Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-7cvxr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-22T15:16:46.642Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Reform for Sale

A Common Agency Model with Moral Hazard Frictions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 February 2023

Perrin Lefebvre
Affiliation:
University of Namur
David Martimort
Affiliation:
Toulouse School of Economics

Summary

Lobbying competition is viewed as a delegated common agency game under moral hazard. Several interest groups try to influence a policy-maker who exerts effort to increase the probability that a reform be implemented. With no restriction on the space of contribution schedules, all equilibria perfectly reflect the principals' preferences over alternatives. As a result, lobbying competition reaches efficiency. Unfortunately, such equilibria require that the policy-maker pays an interest group when the latter is hurt by the reform. When payments remain non-negative, inducing effort requires leaving a moral hazard rent to the decision maker. Contributions schedules no longer reflect the principals' preferences, and the unique equilibrium is inefficient. Free-riding across congruent groups arises and the set of groups active at equilibrium is endogenously derived. Allocative efficiency and redistribution of the aggregate surplus are linked altogether and both depend on the set of active principals, as well as on the group size.
Get access
Type
Element
Information
Online ISBN: 9781009285605
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication: 02 March 2023

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aidt, T. (1998). “Political Internalization of Economic Externallities and Environmental Policy,” Journal of Public Economics, 69: 116.Google Scholar
Arnott, R. and Stiglitz, J. (1991). “Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets with Moral Hazard,” NBER Working Paper 3588.Google Scholar
Attar, A., Casamatta, C., Chassagnon, A. and Décamps, J. P. (2019). “Multiple Lenders, Strategic Default and Covenants,” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 11: 98130.Google Scholar
Attar, A. and Chassagnon, A. (2009). “On Moral Hazard and Nonexclusive Contracts,” Journal of Mathematical Economics, 45: 511525.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Attar, A., Piaser, G. and Porteiro, N. (2007a). “Negotiation and Take-It or Leave-It in Common Agency with Non-Contractible Actions,” Journal of Economic Theory, 135: 590593.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Attar, A., Piaser, G. and Porteiro, N. (2007b). “A Note on Common Agency Models of Moral Hazard,” Economics Letters, 95: 278284.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aumann, R. J. (1959). “Acceptable Points in General Cooperative n-Person Games,” in Tucker, A. W. and Luce, R. D., eds., Contributions to the Theory of Games IV, Princeton University Press, Princeton, 287324.Google Scholar
Baron, D. (1985). “Noncooperative Regulation of a Nonlocalized Externality,” The RAND Journal of Economics, 16: 553568.Google Scholar
Becker, G. (1983). “A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98: 371400.Google Scholar
Becker, G. (1985). “Public Policies, Pressure Groups and Dead-Weight Costs,” Journal of Public Economics, 28: 329346.Google Scholar
Bentley, A. (1908). The Process of Government, University of Chicago Press, Chicago.Google Scholar
Bergstrom, T., Blume, L. and Varian, H. (1986). “On the Private Provision of Public Goods,” Journal of Public Economics, 29: 2549.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernheim, D. (1986). “On the Voluntary and Involuntary Provision of Public Goods,” American Economic Review, 76: 789793.Google Scholar
Bernheim, B., Peleg, B. and Whinston, M. (1987). “Coalition-Proof Nash Equilibria I. Concepts,” Journal of Economic Theory, 42: 112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernheim, D. and Whinston, M. (1986a). “Common Agency,” Econometrica, 54: 923942.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernheim, D. and Whinston, M. (1986b). “Menu Auctions, Resource Allocations and Economic Influence,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101: 131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, T. and Coate, S. (2001). “Lobbying and Welfare in a Representative Democracy,” The Review of Economic Studies, 68: 6782.Google Scholar
Bisin, A. and Guaitoli, D. (2004). “Moral Hazard and Nonexclusive Contracts,” The RAND Journal of Economics, 35: 306328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bombardini, M. (2008). “Firm Heterogeneity and Lobby Participation,” Journal of International Economics, 75: 329348.Google Scholar
Chiesa, G. and Denicolò, V. (2009). “Trading with a Common Agent under Complete Information: A Characterization of Nash Equilibria,” Journal of Economic Theory, 144: 296311.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clarke, E. (1971). “Multipart Pricing of Public Goods,” Public Choice, 11: 1933.Google Scholar
Dahl, R. (1961). Who Governs? Democracy and Power in an American City, Yale University Press, New Heaven, London.Google Scholar
