Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gbm5v Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-22T16:48:36.308Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Small Farmer Credit and the Village Production Unit in Rural Mali

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  23 May 2014

John Van Dusen Lewis*
Affiliation:
Howard University

Extract

This paper reviews the appropriateness of a development intervention celebrated for its direct benefits to the rural poor: small farmer credit. It will focus on the degree of inappropriateness that results from a contradiction between the convenience of directing the credit to discrete compound units and the dependence of small farmers' success on the coordination of production activities among larger groupings. The case to be looked at is from the West African savannah of Central Mali.

The economic posture of Malian savannah farmers develops within the context of these larger groups of producers. Unlike peasant coalitions in Latin America (Ortiz, 1972), the Malian groupings have not arisen to provide mutual security by spreading market risk among a wider group. This occurs where peasants are dependent on returns from a commercial crop the demand for which leaves them uncertain about how much to produce at any given time. If this were the case, subsidized credit inasmuch as it improved the peasant's marketing options might be able to circumvent such coalitions in attracting the small farmer. But the Malian peasant's coalitions are organized to confront production rather than marketing constraints. As long as these production constraints remain, his loyalty will be to his coalitions rather than to a marketing opportunity should these conflict.

The Malian peasant is not limited by land scarcity in the amount he cultivates. Therefore, he is not dependent on income from commercial crops to buy food; he will increase cash crop production only when its marketing situation is stable. Dry season migrant labor opportunities have long been available to him as an alternative for raising money for the colonial and post-colonial head taxes. Migrant laborers come home to grow unmarketed, subsistence crops. The money uses of their labor are often better served elsewhere.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © African Studies Association 1978

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Bazin, Jean. (1974) “War and Servitude in Segu” in Economy and Society, Vol. III, no. 2, 103142.Google Scholar
Dieterlen, Germaine. (1952) Essai sur la Religion Bambara. Paris: Payot, Musee de l'Homme.Google Scholar
De Ganay, Solange. (1960) “Les Tô Societes d'Entr'aide chez les Bambara du Soudan Francais” in Selected Papers at the Fifth International Congress of Anthropological and Ethnological Sciences. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.Google Scholar
Ernst, Klaus. (1976) Tradition and Progress in the African Village: the Non-Capitalist Transformation of Rural Communities in Mali. London: C. Hurst & Co.Google Scholar
Fortes, Meyer. (1958) “Introduction” in Goody, J. (ed.) The Developmental Cycle in Domestic Groups. Cambridge Papers in Social Anthropology, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Harms, Larry W. (1978) “ECIBEV Credit Activities–May 1975 through April 30, 1978,” mimeo of L'OMBEVI, Bamako.Google Scholar
Hopkins, Nicholas S. (1972) Popular Government in an African Town. Chicago: University of Chigao Press.Google Scholar
Imperato, Pascal J. (1977) African Folk Medicine: Practices and Beliefs of the Bambara and Other Peoples. Baltimore: York Press.Google Scholar
Jones, William J. (1976) Planning and Economie Policy: Socialist Mali and her Neighbors. Washington: Three Continents Press.Google Scholar
Lewis, John Van Dusen. (n.d.) “Descendants and Crops: Two Poles of Production in a Malian Peasant Community,” manuscript.Google Scholar
Leynaud, Emile. (1961) Les Cadres Sociaux de la Vie Rurale dans la Haute Vallee du Niger, Vol. II. Paris: BDPA, mimeo.Google Scholar
Meillassoux, Claude. (1975) “Introduction” in Meillassoux, (ed.) L'Esclavage en Afrique Precoloniale. Paris: Maspero.Google Scholar
Monteil, Charles. (1924) Les Bambara de Segou et du Kaarta. Paris: Larose.Google Scholar
Ortiz, Sutti. (1972) Uncertainties in Peasant Farming. London School of Economics: Monograph in Social Anthropology.Google Scholar
Person, Yves. (1968) Samory: Une Revolution Dyula, Vol I. Dakar: IFAN.Google Scholar
Rochette, R. and Rupp, M.. (1974) “Projet USAID de Parc d'Élevage dans la Forêt de Doukou-louma (Ségou) et d'Embouche Paysanne dans la Region de Doukoulouma (Segou).” in Bamako: PROJET MALI/523/FAO/PNUD/L'OMBEVI, mimeo.Google Scholar
Trimingham, J. W. (1962) Islam in West Africa. London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Willis, John Ralph. (1971) “The Western Sudan from the Moroccan Invasion (1591) to the Death of Al-Mukhtar Al-Kunti (1811),” in Ajayi, J.F.A. and Crowder, M. (eds.) History of West Africa. London: Longman.Google Scholar
Wolff, Eric. (1966) Peasants. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar