Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t7fkt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T05:00:17.210Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Tax Policy

Principles and Lessons

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 April 2022

Robin Boadway
Affiliation:
Queen's University, Ontario
Katherine Cuff
Affiliation:
McMaster University, Ontario

Summary

Tax policies are informed by principles developed in the tax theory and policy literature. This Element surveys the policy lessons that emerge from optimal tax analysis since the 1970s. This Element begins with the evolution of tax policy principles from the comprehensive income approach to the expenditure tax approach to normative tax analysis based on social welfare maximization and recounts key results from the optimal income tax analysis inspired by Mirrlees and extended by Diamond to the extensive margin approach. This Element also emphasizes analytical techniques that yield empirically relevant concepts and show the equity-efficiency trade-off at the heart of tax policy. We also extend the analysis to recent literature incorporating involuntary unemployment, and policies like welfare and unemployment insurance.
Get access
Type
Element
Information
Online ISBN: 9781108954426
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication: 12 May 2022

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Ahmad, Ehtisham and Stern, Nicholas (1984), The Theory and Practice of Tax Reform in Developing Countries (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Akerlof, George (1978), ‘The Economics of “Tagging” as Applied to the Optimal Income Tax, Welfare Programs, and Manpower Training,’ American Economic Review 68, 819.Google Scholar
Ales, Laurence, Kurnaz, Musab and Sleet, Christopher (2015), ‘Technical Change, Wage Inequality, and Taxes,’ American Economic Review 105, 3061–101.Google Scholar
Alesina, Alberto and Giuliano, Paola (2011), ‘Preferences for Redistribution,’ in Bisin, A. and Benhabib, J. (eds.), Handbook of Social Economics (The Netherlands: North Holland), 93132.Google Scholar
Alesina, Alberto, Miano, Armando and Stantcheva, Stefanie (2019), ‘Immigration and Redistribution,’ NBER Working Paper No. 24733.Google Scholar
Alesina, Alberto, Stantcheva, Stefanie and Teso, Edoardo (2018), ‘Intergenerational Mobility and Preferences for Redistribution,’ American Economic Review 108, 521–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alm, James, McClelland, Gary H. and Schulze, William D. (1999), ‘Changing the Social Norm of Tax Compliance by Voting,’ Kyklos 52, 141–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Apps, Patricia, Ngo, Van Long and Rees, Ray (2014), ‘Optimal Piecewise Linear Income Taxation,’ Journal of Public Economic Theory 16(4), 523–45.Google Scholar
Aronsson, Thomas, Blomquist, Sören and Sacklén, Hans (1999), ‘Identifying Interdependent Behaviour in an Empirical Model of Labour Supply,’ Journal of Applied Econometrics 14, 607–26.Google Scholar
Aronsson, Thomas and Sjögren, Tomas (2010), ‘Optimal Income Taxation and Social Norms in the Labor Market,’ International Tax and Public Finance 17, 6789.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. (1951), Social Choice and Individual Values (New York: Wiley).Google Scholar
Atkinson, Anthony B. and Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1976), ‘The Design of Tax Structure: Direct vs. Indirect Taxation,’ Journal of Public Economics 6, 5575.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Auerbach, Alan, Devereux, Michael and Simpson, Helen (2010), ‘Taxing Corporate Income,’ in Adam, S., Besley, T., Blundell, R. et al. (eds.), Dimensions of Tax Design (Oxford: Oxford University Press), 838–93.Google Scholar
Treasury, Australian (2010), Australia’s Future Tax System (The Henry Review) (Canberra: Commonwealth of Australia).Google Scholar
