Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-g7gxr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-05T11:07:51.816Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  18 October 2022

Peter E. Earl
Affiliation:
University of Queensland
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Principles of Behavioral Economics
Bringing Together Old, New and Evolutionary Approaches
, pp. 470 - 498
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2022

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abolafia, M. Y. (1996). Making Markets: Opportunism and Restraint on Wall Street. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Abolafia, M. Y. (1998). Markets as cultures: An ethnographic approach. Sociological Review, 46(May), 6985.Google Scholar
Ackley, G. (1961). Macroeconomics Theory. New York: Collier Macmillan.Google Scholar
Adams, T. F. N., & Kobayashi, N. (1969). The World of Japanese Business. London: Ward Lock.Google Scholar
Ainslie, G. (1992). Picoeconomics: The Strategic Interaction of Successive Motivational States within the Person. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Aitken, S. (Writer/Director). (2010). Seduction in the City: The Birth of Shopping. Sydney: Essential Media & Entertainment Pty. Ltd., Screen Australia, ARTE, Screen NSW, and Tel France Ltd.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G. A. (1970). The market for “lemons”: Quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(3), 486500.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G. A., & Dickens, W. T. (1982). The economic consequences of cognitive dissonance. American Economic Review, 72(3), 307319.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G. A., & Kranton, R. E. (2000). Economics and identity. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3, August), 715753.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G. A., & Kranton, R. E. (2010). Identity Economics: How Our Identities Shape Our Work, Wages, and Well-Being. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G. A., & Shiller, R. J (2009). Animal Spirits: How Human Psychology Drives the Economy, and Why It Matters for Global Capitalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G. A., & Shiller, R. J. (2015). Phishing for Phools: The Economics of Manipulation and Deception. Princeton, NJ, and Oxford: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G. A., & Yellen, J. L. (Eds.). (1986). Efficiency Wage Models of the Labor Market. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Alchian, A. (1950). Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory. Journal of Political Economy, 58(3, June), 211221.Google Scholar
Alchian, A. (1969). Information costs, pricing, and resource unemployment. Western Economic Journal (Economic Inquiry), 7(2), 109128.Google Scholar
Aldred, J. (2012). Climate change uncertainty, irreversibility and the precautionary principle. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 36(5), 10511072.Google Scholar
Aliber, R. Z., & Kindleberger, C. P. (2015). Manias, Panics and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises (7th ed.). Basingstoke: Palgrave.Google Scholar
American Psychiatric Association. (1980). Diagnostic and Statistical Manual of Mental Disorders (DSM–III) (3rd ed.). Washington, DC: American Psychiatric Association.Google Scholar
Ames, A. (1952). The Ames Demonstrations in Perception. New York: Hafner Publishing.Google Scholar
Anand, P. (1982). How to be right without being rational (the von Neumann & Morgenstern way). Oxford Agrarian Studies, 11(1), 158172.Google Scholar
Anderton, P. (2020). The Captain Meets His Dad The History of Andertons Music Co (L. Anderton, Interviewer). Video interview, March 29, 2020, YouTube. www.youtube.com/watch?v=MjT1XD0tKW0Google Scholar
Andreozzi, L., & Bianchi, M. (2007). Fashion: Why people like it and theorists do not. In Bianchi, M. (Ed.), The Evolution of Consumption: Theories and Practices. Advances in Austrian Economics, Volume 10 (pp. 209229). Oxford: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Andrews, P. W. S. (1949). Manufacturing Business. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Andrews, P. W. S. (1964). On Competition in Economic Theory. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Andrews, P. W. S. (1993). The Economics of Competitive Enterprise: Selected Essays of P. W. S. Andrews (Lee, F. S and Earl, P. E, Eds.). Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Andrews, P. W. S., & Brunner, E (1975). Studies in Pricing. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Ansoff, H. I. (1965). Corporate Strategy: An Analytic Approach to Business Policy for Growth and Expansion. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Aoki, M., Gustafson, B., & Williamson, O. E. (Eds.). (1990). The Firm as a Nexus of Treaties. London: Sage.Google Scholar
Ariely, D. (2008). Predictably Irrational: The Hidden Forces That Shape Our Decisions. New York: HarperCollins.Google Scholar
