp. 78–79.Google Scholar
6 For example, Burgess, E., Aging in Western Societies, Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 1960Google Scholar, and Cowgill, D. and Holmes, L. D., Ageing and Modernization, New York, Appleton-Century-Crofts, 1972.Google Scholar
7 Phillipson, , op. cit. p. 153.Google Scholar
8 See especially Fischer, D. H., Growing Old in America, New York, Oxford University Press, 1977;Google ScholarAchenbaum, W. A., Old Age in the New Land, Baltimore and London, Johns Hopkins University Press, 1978.Google Scholar See also the exchange between Stone, L., ‘Walking over grandma’, New York Review of Books, 24, 8 (1977), p. 10Google Scholar, and Fischer, D. H., ‘Growing old: an exchange’, New York Review of Books, 24, 14 (1977), p. 48.Google Scholar A more cautious treatment of the history of old age in North America is to be found in Haber, C., Beyond Sixty-Five: The Dilemma of Old Age in America's Past, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1983.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
9 Phillipson, , op. cit. p. 38.Google Scholar
10 Ibid. p. 159.
11 Ibid. p. 158.
12 The evidence is to be found in Wrigley, E. A. and Schofield, R. S., The population History of England 1541–1871: A Reconstruction, London, Edward Arnold, 1981.Google Scholar
13 See the population totals in Wrigley, E. A. and Schofield, R. S., The Population History of England, pp. 208–209;Google ScholarWrigley, E. A., ‘Urban growth in early modern England’, Journal of Interdisciplinary History (forthcoming);Google ScholarTurner, D., ‘A lost seventeenth century demographic crisis’, Local Population Studies 21 (1978).Google Scholar It may be noticed that individual places, especially cities, could have well over 10% of their populations above 60 at dates earlier than industrialisation, in Italy as early as the fifteenth century, in Japan and in Iceland; see Laslett, P., Family Life and Illicit Love in Earlier Generations, Cambridge, 1977, table 5.2.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
14 There are good reasons for believing that marriage was late and economically responsive in medieval England. See Smith, R. M., ‘Some reflections on the evidence for the origins of the “European Marriage Pattern” in England’, in Harris, C., editor, Sociology of the Family (Sociological Review Monograph, 28), 1979Google Scholar, and Smith, R. M., ‘Hypothèses sur la nuptialité en Angleterre aux XIIIe–XIVe siècles’, Annales, Économies Sociétés Civilisations 38 (1983).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
15 See Wrigley, and Schofield, , op. cit. 1981, pp. 528–529.Google Scholar
16 Anderson, M., ‘What is new about the modern family: an historical perspective’, in Office of Populations Censuses and Surveys Occasional Paper 31 British Society for Population Studies Conference on The Family, Exeter, 1983, p. 10.Google Scholar
17 For the place of servants in the family system of early modern England see Kussmaul, A., Servants in Husbandry in Early Modern England, Cambridge University Press, 1981.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
18 For ages of women at last birth in England from 1600–1799 see Wrigley, E. A., and Schofield, R. S., ‘English population history from family reconstruction: summary results 1600–1799’, Population Studies 37 (1983), p. 174.Google Scholar
19 Anderson, M., ‘What is new about the modern family’, p. 8.Google Scholar
20 Laslett, P., Family Life and Illicit Love, p. 204; table 5.12.Google Scholar
21 Le Bras, H. ‘Evolution des liens de famille au cours de l'existence. Unecomparaison entre la France actuelle et la France du XVIIIe siècles’, in thé Proceedings of VIIe Colloque National de Démographie, Strasbourg, 5–7 mai 1982, Les Ages de la Vie 1, Paris, Presses Universitaires de France, 1982.Google Scholar The assumptions made were that in eighteenth-century France expectation of life at birth was 30 for both sexes, that 50% of women were still unmarried at age 25, and that 15% of women never married, that husbands were 6 years older than their wives at marriage and that completed family sizes were 5.75. The contemporary French population was assumed to have an expectation of life at birth of 73 years, 50% of women were married by 23, 7% of women never married, the age gap between spouses was three years and that completed family size was 2.2 births per mother. James Smith has assumed in simulating the eighteenth-century English population e 0s of 36 years for males and 38 years for females, a total marital fertility rate of 8.1, a Net Reproduction Rate of 1.2, an intrinsic growth rate of 1.0%, female and male ages at first marriage of 25 and 28 years respectively. For the present-day English population the following assumptions were made: e 0a for women and men are 70 and 75 respectively, a NRR of 0.9, an intrinsic growth rate of –0.2% and ages at first marriage of 23 for women and 25 for men.
22 Laslett, P., Family Life and Illicit Love, pp. 204–205.Google Scholar
23 Thane, P., ‘The history of provision for the elderly to 1929’, in Jerome, D., Ageing in Modern Society, London, Groom Helm, 1983, p. 191Google Scholar, and Quadagno, J., Aging in Early Industrial Society: Work, Family and Social Policy in Nineteenth Century England, London and New York, Academic Press, 1982, p. 92.Google Scholar
24 Thane, P., ‘The history of the provision for the elderly’, p. 191.Google Scholar
25 Anderson, M., ‘The impact on the family relationships of the elderly of changes since Victorian times in governmental income-maintenance’ in Shanas, E., and Sussman, M., editors Family Bureaucracy and The Elderly, Durham, N. C., Duke University Press, 1977, p. 36.Google Scholar