Banks, James and Diamond, Peter (2010), ‘The Base for Direct Taxation,’ in Adam, S., Besley, T., Blundell, R. et al. (eds.), Dimensions of Tax Design: The Mirrlees Review (Oxford: Oxford University Press), 548648.Google Scholar
Bargain, Olivier, Dolls, Mathias, Neumann, Drik, Peichl, Andreas and Siegloch, Sebastian (2014a), ‘Tax-Benefit Revealed Social Preferences in Europe and the US,’ Annals of Economics and Statistics 113/114, 257–89.Google Scholar
Bargain, Olivier, Dolls, Mathias, Neumann, Dirk, Peichl, Andreas and Siegloch, Sebastian (2014b), ‘Comparing Inequality Aversion across Countries when Labor Supply Responses Differ,’ International Tax and Public Finance 21, 845–73.Google Scholar
Bastani, Spencer, Blomquist, Sören and Micheletto, Luca (2019), ‘Nonlinear and Piecewise Linear Income Taxation, and the Subsidization of Work-Related Goods,’ International Tax and Public Finance 26, 806–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bastani, Spencer and Lundberg, Jacob (2017), ‘Political Preferences for Redistribution in Sweden,The Journal of Economic Inequality 15, 345–67.Google Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas and Taubinsky, Dmitry (2018), ‘Behavioral Public Economics,’ in Bernheim, B. D., DellaVigna, S. and Laibson, D. (eds.), Handbook of Behavioral Economics, Volume 1 (Amsterdam: North Holland), 381516.Google Scholar
Blackorby, Charles and Donaldson, David (1988), ‘Cash versus Kind, Self Selection and Efficient Transfers,’ American Economic Review 78, 691700.Google Scholar
Blumkin, Tomer and Sadka, Efraim (2005), ‘Income Taxation with Intergenerational Mobility: Can Higher Inequality Lead to Less Progression?European Economic Review 49, 1915–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boadway, Robin (2012), From Optimal Tax Theory to Tax Policy: Retrospective and Prospective Views, The Munich Lectures, 2009 (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press).Google Scholar
Boadway, Robin and Bruce, Neil (1984), Welfare Economics (Oxford: Blackwell).Google Scholar
Boadway, Robin and Cuff, Katherine (1999), ‘Monitoring Job Search as an Instrument for Targeting Transfers,’ International Tax and Public Finance 6, 317–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boadway, Robin and Cuff, Katherine (2001), ‘A Minimum Wage can be Welfare-Improving and Employment-Enhancing,’ European Economic Review 45, 553–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boadway, Robin and Cuff, Katherine (2014), ‘Monitoring and Optimal Income Taxation with Involuntary Unemployment,’ Annals of Economics and Statistics 113/114, 121–57.Google Scholar
Boadway, Robin and Cuff, Katherine (2015), ‘Tax Treatment of Bequests when Donor Benefits are Discounted,’ International Tax and Public Finance 22, 604–34.Google Scholar
Boadway, Robin and Cuff, Katherine (2018), ‘Optimal Unemployment Insurance and Redistribution,’ Journal of Public Economic Theory 20, 303–24.Google Scholar
Boadway, Robin and Cuff, Katherine (2019), ‘Designing a Basic Income: Lessons from the Optimal Income Tax Literature,’ paper prepared for the British Columbia Basic Income Expert Committee, British Columbia Ministry of Social Development and Poverty Reduction.Google Scholar
Boadway, Robin, Cuff, Katherine and Marchand, Maurice (2000a), ‘Optimal Income Taxation with Quasi-Linear Preferences Revisited,’ Journal of Public Economic Theory 2, 435–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boadway, Robin and Jacquet, Laurence (2008), ‘Optimal Marginal and Average Income Tax Rates under Maximin,’ Journal of Economic Theory 143, 425–41.Google Scholar
Boadway, Robin, Marceau, Nicolas and Sato, Motohiro (1999), ‘Agency and the Design of Welfare Systems,Journal of Public Economics 73, 130.Google Scholar
Boadway, Robin, Marchand, Maurice, Pestieau, Pierre and Racionero, Maria del Mar (2000b), ‘Optimal Redistribution with Heterogeneous Preferences for Leisure,’ Journal of Public Economic Theory 4, 475–98.Google Scholar