Arnould, E. J., & Price, L. L. (1993). River magic: Extraordinary experiences and the extended service encounter. Journal of Consumer Research, 20(1, June), 2445.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J. (1962). Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In Universities-National Bureau Committee for Economic Research and Committee on Economic Growth of the Social Science Research Council (Eds.), The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity: Economic and Social Factors (pp. 609626). Princeton, NJ: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Augier, M., & March, J. G. (2008). Realism and comprehension in economics: A footnote to an exchange between Oliver E. Williamson and Herbert A. Simon. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 66(1), 95105.Google Scholar
Baddeley, M. (2010). Herding, social influence and economic decision-making: Socio-psychological and neuroscientific analyses. Philosophical Transactions: Biological Sciences, 365(1538, January 27), 281290.Google Scholar
Baddeley, M. (2013). Behavioural Economics and Finance. London and New York: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bain, A. D. (1964). The Growth of Television Ownership in the United Kingdom since the War: A Lognormal Model. University of Cambridge, Department of Applied Economics Monographs, No. 12. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bannister, D., & Fransella, F. (1971). Inquiring Man: The Theory of Personal Constructs. Harmondsworth: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Barberis, N. C. (2013). Thirty years of prospect theory in economics: A review and assessment. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 27(1, Winter), 173196.Google Scholar
Barley, S. R. (2015). Why the Internet makes buying a car less loathsome: How technology changes role relations. Academy of Management Discoveries, 1(1), 3160.Google Scholar
Barnard, C. I. (1938). The Functions of the Executive. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Baumeister, R. F. (2014). Self-regulation, ego-depletion, and inhibition. Neuropsychologia, 65(December), 313319.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Baumeister, R. F., Bratslavsky, E., Muraven, M., & Tice, D. M. (1998). Ego depletion: Is the active self a limited resource? Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 74(5), 12521265.Google Scholar
Baumeister, R. F., Sparks, E. A., & Stillman, T. F. (2008). Free will in consumer behavior: Self-control, ego depletion, and choice. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 18(1), 413.Google Scholar
Baumol, W. J. (1959). Business Behavior, Value and Growth. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Baumol, W. J., Panzar, J., & Willig, R. (1982). Contestable Markets and the Theory of Industrial Structure. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.Google Scholar
Baumol, W. J., & Quandt, R. E. (1964). Rules of thumb and optimally imperfect decisions. American Economic Review, 54(2, March), 2346.Google Scholar
Bausor, R. (1982). Time and the structure of economic analysis. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 5(Winter), 163179.Google Scholar
Bausor, R. (1984). Towards a historically dynamic economics: Examples and illustrations. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 6(Spring), 360376.Google Scholar
Becker, G. S., & Murphy, K. (1988). A theory of rational addiction. Journal of Political Economy, 96(4), 675700.Google Scholar
Beckert, J. (2020). Markets from meaning: Quality uncertainty and the intersubjective construction of value. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 44(2, March), 285301.Google Scholar
Beiser, V. (2018). The World in a Grain: The Story of Sand and How It Transformed Civilization. New York: Riverhead Books/Penguin Random House.Google Scholar
Belsky, G., & Gilovich, T. (1999). Why Smart People Make Big Money Mistakes and How to Avoid Them. New York: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Benartzi, S., & Thaler, R. H. (2007). Heuristics and biases in retirement planning. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(3, Summer), 81104.Google Scholar
Berg, N., & Gigerenzer, G. (2010). As-if behavioral economics: Neoclassical economics in disguise? History of Economic Ideas, 18(1), 133166.Google Scholar
Berger, L. A. (1989). Economics and hermeneutics. Economics and Philosophy, 5(2, October), 209234.Google Scholar
Berle, A. A., & Means, G. C. (1932). The Modern Corporation and Private Property. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Berne, E. (1964). Games People Play: The Psychology of Human Relationships. Harmondsworth: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Bernstein, C., & Woodward, B. (1974). All the President’s Men. New York: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Bertrand, M., Mullanathan, S., & Shafir, E. (2004). A behavioral-economics view of poverty. American Economic Review, 94(2, May), 419423.Google Scholar
Bettman, J. R. (1979). An Information-Processing Theory of Consumer Choice. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.Google Scholar