Dixit, A. (1996). The Making of Economic Policy, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dixit, A., Grossman, G. and Helpman, E. (1997). “Common Agency and Coordination: General Theory and Application to Government Policy Making,” Journal of Political Economy, 105: 752769.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, D. and O’Halloran, S. (1997). “Modelling Madison: A Multiple Principals Model of Interest Groups Competition,” Harvard University mimeo.Google Scholar
Epstein, D. and O’Halloran, S. (1999). Delegating Powers: A Transaction Cost Politics Approach to Policy Making under Separate Powers, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fraysse, J. (1993). “Common Agency: Existence of an Equilibrium in the Case of Two Outcomes,” Econometrica, 61: 12251229.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Furusawa, T. and Konishi, H. (2011). “Contributing or Free-Riding? Voluntary Participation in a Public Good Economy,” Theoretical Economics, 6: 29256.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gottlieb, D. and Moreira, H. (2022). “Simple Contracts with Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard,” Theoretical Economics, 17(3): 13571401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Green, J. and Laffont, J. J. (1977). “Characterization of Satisfactory Mechanisms for the Revelation of Preferences for Public Goods,” Econometrica, 45: 427438.Google Scholar
Grossman, S. and Hart, O. (1983). “An Analysis of the Principal-Agent Problem,” Econometrica, 51: 746.Google Scholar
Grossman, G. and Helpman, E. (1994). “Protection for Sale,” American Economic Review, 84: 833850.Google Scholar
Grossman, G. and Helpman, E. (2001). Special Interest Politics, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Groves, T. (1973). “Incentives in Teams,” Econometrica, 41: 617631.Google Scholar
Hellwig, M. (1983). “On Moral Hazard and Non-price Equilibria in Competitive Insurance Markets,” mimeo.Google Scholar
Hellwig, M. (2003). “Public-Good Provision with Many Participants,” The Review of Economic Studies, 70: 589614.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Helpman, E. and Laffont, J. J. (1975). “On Moral Hazard in General Equilibrium,” Journal of Economic Theory, 10: 823.Google Scholar
Helpman, E. and Persson, T. (2001). “Lobbying and Legislative Bargaining,” Advances in Economic Analysis and Policy, 1(1): 133.Google Scholar
Holmstrom, B. (1979). “Moral Hazard and Observability,” The Bell Journal of Economics, 10(1): 7491.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holmstrom, B. and Milgrom, P. (1987). “Aggregation and Linearity in the Provision of Intertemporal Incentives,” Econometrica, 55: 303328.Google Scholar
Hula, K. (1999). Lobbying Together: Interest Group Coalitions in Legislative Politics, Georgetown University Press, Washington DC.Google Scholar
Kahn, C. and Mookherjee, D. (1995). “Coalition Proof Equilibrium in an Adverse Selection Insurance Economy,” Journal of Economic Theory, 66: 113138.Google Scholar
Kiewiet, R. and McCubbins, M. (1991). The Logic of Delegation, University of Chicago Press, Chicago.Google Scholar
Kirchsteiger, G. and Prat, A. (2001). “Inefficient Equilibria in Lobbying,” Journal of Public Economics, 82: 349375.Google Scholar
Laffont, J. J. and Martimort, D. (2002). The Theory of Incentives: The Principal-Agent Model, Princeton University Press, Princeton.Google Scholar
Laussel, D. and Le Breton, M. (1998a). “Efficient Private Production of Public Goods under Common Agency,” Games and Economic Behavior, 25: 194218.Google Scholar
Laussel, D. and Le Breton, M. (1998b). “Free Riding as a By-Product of Incentive Constraints: A New Look at the Private Provision of Public Goods,” Mimeo GREQAM, Université de la Méditerranée.Google Scholar
Laussel, D. and Le Breton, M. (2001). “Conflict and Cooperation: The Structure of Equilibrium Payoffs in Common Agency,” Journal of Economic Theory, 100: 93128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Le Breton, M. and Salanié, F. (2003). “Lobbying under Political Uncertainty,” Journal of Public Economics, 87: 25892610.Google Scholar
Leaver, C. and Makris, M. (2006). “Passive Industry Interests in Large Polity,” Journal of Public Economic Theory, 8: 571602.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lefebvre, P. and Martimort, D. (2020). “When Olson Meets Dahl’: From Inefficient Groups Formation to Inefficient Policy-Making,” The Journal of Politics, 82: 10261043.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lima, R. and Moreira, H. (2014). “Information Transmission and Inefficient Lobbying,” Games and Economic Behavior, 86: 282307.Google Scholar
Mailath, G. and Postlewaite, A. (1990). “Asymmetric Information Bargaining Problems with Many Agents,” The Review of Economic Studies, 57: 351367.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mallard, G. (2014). “Static Common Agency and Political Influence: An Evaluative Survey,” Journal of Economic Surveys, 28: 1735.Google Scholar
Martimort, D. (1996). “The Multi-Principal Nature of the Government,” European Economic Review, 40: 673685.Google Scholar