Boadway, Robin and Martineau, Nicolas-Guillaume (2016), ‘Optimal Redistribution with Endogenous Social Norms,’ The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 118(3), 524–56.Google Scholar
Boadway, Robin and Pestieau, Pierre (2007), ‘Tagging and Redistributive Taxation,’ Annales d’ Economie et de Statistique 83/84, 225.Google Scholar
Boadway, Robin and Shah, Anwar (2009), Fiscal Federalism: Principles and Practice of Multiorder Governance (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Boone, Jan and Lans Bovenberg, A. (2013), ‘Optimal Taxation and Welfare Benefits with Monitoring of Job-Search,’ International Tax and Public Finance 20, 268–92.Google Scholar
Bourguignon, François and Spadaro, Amedeo (2012), ‘Tax-Benefit Revealed Social Preferences,’ Journal of Economic Inequality 10, 75108.Google Scholar
Bovenberg, A. Lans and Jacobs, Bas (2005), ‘Redistribution and Education Subsidies are Siamese Twins,’ Journal of Public Economics 89, 2005–35.Google Scholar
Chetty, Raj (2008), ‘Moral Hazard versus Liquidity and Optimal Unemployment Insurance,’ Journal of Political Economy 116, 173234.Google Scholar
Chetty, Raj (2009), ‘Is the Taxable Income Elasticity Sufficient to Calculate Deadweight Loss? The Implications of Evasion and Avoidance,’ American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 1, 3152.Google Scholar
Chetty, Raj and Saez, Emmanuel (2013), ‘Teaching the Tax Code: Earnings Responses to an Experiment with EITC Recipients,’ American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 5, 131.Google Scholar
Choné, Philippe and Laroque, Guy (2005), ‘Optimal Incentives for Labor Force Participation,’ Journal of Public Economics 89, 395425.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Choné, Philippe and Laroque, Guy (2010), ‘Negative Marginal Tax Rates and Heterogeneity,’ American Economic Review 100(5), 2532–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Choné, Philippe and Laroque, Guy (2011), ‘Optimal Taxation in the Extensive Model,’ Journal of Economic Theory 146, 425–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christiansen, Vidar (2015), ‘Optimal Participation Taxes,’ Economica 82, 595612.Google Scholar
Christiansen, Vidar and Jansen, Eilev S. (1978), ‘Implicit Social Preferences in the Norwegian System of Indirect Taxation,’ Journal of Public Economics 10, 217–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christiansen, Vidar and Smith, Stephen (2021), Economic Principles of Commodity Taxation, Elements in Public Economics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corlett, W. J. and Hague, D. C. (1953), ‘Complementarity and the Excess Burden of Taxation,’ Review of Economic Studies 21, 2130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cremer, Helmuth, Gahvari, Firouz and Lozachmeur, Jean-Marie (2010), ‘Tagging and Income Taxation: Theory and an Application,’ American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 2, 3150.Google Scholar
Cremer, Helmuth and Pestieau, Pierre (2011), ‘The Tax Treatment of Intergenerational Wealth Transfer,’ CESifo Economic Studies 57, 365401.Google Scholar
Cuff, Katherine (2000), ‘Optimality of Workfare with Heterogeneous Preferences,’ Canadian Journal of Economics 33, 149–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dahlby, Bev (2008), The Marginal Cost of Public Finds: Theory and Applications (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deaton, Angus (1979), ‘Optimally Uniform Commodity Taxes,’ Economics Letters 2, 357–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, Peter A. (1980), ‘Income Taxation with Fixed Hours of Work,’ Journal of Public Economics 13, 101–10.Google Scholar
Diamond, Peter A. (1998), ‘Optimal Income Taxation: An Example with a U-Shaped Pattern of Optimal Marginal Tax Rates,’ American Economic Review 88, 8395.Google Scholar
Diamond, Peter A. (2006), ‘Optimal Tax Treatment of Private Contributions for Public Goods with and without Warm Glow Preferences,’ Journal of Public Economics 90, 897919.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, Peter A. and Mirrlees, James A. (1971), ‘Optimal Taxation and Public Production I: Production Efficiency and II: Tax Rules,’ American Economic Review 61, 827 and 261–78.Google Scholar
Diamond, Peter A. and Saez, Emmanuel (2011), ‘The Case for a Progressive Tax: From Basic Research to Policy Recommendations,’ Journal of Economic Perspectives 25, 165–90.Google Scholar
Edwards, Jeremy, Keen, Michael and Tuomala, Matti (1994), ‘Income Tax, Commodity Taxes and Public Good Provision: A Brief Guide,’ FinanzArchiv 51, 472–97.Google Scholar
Elster, Jon (1989), ‘Social Norms and Economic Theory,’ Journal of Economic Perspectives 3, 99117.Google Scholar
Farhi, Emmanuel and Gabaix, Xavier (2020), ‘Optimal Taxation with Behavioral Agents,’ American Economic Review 110, 298336.Google Scholar
Feldstein, Martin (2012), ‘The Mirrlees Review,’ Journal of Economic Literature 50, 781–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feldstein, Martin S. (1976), ‘On the Theory of Tax Reform,’ Journal of Public Economics 6, 77104.Google Scholar
Feldstein, Martin S. (1999), ‘Tax Avoidance and the Deadweight Loss of the Income Tax,’ Review of Economics and Statistics 81, 674–80.Google Scholar
Fleurbaey, Marc and Maniquet, François (2011), A Theory of Fairness and Social Welfare (New York: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Fong, Christina (2001), ‘Social Preferences, Self-Interest and the Demand for Redistribution,’ Journal of Public Economics 82, 225–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, Robert H. (2005), ‘Are Concerns about Relative Income Relevant for Public Policy?American Economic Review 95, 137–41.Google Scholar
Gans, Joshua and Smart, Michael (1996), ‘Majority Voting with Single Crossing Preferences,’ Journal of Public Economics 59, 219–37.Google Scholar
Gerritsen, Aart (2016), ‘Optimal Taxation when People Do Not Maximize Well-Being,’ Journal of Public Economics 144, 122–39.Google Scholar
Gordon, Roger and Sarada, (2019), The Role of the Corporation Income, Elements in Public Economics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Gordon, Roger H. and Cullen, Julie Berry (2012), ‘Income Redistribution in a Federal System of Governments,’ Journal of Public Economics 96, 1100–09.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grodner, Andrew and Kniesner, Thomas J. (2006), ‘Social Interactions in Labor Supply,’ Journal of the European Economic Association 4, 1226–48.Google Scholar
Gruber, Jon and Saez, Emmanuel (2002), ‘The Elasticity of Taxable Income: Evidence and Implications,’ Journal of Public Economics 84, 132.Google Scholar
Guvenen, Fatih, Kambourov, Gueorgui, Kuruscu, Burhanettin, Ocampo-Diaz, Sergio and Chen, Daphne (2019), ‘Use It or Lose It: Efficiency Gains from Wealth Taxation,’ NBER Working Paper No. 26284.Google Scholar
Haig, Robert M. (1921), The Federal Income Tax (New York: Columbia University Press).Google Scholar
Hammond, Peter J. (1987), ‘Altruism,’ in Eatwell, J., Milgate, M. and Newman, P. (eds.), The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, 1st ed. (Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan), 8587.Google Scholar
Harberger, Arnold C. (1964), ‘Taxation, Resource Allocation and Welfare,’ in Due, J. (ed.), The Role of Direct and Indirect Taxes in the Federal Revenue System (Princeton: Princeton University Press), 2570.Google Scholar
Hellwig, Martin F. (2009), ‘A Note on Deaton’s Theorem on the Undesirability of Nonuniform Excise Taxation,’ Economic Letters 105, 186–88.Google Scholar
Hellwig, Martin F. (2010), ‘A Generalization of the Atkinson-Stiglitz (1976) Theorem on the Undesirability of Nonuniform Excise Taxation,’ Economic Letters 108, 156–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hicks, John R. (1946), Value and Capital, 2nd ed. (Oxford: Clarendon Press).Google Scholar
Hochman, Harold M. and Rodgers, James D. (1969), ‘Pareto Optimal Redistribution,’ American Economic Review 59, 542–57.Google Scholar
Hosios, Arthur J. (1990), ‘On the Efficiency of Matching and Related Models of Search and Unemployment,’ Review of Economic Studies 57, 279–98.Google Scholar
Hungerbühler, Mathias and Lehmann, Etienne (2009), ‘On the Optimality of a Minimum Wage: New Insights from Optimal Tax Theory,’ Journal of Public Economics 93, 464–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hungerbühler, Mathias, Lehmann, Etienne, Parmentier, Alexis and Bruno, Van der Linden (2006), ‘Optimal Redistributive Taxation in a Search Equilibrium Model,’ Review of Economic Studies 73, 743–67.Google Scholar
Hvidberg, Kristoffer, Kreiner, Claus and Stantcheva, Stefanie (2020), ‘Social Position and Fairness Views,’ NBER Working Paper No. 28099.Google Scholar
Immonen, Rivta, Kanbur, Ravi, Keen, Michael and Tuomala, Matti (1998), ‘Tagging and Taxing: The Optimal Use of Categorical and Income Information in Designing Tax/Transfer Schemes,’ Economica 65, 179–92.Google Scholar
Jacobs, Bas and Lans Bovenberg, A. (2010), ‘Human Capital and Optimal Positive Taxation of Capital Income,’ International Tax and Public Finance 17, 451–78.Google Scholar
Jacobs, Bas and Lans Bovenberg, A. (2011), ‘Optimal Taxation of Human Capital and the Earnings Function,’ Journal of Public Economic Theory 13, 957–71.Google Scholar
Jacobs, Bas, Jongen, Egbert L. W. and Zoutman, Floris T. (2017), ‘Revealed Social Preferences of Dutch Political Parties,’ Journal of Public Economics 156, 81100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacobson, Louis S., LaLonde, Robert J. and Sullivan, Daniel G. (1993), ‘Earnings Losses of Displaced Workers,’ American Economic Review 83, 685709.Google Scholar
Jacobson, Louis S., LaLonde, Robert J. and Sullivan, Daniel G. (2005), ‘Is Retraining Displaced Workers a Good Investment?Economic Perspectives 29, 4766.Google Scholar
Jacquet, Laurence, Lehmann, Etienne and Bruno, Van der Linden (2013), ‘The Optimal Marginal Tax Rates with Both Extensive and Intensive Responses,’ Journal of Economic Theory 148, 1770–805.Google Scholar
Jacquet, Laurence, Lehmann, Etienne and Bruno, Van der Linden (2014), ‘Optimal Income Taxation with Kalai Wage Bargaining and Endogenous Participation,’ Social Choice and Welfare 42, 381402.Google Scholar
Jacquet, Laurence and Bruno, Van der Linden (2006), ‘The Normative Analysis of Tagging Revisited: Dealing with Stigmatization,’ FinanzArchiv 62, 168–98.Google Scholar
Kaldor, Nicholas (1955), An Expenditure Tax (London: Allen and Unwin).Google Scholar
Kanbur, Ravi and Tuomala, Matti (2013), ‘Relativity, Inequality, and Optimal Nonlinear Income Taxation,’ International Economic Review 54, 1199–217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplow, Louis (2001), ‘Horizontal Equity: New Measures, Unclear Principles,’ in Hassett, K. and Hubbard, G. (eds.), Inequality and Tax Policy (Washington: American Enterprise Institute), 7597.Google Scholar
Kaplow, Louis (2006), ‘On the Desirability of Commodity Taxation Even when Income Taxation is Not Optimal,’ Journal of Public Economics 90, 1235–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplow, Louis (2008), The Theory of Taxation and Public Economics (Princeton: Princeton University Press).Google Scholar
Karni, Edi (1999), ‘Optimal Unemployment Insurance: A Survey,’ Southern Economic Journal 66, 442–65.Google Scholar
Kasy, Maximilian (2018), ‘Why a Universal Basic Income is Better than Subsidies of Low-Wage Work,’ Data for Progress Working Paper No. 2. http://filesforprogress.org/pdfs/UBI_EITC_Kasy_DFP_Working_Paper.pdfGoogle Scholar