Bezemer, D. J. (2009). “No one saw this coming”: Understanding financial crisis through accounting models. MPRA Paper No. 15892. Available online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/15892/Google Scholar
Bianchi, M. (Ed.) (1998). The Active Consumer: Novelty and Surprise in Consumer Choice. London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Bianchi, M., & Patalano, R. (2017). Storytelling and Choice. Rounded Globe eBook. Retrieved from https://roundedglobe.com/books/ad46e83f-b971–4a96–8efc-662855976998/Storytelling%20and%20Choice/Google Scholar
Bikhchandani, S., Hirshleifer, D., & Welch, I. (1992). A theory of fads, fashion, custom and cultural change. Journal of Political Economy, 100(5), 9921026.Google Scholar
Blatt, J. M. (1979). The utility of being hanged on the gallows. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 2(2), 231239.Google Scholar
Block, L. G. (1999). Fear appeal and persuasion. In Earl, P. E. & Kemp, S. (Eds.), The Elgar Companion to Consumer Research and Economic Psychology (pp. 239246). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Blois, K. J. (1972). Vertical quasi-integration. Journal of Industrial Economics, 20(3, July), 253272.Google Scholar
Boland, L. A. (1986). Methodology for a New Microeconomics: The Critical Foundations. Boston, MA: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Borg, L. (2001). Jeans leap ahead as the “Jeremy Clarkson effect” fades. The Daily Telegraph, 12 April. Available online at www.telegraph.co.uk/news/uknews/1315886/Jeans-leap-ahead-as-Jeremy-Clarkson-effect-fades.htmlGoogle Scholar
Bradbury, R. ([1953] 1977). A sound of thunder. In R. Bradbury, Golden Apples of the Sun (pp. 88–99). St Albans: Granada (originally published 1953, London: Rupert Hart-Davis).Google Scholar
Brooks, R. (2011). Sex, Genes and Rock ‘n’ Roll: How Evolution Has Shaped the Modern World. Sydney: University of New South Wales Press.Google Scholar
Bruni, L. (Ed.) (2021). A Modern Guide to the Economics of Happiness. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Burke, J. (Writer). (1989). After the Warming. Maryland Public Television/Film Australia/Wisemans/Electric Image/Principal Film Company.Google Scholar
Burnham, T. C., & Phelps, J. (2019). Ordinaries: Thomas Kuhn, Adam Smith, and Charles Darwin. Journal of Bioeconomics, 21(3, October), 145155.Google Scholar
Burns, T., & Stalker, G. M. (1961). The Management of Innovation. London: Tavistock Publications.Google Scholar
Butos, W. N. (Ed.) (2010). The Social Sciences of Hayek’s ‘The Sensory Order.’ Advances in Austrian Economics, Volume 13. Bingley: Emerald.Google Scholar
Cairncross, A. K. (1958). Economic schizophrenia. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 5(1, February), 1521.Google Scholar
Camerer, C., Babcock, L., Lowenstein, G., & Thaler, R. H. (1997). Labor supply of New York cabdrivers: One day at a time. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2, May), 407440.Google Scholar
Camerer, C., Issacharoff, S., Lowenstein, G., O’Donoghue, T., & Rabin, M. (2003). Regulation for conservatives: Behavioral economics and the case for “asymmetric paternalism.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 151(3), 12111254.Google Scholar
Camerer, C., & Vepsalainen, A. (1988). The economic efficiency of corporate culture. Strategic Management Journal, 9(Summer), 115126.Google Scholar
Cameron, S., & Golby, D. (1990). An economic analysis of personal debt. Bulletin of Economic Research, 42(3, July), 241247.Google Scholar
Carlson, S. (1951). Executive Behaviour. Stockholm: Stromberg.Google Scholar
Carter, C. F. (1953). A revised theory of expectations. Economic Journal, 63(252, December), 811820.Google Scholar
Cartwright, E. (2014). Behavioral Economics (2nd ed.). Abingdon and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Catmull, E. (2014). Creativity, Inc. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Celsi, R. L., Rose, R. L., & Leigh, T. W. (1993). An exploration of high-risk leisure consumption through skydiving. Journal of Consumer Research, 20(1, June), 123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chabris, C., & Simons, D. (2010). The Invisible Gorilla: How Our Intuitions Deceive Us. New York: Crown Publishers/Random House.Google Scholar
Chai, A., Earl, P. E., & Potts, J. (2007). Fashion, growth and welfare: An evolutionary approach. In Bianchi, M. (Ed.), The Evolution of Consumption: Theories and Practices. Advances in Austrian Economics, Volume 10 (pp. 187207). Oxford: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Chandler, A. D. (1962). Strategy and Structure: Chapters in the History of the American Industrial Enterprise. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Chandler, A. D. (1977). The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press/Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Chandler, A. D. (1990). Scale and Scope: The Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press/Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Chang, H.-J. (2010). 23 Things They Don’t Tell You About Capitalism. London: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Chase, W. G., & Simon, H. A. (1973). Perception in chess. Cognitive Psychology, 4(1, January), 5581.Google Scholar