Martimort, D. (2007). “Multi-Contracting Mechanism Design,” in Blundell, R., Newey, W. K., and Persson, T., eds., Advances in Economic Theory Proceedings of the World Congress of the Econometric Society, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.Google Scholar
Martimort, D. (2018). “Une revue critique de la théorie de l’agence commune appliquée aux jeux de lobbies,” Revue Économique, 69: 10251053.Google Scholar
Martimort, D. and Moreira, H. (2010). “Common Agency and Public Good Provision under Asymmetric Information,” Theoretical Economics, 5: 159213.Google Scholar
Martimort, D. and Semenov, A. (2007a). “The Pluralistic View of Politics: Asymmetric Lobbyists, Ideological Uncertainty and Political Entry,” Economics Letters, 97: 155161.Google Scholar
Martimort, D. and Semenov, A. (2007b). “Political Biases in Lobbying under Asymmetric Information,” Journal of the European Economic Association, 5: 614623.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martimort, D. and Semenov, A. (2008). “Ideological Uncertainty and Lobbying Competition,” Journal of Public Economics, 92: 456481.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martimort, D. and Stole, L. (2003). “Contractual Externalities and Common Agency Equilibria,” Advances in Theoretical Economics, 3(1): Article 4. www.bepress.com/bejte.Google Scholar
Martimort, D. and Stole, L. (2009). “Selecting Equilibria in Common Agency Games,” Journal of Economic Theory, 144: 604634.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martimort, D. and Stole, L. (2012). “Representing Equilibrium Aggregates in Aggregate Games with Applications to Common Agency,” Games and Economic Behavior, 76: 753772.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martimort, D. and Stole, L. (2018). “Menu Auctions and Influence Games with Private Information,” SSRN 2569703. https://ssrn.com/abstract=2569703Google Scholar
Mirrlees, J. (1999). “The Theory of Moral Hazard and Unobservable Behaviour: Part I,” The Review of Economic Studies, 66: 321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirrlees, J. (1976). “The Optimal Structure of Incentives and Authority within an Organization.” The Bell Journal of Economics. 7:105131.Google Scholar
Mitra, D. (1999). “Endogenous Lobby Formation and Endogenous Protection: A Long-Run Model of Trade Policy Formation,” American Economic Review, 89: 11161134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moe, T. (1981). The Organization of Interests, University of Chicago, Chicago.Google Scholar
Moe, T. (1989). “The Politics of Structural Choice: Towards a Theory of Public Bureaucracy,” in Williamson, O., ed., Organization Theory: From Chester Barnard to the Present and Beyond, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 116153.Google Scholar
Olson, M. (1965). The Logic of Collective Action, Harvard University Press, Boston.Google Scholar
Pauly, M. (1974). “Overprovision and Public Provision of Insurance: The Roles of Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 88: 4462.Google Scholar
Peltzman, S. (1976). “Toward a More General Theory of Regulation,” The Journal of Law and Economics, 19: 211240.Google Scholar
Peters, M. (2003). “Negotiation and Take It or Leave it in Common Agency,” Journal of Economic Theory, 111: 88109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peters, M. and Szentes, B. (2012). “Definable and Contractible Contracts,” Econometrica, 80: 363411.Google Scholar
Rama, M. and Tabellini, G. (1998). “Lobbying by Capital and Labor Overtrade and Labor Market Policies,” European Economic Review, 42: 12961316.Google Scholar
Ray, D. and Vohra, R. (1997). “Equilibrium Binding Agreements,” Journal of Economic Theory, 73: 3078.Google Scholar
Shapley, L. (1971). “Cores of Convex Games,” International Journal of Game Theory, 1: 1126.Google Scholar
Snyder, J. and Weingast, B. (2000). “The American System of Shared Powers: The President, Congress, and the NLRB,” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 16: 269305.Google Scholar
Spiller, P. and Urbiztondo, S. (1994). “Political Appointees vs. Career Civil Servants: A Multiple Principals Theory of Political Bureaucracies,” European Journal of Political Economy, 10: 465497.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Szentes, B. (2015). “Contractible Contracts in Common Agency Problems,” The Review of Economic Studies, 82: 391422.Google Scholar
Truman, D. (1951). The Government Process, Knopf, New York.Google Scholar
Warr, P. (1983). “The Private Provision of a Public Good is Independent of the Distribution of Income,” Economics Letters, 13: 207211.Google Scholar
Wilson, J. (1989). Bureaucracy, Basic Books, New York.Google Scholar
Yu, Z. (2005). “Environmental Protection: A Theory of Direct and Indirect Competition for Political Influence,” The Review of Economic Studies, 72: 269286.Google Scholar

Save element to Kindle

To save this element to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Reform for Sale
Available formats
×

Save element to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Reform for Sale
Available formats
×

Save element to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Reform for Sale
Available formats
×