26 Ibid. p. 56.
27 The classic work is of course Thompson, E. P., ‘The moral economy of the English crowd in the eighteenth century’, Past and Present 50 (1971);CrossRefGoogle Scholar see also, Walter, J., and Wrightson, K., ‘Dearth and the social order in early modern England’, Past and Present, 71, 1976CrossRefGoogle Scholar and especially Walter, J., ‘A rising of the people? The Oxfordshire rising and the crisis of the 1590s', Past and Present (forthcoming).Google Scholar
28 A stimulating discussion of this literature and its context is to be found in Wales, T. C., ‘Poverty and poor relief in early modern England: a reassessment’ (unpublished manuscript).Google Scholar
29 Otter, W., ‘Memoir of Robert Malthus (1816)’ (published with the posthumous 2nd edn., of Malthus's Principles of Political Economy, London, 1836), pp. xxi–xxii.Google Scholar
30 Tierney, B., Medieval Poor Law: A Sketch of Canonical Theory and Its Application in England, Berkeley and Los Angeles, University of California Press, 1959, p. 6.Google Scholar
31 See especially, Tierney, B., ‘The decretists and the “deserving poor”’, Comparative Studies in Society and History I, (1958–1959).Google Scholar
32 Such as Macfarlane, A., Witchcraft in Tudor and Stuart England; a Regional and Comparative Study, London, Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1977.Google Scholar
33 See especially Thomson, D., “I am not my father's keeper”. Families and the elderly in nineteenth century England’, Law and History Review 3 (1984).Google Scholar
34 Walford, C., Gilds, Their Origin, Constitution, Objects and Later History, London, 1879;Google ScholarWestlake, H. F., The Parish Gilds of Medieval England, London, 1919Google Scholar, and more recently, Scarisbrick, J., The Reformation and the English People, Oxford, Basil Blackwell, 1984.Google Scholar
35 Poor relief to elderly widows of approximately £3.00 per annum in relation to the annual income of £15 for labouring families was not uncommon in the late seventeenth century. See Wales, T. C., ‘Poverty, poor relief and the life-cycle; some evidence from seventeenth century Norfolk’, in Smith, R. M., editor Land, Kinship and Life-cycle, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1984.Google Scholar
36 Anderson, M., ‘The impact on the family relationships of the elderly’, p. 36.Google Scholar
37 Cain, M., ‘Fertility as an adjustment to risk’, Population and Development Review, 9 (1983), p. 693.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
38 See Page, F. M., ‘The customary Poor Law of three Cambridgeshire manors’, Cambridge Historical Journal 3 (1930);CrossRefGoogle ScholarHomans, G. C., English Villagers of the Thirteenth Century, Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University Press, 1941CrossRefGoogle Scholar, and Clark, E., ‘Some aspects of social security in Medieval England’, Journal of Family History, 7 (1982).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
39 See Wales, T. C., ‘Poverty, poor relief and the life-cycle’, and Newman Brown, W., ‘The receipt of poor relief and family situation in Aldenham, Hertfordshire 1630–1690’ in Smith, R. M., editor, Land, Kinship and Life-cycle, Cambridge University Press, 1984;Google ScholarSlack, P., ‘Poverty and politics in Salisbury 1597–1666’, in Clark, P., and Slack, P., editors, Crisis and Order in English Towns 1500–1700, London 1972;Google ScholarBeier, A. L., ‘The social problems of an Elizabethan country town: Warwick 1560–1590’, in Clark, P., editor, Country Towns in Pre-industrial England, Leicester, Leicester University Press, 1981.Google Scholar
40 Anderson, M., ‘The impact on the family relationships of the elderly’, p. 56.Google Scholar
41 This is discussed more fully in Smith, R. M., ‘Some issues concerning families and their property in rural England 1240–1800’, chapter 1 in Smith, R. M., editor, Land, Kinship and Life-cycle, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar, particularly section(v), of that chapter, ‘Some issues in the family cycle of the propertyless or deficient’.
42 See also the comments concerning the multiple-family households of the Russian serfs as little welfare ‘republics’ in Czap, P., ‘The perennial multiple family household, Mishino, Russia 1782–1853’, Journal of Family History 7 (1982)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, and in ‘A large family: the peasant’s greatest wealth: serf households in Mishino, Russia 1814–58’ in Wall, R., Robin, J., and Laslett, P., editors, Family Forms in Historic Europe, Cambridge University Press, 1983.CrossRefGoogle Scholar There are reasons to believe that welfare and charity recipients in areas of Southern Europe were unlike those in north-west European areas. Some recent research suggests that the elderly were far less prominent in the lists of beneficiaries analysed by Martz, L., Poverty and Welfare in Hapsburg Spain, Cambridge University Press, 1983CrossRefGoogle Scholar, and Jones, C., Chanté et bienfaisance: The Treatment of the Poor in the Montpellier Region 1740–1815, Cambridge University Press, 1982.Google Scholar
43 See for example, Freeman, R., Chang, Ming Cheng and Sun, Te-Hsiung, ‘Household composition, extended kinship and reproduction in Taiwan’, Population Studies 36 (1982);Google ScholarMartin, L., and Cutler, S., ‘Mortality decline and Japanese family structure’, Population and Development Review 9 (1983).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
44 This implies a diminution of the emphasis given to the mode of production by, for example, Walker, A., ‘Towards a Political Economy of Old Age’, p. 77 and n. 26, p. 92.Google Scholar
- 31
- Cited by