Choi, Y. B. (1993). Paradigms and Conventions: Uncertainty, Decision Making and Entrepreneurship. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Christandl, F., & Fetchenhauer, D. (2009). How laypeople and experts misperceive the effect of economic growth. Journal of Economic Psychology, 30(3), 381392.Google Scholar
Christensen, C. (1997). The Innovator’s Dilemma: When New Technologies Cause Great Firms to Fail. Boston, MA: Harvard Business Review Press.Google Scholar
Cialdini, R. B. (1984). Influence: The Psychology of Persuasion. New York: William Morrow & Company.Google Scholar
Cialdini, R. B. (2009). Influence: Science and Practice (5th ed.). Boston, MA: Pearson Education.Google Scholar
Cialdini, R. B. (Writer). (2014). The Power of Persuasion (Stanfor Business Breakfast Presentation). San Francisco, CA: Kanopy Streaming.Google Scholar
Clydesdale, G. (2021). Reducing Inter-generational Ethnic Poverty: Economics, Psychology and Culture. Abingdon and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica (New Series), 4(16, November), 386405.Google Scholar
Coddington, A. (1976). Keynesian economics: The search for first principles. Journal of Economics Literature, 14(4, December), 12581273.Google Scholar
Coddington, A. (1982). Deficient foresight: A troublesome theme in Keynesian economics. American Economics Review, 72(3, June), 480487.Google Scholar
Coelli, T., Rao, D. S. P., O’Donnell, C. J., & Battese, G. E. (2005). An Introduction to Efficiency and Productivity Analysis (2nd ed.). New York: Springer.Google Scholar
Cohen, J. L., & Dickens, W. T. (2002). A foundation for behavioral economics. American Economic Review, 92(2), 335338.Google Scholar
Cohen, M. D., March, J. G., & Olsen, J. P. (1972). A garbage can model of organizational choice. Administrative Sciences Quarterly, 17(1, March), 125.Google Scholar
Cooper, R. A., Hartley, K., & Harvey, C. R. M. (1970). Export Performance and the Pressure of Demand: A Study of Firms. London: Allen & Unwin (Reprinted 2018 London: Routledge).Google Scholar
Cosmides, L., & Tooby, J. (1994). Better than rational: Evolutionary psychology and the invisible hand. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 84(2), 327332.Google Scholar
Coutts, K., Godley, W., & Nordhaus, W. (1978). Industrial Pricing in the United Kingdom. University of Cambridge, Department of Applied Economics, Monograph 26. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Cripps, F., & Godley, W. (1978). Control over imports as a means to full employment and the expansion of world trade: The UK’s case. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 2(3, September), 327334.Google Scholar
Csibra, G., & Gergely, G. (2011). Natural pedagogy as an evolutionary adaptation. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society (B), 366, 11491157.Google Scholar
Csikszentmihalyi, M. (1990). Flow: The Psychology of Optimal Experience. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Cunningham, M. T., & White, J. G. (1974). The behaviour of industrial buyers in their search for supplier of machine tools. Journal of Management Studies, 11(May), 115128.Google Scholar
Cyert, R. M., Feigenbaum, E. A., & March, J. G. (1959). Models in a behavioral theory of the firm. Behavioral Science, 4(2, April), 8196.Google Scholar
Cyert, R. M., & March, J. G. (1955). Organizational structure and pricing behavior in an oligopoly. American Economic Review, 45(1, March), 129139.Google Scholar
Cyert, R. M., & March, J. G. (1956). Organizational factors in the theory of oligopoly. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70(1, February), 4464.Google Scholar
Cyert, R. M., & March, J. G. (1963). A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall (2nd ed. 1992, Malden, MA and Oxford: Blackwell).Google Scholar
Daly, J., Mercer, D., & Kuang, W. (2021). Is the dream over? Amid China’s trade war, producers grapple with new world order. ABC Rural News, 16 May. Australian Broadcasting Corporation. Available online at www.abc.net.au/news/rural/2021-05-17/after-12-months-of-the-trade-war-is-the-china-dream-over/100127874Google Scholar
Daly, M. T. (1982). Sydney Boom, Sydney Bust: The City and Its Property Market, 1854–1981. Sydney: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Damasio, A. (1994). Descartes’ Error: Emotion, Reason, and the Human Brain. New York: Putnam.Google Scholar
Darby, M. R., & Karni, E. (1973). Free competition and the optimal amount of fraud. Journal of Law & Economics, 16(1, April), 6788.Google Scholar
Davies, J. E., & Lee, F. S. (1988). A post Keynesian appraisal of the contestability criterion. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 11(1, Autumn), 325.Google Scholar
Day, R. H. (1967). Profits, learning and the convergence of satisficing to marginalism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 81(2), 302311.Google Scholar