Keane, Michael P. (2011), ‘Labor Supply and Taxes: A Survey,’ Journal of Economic Literature 49, 9611075.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kleven, Henrik Jacobsen (2014), ‘How Can Scandinavians Tax So Much?Journal of Economic Perspectives 28, 7798.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kleven, Henrik Jacobsen (2019), ‘The EITC and the Extensive Margin: A Reappraisal,’ Working Paper No. 26405, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Kleven, Henrik Jacobsen and Kopczuk, Wojciech (2011), ‘Transfer Program Complexity and the Take Up of Social Benefits,’ American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 3, 5490.Google Scholar
Kleven, Henrik Jacobsen and Schultz, Esben Anton (2014), ‘Estimating Taxable Income Responses Using Danish Tax Reforms,’ American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 6, 271301.Google Scholar
Kroft, Kory, Kucko, Kavan, Lehmann, Etienne and Schmieder, Johannes (2020), ‘Optimal Income Taxation with Unemployment and Wage Responses: A Sufficient Statistics Approach,’ American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 12, 254–92.Google Scholar
Kuziemko, Ilyana, Norton, Michael I., Saez, Emmanuel and Stantcheva, Stefanie (2015), ‘How Elastic are Preferences for Redistribution? Evidence from Randomized Survey Experiments,’ American Economic Review 105, 1478–508.Google Scholar
LaLonde, Robert J. (2007), The Case for Wage Insurance, Council on Foreign Relations Special Report No. 30 (New York: Council on Foreign Relations).Google Scholar
Landais, Camille, Michaillat, Pascal and Saez, Emmanuel (2018), ‘A Macroeconomic Approach to Optimal Unemployment Insurance: Theory,’ American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 10, 152–81.Google Scholar
Laroque, Guy (2005), ‘Indirect Taxation is Superfluous under Separability and Taste Homogeneity: A Simple Proof,’ Economics Letters 87, 141–44.Google Scholar
Lavecchia, Adam (2020), ‘Minimum Wage Policy with Optimal Taxes and Unemployment,’ Journal of Public Economics 190, 104228.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Layard, Richard (1980), ‘Human Satisfactions and Public Policy,’ Economic Journal 90, 737–50.Google Scholar
Lee, David and Saez, Emmanuel (2012), ‘Optimal Minimum Wage Policy in Competitive Labor Markets,’ Journal of Public Economics 96, 739–49.Google Scholar
Lehmann, Etienne, Parmentier, Alexis and Bruno, Van der Linden (2011), ‘Optimal Income Taxation with Endogenous Participation and Search Unemployment,’ Journal of Public Economics 95, 1523–37.Google Scholar
Lockwood, Benjamin B. (2020), ‘Optimal Income Taxation with Present Bias,’ American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 12, 298-327.Google Scholar
Lockwood, Benjamin B. and Weinzierl, Matthew (2016), ‘Positive and Normative Judgments Implicit in U.S. Tax Policy, and the Costs of Unequal Growth and Recessions,’ Journal of Monetary Economics 77, 3047.Google Scholar
Luttmer, Erzo F. P. and Singhal, Monica (2014), ‘Tax Morale,’ Journal of Economic Perspectives 28, 149–68.Google Scholar
Marceau, Nicolas and Boadway, Robin (1994), ‘Minimum Wage Legislation and Unemployment Insurance as Instruments for Redistribution,’ Scandinavian Journal of Economics 96, 6781.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martinez-Vazquez, Jorge and Winer, Stanley L. (eds.) (2014), Coercion and Social Welfare in Public Finance (New York: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Report, Meade (1978), The Structure and Reform of Direct Taxation, Report of a Committee Chaired by Professor J. E. Meade (London: Allen and Unwin).Google Scholar
Meltzer, Allan H. and Richard, Scott F. (1981), ‘A Rational Theory of the Size of Government,’ Journal of Political Economy 89, 914–27.Google Scholar
Milgrom, Paul (1993), ‘Is Sympathy an Economic Value? Philosophy, Economics, and the Contingent Valuation Method,’ in Hausman, J. A. (ed.), Contingent Valuation: A Critical Assessment (Amsterdam: Elsevier), 418–35.Google Scholar
