from PART VII - ADVERSE SELECTION AND LIQUIDITY PROVISION
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 26 February 2018
Another issue brought to the fore by the crisis is the need to better understand the determinants of liquidity in financial markets. The notion that financial assets can always be sold at prices close to their fundamental values is built into most economic analysis…
(Ben Bernanke)As we discussed in Chapter 1, organising a market to ensure fair and orderly trading is by no means a trivial task. As we also discussed in Chapter 1, transactions can only take place if some market participants post binding quotes to the rest of the market, in the sense that they specify prices at which they agree to buy or sell a specified quantity of an asset. By posting these quotes, liquidity providers put themselves at risk, because liquidity takers can decide whether or not they want to accept these offers to trade – and will only do so if they believe that the price is favourable. Liquidity providers are therefore exposed to a systematic, adverse bias: while some trades are uninformed and innocuous, other trades may be informed and be followed by large price moves in the direction of the trade, to the detriment of the liquidity provider.
Given this seemingly unfavourable position, why do any market participants provide liquidity at all? The answer is that many liquidity-provision strategies, including the popular strategy of market-making, can be profitable in the long run because a large fraction of trades are in fact non-informed (or very weakly informed). As we noted in Section 1.3.2, the fundamental consideration for implementing these strategies in the long run is the balance between the mean size of the bid–ask spread and the mean strength of adverse impact.
In older financial markets, only a select few market participants were able to act as market-makers. Due to the large spreads that were typical of these markets, market-making was a highly profitable business for these individuals. In modern electronic markets, by contrast, any market participant can act as a market-maker. As we discuss in the chapter, this important change has made market-making a highly competitive business that is typically only marginally profitable.
In this chapter, we introduce and study some simple models that help to make our previous discussions of market-making and the bid–ask spread more precise.
To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.