de Montaigne, M. ([1533–1592] 1963). Essays and Selected Writings (bilingual edition, translated and edited by D. M. Frame). New York: St Martin’s.Google Scholar
De Vany, A. (2004). Hollywood Economics: How Extreme Uncertainty Shapes the Film Industry. London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
DellaVigna, S., & Malmedier, U. (2004). Contract design and self-control: Theory and evidence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(2, May), 353402.Google Scholar
DellaVigna, S., & Malmedier, U. (2006). Paying not to go to the gym. American Economic Review, 96(3), 694719.Google Scholar
DeRiviere, L. (2008). Do economists need to rethink their approaches to modeling intimate partner violence? Journal of Economic Issues, 42(3, September), 583606.Google Scholar
DeVoe, C. (2019). Dentists with Alembics. Steve Hoffman’s Music Forums, https://forums.stevehoffman.tv/threads/dentists-with-alembics.887394/Google Scholar
Dewey, J. (1910). How We Think. New York: D. C. Heath.Google Scholar
Dhami, S. (2016). The Foundations of Behavioral Economics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Diderot, D. (1775–1777). Regrets sur ma vieille robe de chambre [Regrets on my old dressing gown]. In Assézat, J. & Tourneux, M. (Eds.), Miscellanea Philosophiques (pp. 512). Paris: Garnier (via Wikisource).Google Scholar
Dittmar, H. (1992). The Social Psychology of Material Possessions: To Have is to Be. Hemel Hempstead: Harvester Wheatsheaf.Google Scholar
Doidge, N. (2007). The Brain that Changes Itself: Stories of Personal Triumph from the Frontiers of Brain Science. New York: Viking Penguin.Google Scholar
Dopfer, K. (2012). The origins of meso economics. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 22(1), 133160.Google Scholar
Dopfer, K., Foster, J., & Potts, J. (2004). Micro-meso-macro. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 14(3), 263279.Google Scholar
Dore, R. P. (1973). British Factory, Japanese Factory: The Origins of National Diversity in Industrial Relations. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Dore, R. P. (2012). Flexible Rigidities: Industrial Policy and Structural Adjustment in the Japanese Economy, 1970–1980. London: Bloomsbury.Google Scholar
Dow, A., & Dow, S. C. (2011). Animal spirits revisited. Capitalism and Society, 6(2), Article 1, 25. Available online at https://papers.ssrn.com/sol23/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2208040Google Scholar
Dow, S. C. (2013). Formalism, rationality, and evidence: The case of behavioural economics. Erasmus Journal for Philosophy and Economics, 6(3, Special Issue), 2643.Google Scholar
Dow, S. C. (2014). Animal spirits and organization. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 37(2), 211231.Google Scholar
Dow, S. C., & Earl, P. E. (1982). Money Matters: A Keynesian Approach to Monetary Economics. Oxford: Martin Robertson.Google Scholar
Downie, J. (1958). The Competitive Process. London: Duckworth.Google Scholar
Drakopoulos, S. A. (1994). Hierarchical choice in economics. Journal of Economic Surveys, 8(2), 133153.Google Scholar
Drakopoulos, S. A., & Karayiannis, A. D. (2004). The historical development of hierarchical behavior in economic thought. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 26(3), 363378.Google Scholar
Duesenberry, J. S. (1949). Income, Saving and the Theory of Consumer Behavior. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Duggan, V. (2018). “That’s insane… did they guarantee everything?”: Reliving the night of the bank bailout. The Journal, 30 September. Available online at www.thejournal.ie/readme/night-of-the-bank-guarantee-4258897-Sep2018/Google Scholar
Duhen, P. M. M. (1906). The Aim and Structure of Physical Theory. (Translated by P. Weiner.) Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Dunn, S. P. (2000). Fundamental uncertainty and the firm in the long run. Review of Political Economy, 12(4), 419433Google Scholar
Dutton, D. (2003). Aesthetics and evolution. In Levinson, J. (Ed.), The Oxford Handbook of Aesthetics (pp. 693705). New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Eagleman, D., & Brandt, A. (2017). The Runaway Species: How Human Creativity Remakes the World. Edinburgh: Canongate.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (1983a). A behavioral theory of economists’ behavior. In Eichner, A. S (Ed.), Why Economics is Not Yet a Science (pp. 90125). Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe (London: Macmillan).Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (1983b). The consumer in his/her social setting: A subjectivist view. In Wiseman, J. (Ed.), Beyond Positive Economics? (pp. 176191). London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (1983c). The Economic Imagination: Towards a Behavioral Analysis of Choice. Brighton: Wheatsheaf.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (1984). The Corporate Imagination: How Big Companies Make Mistakes. Brighton: Wheatsheaf.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (1986a). A behavioural analysis of demand elasticities. Journal of Economic Studies, 13(3), 2037.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (1986b). Lifestyle Economics: Consumer Behaviour in a Turbulent World. Brighton: Wheatsheaf.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (Ed.) (1988). Behavioural Economics. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (1990). Monetary Scenarios: A Modern Approach to Financial System. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (1992). On the complementarity of economic applications of cognitive dissonance theory and personal construct psychology. In Lea, S. E. G., Webley, P., & Young, B. (Eds.), New Directions in Economic Psychology (pp. 4965). Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (1995). Microeconomics for Business and Marketing: Lectures, Cases and Worked Essays. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (1996). Contracts, coordination, and the construction industry. In Earl, P. E. (Ed.), Management, Marketing, and the Competitive Process (pp. 149171). Cheltenham: Edward Elgart.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (2001). Simon’s Travel Theorem and the demand for live music. Journal of Economic Psychology, 22(3, June), 335358.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (2002). Information, Opportunism and Economic Coordination. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (2003). The entrepreneur as a constructor of connections. In Koppl, R. (Ed.), Austrian Economics and Entrepreneurial Studies. Advances in Austrian Economics, Volume 6 (pp. 113130). Oxford: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (2009). Update on censorship of critique of emissions trading schemes. Eclectic Real-World Economics. Posted 6 December, at https://shredecon.wordpress.com/2009/12/06/update-on-censorship-of-critique-of-emssions-trading-schemes/Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (2011). From anecdotes to novels: Reflective inputs for behavioural economic. New Zealand Economic Papers, 45(1/2), 522.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (2012). Experiential analysis of automotive consumption. Journal of Business Research, 65(7, July), 10671072.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (2013). The robot, the party animal and the philosopher: An evolutionary perspective on deliberation and preference. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 37(6, November), 12631282.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (2017a). Lifestyle changes and the lifestyle selection process. Journal of Bioeconomics, 19(1, April), 97114.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (2017b). The evolution of behavioural economics. In Frantz, R., Chen, S.-H., Dopfer, K., Heukelom, F., & Mousavi, S. (Eds.), Routledge Handbook of Behavioral Economics (pp. 517). London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (2018). Richard H. Thaler: A Nobel prize for behavioural economics. Review of Political Economy, 30(2), 107125.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (2020a). COVID-19 macroeconomics from the standpoint of Keynes’s “How to Pay for the War.” Eclectic Real-World Economics. Posted 21 March, at https://shredecon.wordpress.com/2020/03/21/covid-19-macroeconomics-from-the-standpoint-of-keyness-how-to-pay-for-the-war/Google Scholar
Earl, P. E. (2020b). Is it inevitable that macroeconomic stimulus packages “ultimately have to be paid for” after the COVID-19 recession is over? Eclectic Real-World Economics. Posted 6 August, at https://shredecon.wordpress.com/2020/08/06/is-it-inevitable-that-macroeconomic-stimulus-packages-ultimately-have-to-be-paid-for-after-the-covid-19-recession-is-over/Google Scholar
Earl, P. E., Friesen, L., & Shadforth, C. (2017). The efficiency of market-assisted choices: An experimental analysis of mobile phone connection service recommendations. Journal of Institutional Economics, 13(4), 849873.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E., Friesen, L., & Shadforth, C. (2019). Elusive optima: A process-tracing analysis of procedural rationality in mobile phone connection plan choices. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 161, 303322.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E., & Glaister, K. W. ([1979] 1980). Wage stickiness from the demand side. University of Stirling Discussion Papers in Economics, Finance, and Investment, No. 78 [December 1979]. Slightly revised (1980) journal submission version available online at https://shredecon.files.wordpress.com/2021/01/earl-and-glaister-1980wage-stickiness.pdfGoogle Scholar