Mirrlees, James, Adam, Stuart, Besley, Timothy et al. (2011), Tax by Design: The Mirrlees Review (Oxford: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
Mirrlees, James A. (1971), ‘An Exploration in the Theory of Optimum Income Taxation,’ Review of Economic Studies 38, 175208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirrlees, James A. (2007), ‘Taxation of Gifts and Bequests,’ slides for a talk at the Centenary of James Meade Conference, mimeo.Google Scholar
Musgrave, Richard A. (1959), The Theory of Public Finance (New York: McGraw-Hill).Google Scholar
Nava, Mario, Schroyen, Fred and Marchand, Maurice (1996), ‘Optimal Fiscal and Public Expenditure Policy in a Two-Class Economy,’ Journal of Public Economics 61, 119–37.Google Scholar
Newbery, David M. (1986), ‘On the Desirability of Input Taxes,’ Economics Letters 20, 267–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nishimura, Yukihiro (2003), ‘Optimal Commodity Taxation for the Reduction of Envy,’ Social Choice and Welfare 21, 501–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olivera, Javier (2015), ‘Preferences for Redistribution in Europe,’ IZA Journal of European Labor Studies 4, 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Osborne, Martin J. and Slivinski, Al (1996), ‘A Model of Political Competition with Citizen-Candidates,’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 111, 6596.Google Scholar
Oswald, Andrew (1983), ‘Altruism, Jealousy and the Theory of Optimal Non-Linear Taxation,’ Journal of Public Economics 20, 7787.Google Scholar
Parsons, Donald O. (1996), ‘Imperfect “Tagging” in Social Insurance Programs,’ Journal of Public Economics 62, 183207.Google Scholar
Piketty, Thomas and Saez, Emmanuel (2013), ‘Optimal Labor Income Taxation,’ in Auerbach, A., Chetty, R., Feldstein, M. and Saez, E. (eds.), Handbook of Public Economics, Volume 5 (Amsterdam: North Holland), 391474.Google Scholar
Pissarides, Christopher A. (2000), Equilibrium Unemployment Theory, 2nd ed. (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press).Google Scholar
President’s Advisory Panel on Federal Tax Reform (2005), Simple, Fair and Pro-Growth: Proposals to Fix America’s Tax System (Washington, DC: U.S. Treasury).Google Scholar
Ramsey, Frank P. (1927), ‘A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation,’ Economic Journal 37, 4761.Google Scholar
Roemer, John E. (1998), Equality of Opportunity (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
Rogerson, Richard, Shimer, Robert and Wright, Randall (2005), ‘Search-Theoretic Models of the Labor Market: A Survey,’ Journal of Economic Literature 43, 959–88.Google Scholar
Rothschild, Casey and Scheuer, Florin (2013), ‘Redistributive Taxation in the Roy Model,’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 128, 623–68.Google Scholar
Rothstein, Jesse (2010), ‘Is the EITC as Good as an NIT? Conditional Cash Transfers and Tax Incidence,’ American Economic Policy: Economic Policy 2, 177208.Google Scholar
Royal Commission on Taxation (1966), Report (The Carter Report) (Ottawa: Queen’s Printer).Google Scholar
Royal Commission on the Taxation of Profits and Income (1955), Report (London: Her Majesty’s Stationery Office).Google Scholar
Saez, Emmanuel (2001), ‘Using Elasticities to Derive Optimal Income Tax Rates,’ Review of Economic Studies 68, 205–09.Google Scholar
Saez, Emmanuel (2002), ‘Optimal Income Transfer Programs: Intensive vs Extensive Labor Supply Responses,’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, 1039–73.Google Scholar
Saez, Emmanuel (2010), ‘Do Taxpayers Bunch at Kink Points?American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 2, 180212.Google Scholar
Emmanuel, Saez, Slemrod, Joel and Giertz, Seth (2012), ‘The Elasticity of Taxable Income with Respect to Marginal Tax Rates: A Critical Review,’ Journal of Economic Literature 50, 350.Google Scholar
Saez, Emmanuel and Stantcheva, Stefanie (2016), ‘Generalized Social Marginal Welfare Weights for Optimal Tax Theory,’ American Economic Review 106, 2445.Google Scholar