Earl, P. E., & Littleboy, B. (2014). G. L. S. Shackle. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E., & Peng, T.-C. (2012). Brands of economics and the Trojan horse of pluralism. Review of Political Economy, 24(3, July), 451467.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E., Peng, T.-C., & Potts, J. (2007). Decision rule cascades and the dynamics of speculative bubbles. Journal of Economic Psychology, 18(3, June), 351364.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E., & Potts, J. (2000). Latent demand and the browsing shopper. Managerial and Decision Economics, 21(3–4), 1122.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E., & Potts, J. (2004). The market for preferences. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 28(4), 619633.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E., & Potts, J. (2013). The creative instability hypothesis. Journal of Cultural Economics, 37(2), 153173.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E., & Potts, J. (2016). The management of creative vision and the economics of creative cycles. Managerial and Decision Economics, 37(7, October), 474484.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E., & Wakeley, T. (2005). Business Economics: A Contemporary Approach. Maidenhead: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E., & Wakeley, T. (2009). Price-based versus standards-based approaches to reducing car addiction and other environmentally destructive activities. In Holt, R. P. F., Pressman, S., & Spash, C. L. (Eds.), Post Keynesian and Ecological Economics (pp. 221236). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E., & Wakeley, T. (2010). Economic perspectives on the development of complex products for increasingly demanding customers. Research Policy, 39(8, October), 11221132.Google Scholar
Earl, P. E., & Wicklund, R. A. (1999). Cognitive dissonance. In Earl, P. E. & Kemp, S. (Eds.), The Elgar Companion to Consumer Research and Economic Psychology (pp. 8188). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Easterlin, R. A. (1974). Does economic growth improve the human lot? Some empirical evidence. In David, P. A. & Reder, M. W. (Eds.), Nations and Households in Economic Growth: Essays in Honor of Moses Abramovitz (pp. 89125). New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Easterlin, R. A. (1995). Will raising the incomes of all increase the happiness of all? Journal of Economic Behavioor and Organization, 27(1), 3547.Google Scholar
Easterlin, R. A. (Ed.) (2002). Happiness in Economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Economist (2011). Burberry and globalization: A checkered story: Burberry’s revival reflects the power of globalisation, and its limits’, The Economist, 20 January. Available online at www.economist.com/node/17963363?story_id=17963363Google Scholar
Edwardes, M. (1983). Back from the Brink. London: Collins.Google Scholar
Ehrenberg, A., & Scriven, , J. (1999). Brand loyalty. In Earl, P. E. & Kemp, S. (Eds.), The Elgar Companion to Consumer Research and Economic Psychology (pp. 5263). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Elster, J. (1983). Sour Grapes: Studies in the Subversion of Rationality. New York: Paris Cambridge University Press and Editions de la Maison des Sciences de l’Homme.Google Scholar
Elster, J. (1984). Ulysses and the Sirens: Studies in Rationality and Irrationality (rev. ed.). New York: Cambridge University Press; Paris: Editions de la Maison des Sciences de l’Homme.Google Scholar
Elster, J., & Lowenstein, G. (1992). Utility from memory and anticipation. In Lowenstein, G. & Elster, J. (Eds.), Choice Over Time (pp. 213234). New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Endres, A. M. (1991). Marshall’s analysis of economising behaviour with particular reference to consumption. European Economic Review, 35(2, April), 333341.Google Scholar
Endres, A. M., & Harper, D. A. (2012). The kinetics of capital formation and economic organisation. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 36(4), 963980.Google Scholar
Endres, A. M., & Harper, D. A. (2020). Economic development and complexity: The role of recombinant capital. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 44(1, January), 157180.Google Scholar
Engel, J. F., Kollat, D. T., & Blackwell, R. D. (1968). Consumer Behavior. Hinsdale, IL: Dryden Press.Google Scholar
Ericsson, K. A., & Simon, H. A. (1993). Protocol Analysis: Verbal Reports as Data (rev. ed.). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Esteves, P. S., & Rua, A. (2015). Is there a role for domestic demand pressure on export performance? Empirical Economics, 49(4), 11731189.Google Scholar
Etzioni, A. (1988). The Moral Dimension: Toward a New Economics. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Fairlie, S. (2010). Meat: A Benign Extravagance. East Meon: Permanent Publications.Google Scholar
Fasolo, B., McClelland, G. H., & Todd, P. M. (2007). Escaping the tyranny of choice: When fewer attributes make choice easier. Marketing Theory, 7(1), 1326.Google Scholar
Fellner, W., , & Goehmann, B. (2020). Human needs, consumerism and welfare. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 44(2), 303318.Google Scholar
Ferguson, N., & Schularick, M. (2007). Chimerica and the global asset market boom. International Finance, 10(3), 215239.Google Scholar
Fernandez, K. V., & Lastovicka, J. L. (2011). Making magic: Fetishes in contemporary consumption. Journal of Consumer Research, 38(2, August), 278299.Google Scholar