Saez, Emmanuel and Veall, Michael (2005), ‘The Evolution of High Incomes in Northern America: Lessons from Canadian Evidence,’ American Economic Review 95, 831–49.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. (1986), ‘Theory of Optimal Taxation,’ Journal of Public Economics 30, 137–43.Google Scholar
Sandmo, Agnar (1976), ‘Optimal Taxation: An Introduction to the Literature,’ Journal of Public Economics 6, 3754.Google Scholar
Schanz, George von (1896), ‘Der Einkommensbegriff und die Einkommensteuergesetze,’ FinanzArchiv 13, 187.Google Scholar
Scheuer, Florian and Slemrod, Joel (2021), ‘Taxing our Wealth,’ Journal of Economic Perspectives 35, 207–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, Amartya (1973), On Economic Inequality (Oxford: Clarendon Press).Google Scholar
Sheshinski, Eytan (1972), ‘The Optimal Linear Income Tax,’ Review of Economic Studies 39, 297302.Google Scholar
Simons, Henry C. (1938), Personal Income Taxation (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).Google Scholar
Slemrod, Joel, Yitzhaki, Shlomo, Mayshar, Joram and Lundholm, Michael (1994), ‘The Optimal Two-Bracket Linear Income Tax,’ Journal of Public Economics 53, 269–90.Google Scholar
Spadaro, Amedeo, Piccoli, Luca and Mangiavacchi, Lucia (2015), ‘Optimal Taxation, Social Preferences and the Four Worlds of Welfare Capitalism in Europe,’ Economica 82, 448–85.Google Scholar
Spinnewijn, Johannes (2015), ‘Unemployed but Optimistic: Optimal Insurance Design with Biased Beliefs,’ Journal of the European Economic Association 13, 130–67.Google Scholar
Stantcheva, Stefanie (2015), ‘Learning and (or) Doing: Human Capital Investments and Optimal Taxation,’ NBER Working Paper No. 21381.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1982), ‘Self-Selection and Pareto Efficient Taxation,’ Journal of Public Economics 17, 213–40.Google Scholar
Tanninen, Hannu, Tuomala, Matti and Tuominen, Elina (2019), Inequality and Optimal Redistribution, Elements in Public Economics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Tarroux, Benoît (2019), ‘The Value of Tax Progressivity: Evidence from Survey Experiments,’ Journal of Public Economics 179, Article No. 104068.Google Scholar
Tuomala, Matti (2016), Optimal Redistributive Taxation (Oxford: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
United States Treasury (1977), Blueprints for Basic Tax Reform (Washington, DC: Government Printing Office).Google Scholar
Veall, Michael (2012), ‘Top Income Shares in Canada: Recent Trends and Policy Implications,’ Canadian Journal of Economics 45, 1247–72.Google Scholar
Weinzierl, Matthew (2014), ‘The Promise of Positive Optimal Taxation: Normative Diversity and a Role for Equal Sacrifice,’ Journal of Public Economics 118, 128–42.Google Scholar
Weinzierl, Matthew C. (2011), ‘The Surprising Power of Age-Dependent Taxes,’ Review of Economic Studies 78, 1490–518.Google Scholar
Wenzel, Michael (2005), ‘Motivation or Rationalisation? Causal Relations between Ethics, Norms and Tax Compliance,’ Journal of Economic Psychology 26, 491508.Google Scholar
Wicksell, Knut (1896), Finanztheoretische Untersuchungen (Jena: Gustav Fischer); translated as ‘A New Principle of Just Taxation,’ in Musgrave, R. and Peacock, A. T. (eds.), Classics in the Theory of Public Finance (New York: St. Martin’s Press), 72118.Google Scholar
Woittiez, Isolde and Kapteyn, Arie (1998), ‘Social Interactions and Habit Formation in a Model of Female Labour Supply,’ Journal of Public Economics 70, 185205.Google Scholar

Save element to Kindle

To save this element to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Tax Policy
Available formats
×

Save element to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Tax Policy
Available formats
×

Save element to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Tax Policy
Available formats
×