Festinger, L. (1957). A Theory of Cognitive Dissonance. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Fishbein, M., & Ajzen, I. (1975). Belief, Attitude, Intention, and Behavior. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.Google Scholar
Foley, C. A. (1893). Fashion. Economic Journal, 3(11, September), 458474.Google Scholar
Foss, N. J. (Ed.) (1997). Resources, Firms and Strategies: A Reader in the Resource-Based Perspective. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Foss, N. J., & Knudsen, C. (Eds.) (1996). Towards a Competence theory of the Firm. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Foxall, G. (1990). Consumer Psychology in Behavioural Perspective. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Frank, E. (Director). (2016). Victorian Slum [DVD]. UK: Dazzler Media (DVD)/Amazon Instant View.Google Scholar
Frank, R. H. (2007). Does context matter more for some goods than others? In Bianchi, M. (Ed.), The Evolution of Consumption: Theories and Practices. Advances in Austrian Economics, Volume 10 (pp. 231248). Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Frankel, M. (1955). Obsolescence and technical change in maturing economies. American Economic Review, 45(June), 296319.Google Scholar
Frantz, R., & Leeson, R. (Eds.) (2013). Hayek and Behavioral Economics. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. (1953). The methodology of positive economics. In Friedman, M. (Ed.), Essays in Positive Economics (pp. 343). Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, T. L. (1999). The Lexus and the Olive Tree: Understanding Globalization. London: HarperCollins.Google Scholar
Friesen, L., & Earl, P. E. (2015). Multipart tariffs and bounded rationality: An experimental analysis of mobile phone plan choices. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 116(August), 239253.Google Scholar
Friesen, L., & Earl, P. E. (2020). An experimental analysis of regulatory interventions for complex pricing. Southern Economic Journal, 86(3), 12411266.Google Scholar
Friston, K. (2010). The free-energy principle: A unified brain theory? Nature Reviews Neuroscience, 11(2), 127138.Google Scholar
Frost, R. O., & Stekatee, G. (2010). Stuff: Compulsive Hoarding and the Meaning of Things. Boston, MA and New York: Houghton Mifflin Harcourt.Google Scholar
Fry, A., & Silver, S. (2010). First person: We invented the post-it note. FT Magazine, 3 December. Available at www.ft.com/cms/s/2/f08e8a9a-fcd7-11df-ae2d-00144feab49a.html#axzz18hyDnyKXGoogle Scholar
Fullbrook, E. (1998). Caroline Foley and the theory of intersubjective demand. Journal of Economic Issues, 32(3), 709731.Google Scholar
Gabaix, X., & Laibson, D. (2006). Shrouded attributes: Consumer myopia, and information suppression in competitive markets. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(2, May), 505540.Google Scholar
Gabor, A., & Granger, C. W. J. (1966). Price as an indicator of quality: Report on an enquiry. Economica, 33(129, February), 4370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galbraith, J. K. (1958). The Affluent Society. London: Hamish Hamilton.Google Scholar
Garfinkel, H. (1967). Studies in Ethnomethodology. Engleood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Genicot, A., & Ray, A. (2017). Aspirations and inequality. Econometrica, 85(2, March), 489519.Google Scholar
Georgescu-Roegen, N. (1971). The Entropy Law and the Economic Process. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, G. (2015). On the supposed evidence for libertarian paternalism. Review of Philosophy and Psychology, 6(3, September), 361383.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, G., & Brighton, H. (2009). Homo Heuristicus: Why biased minds make better inferences. Topics in Cognitive Sciences, I(1), 107143.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, G., & Goldstein, D. G. (1996). Reasoning the fast and frugal way: Models of bounded rationality. Psychological Review, 103(4), 650669.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, G., Todd, P. M., & the ABC Research Group (1999). Simple Heuristics that Make Us Smart. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Gilleard, C. (1999). McClelland hypothesis. In Earl, P. E. & Kemp, S. (Eds.), The Elgar Companion to Consumer Research and Economic Psychology (pp. 380382). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Gimpl, M. L., & Dakin, S. R. (1984). Management and magic. California Management Review, 27(1, October), 125136.Google Scholar
Godley, W., & Lavoie, M. (2007). Monetary Economics: An Integrated Approach to Credit, Money, Income, Production and Wealth. Basingstoke: Palgrave.Google Scholar
Goldratt, E. (2004). The Goal: A Process of Ongoing Improvment (Third Revised Edition). Great Barrington, MA: North Rivers Press.Google Scholar
Gomes-Casseres, B. (2009). NUMMI: What Toyota learned and GM didn’t. Harvard Business Review Blog. Posted September 1 at https://hbr.org/2009/09/nummi-what-toyota-learneGoogle Scholar
Goodhart, C. A. E. (2008). Risk, uncertainty and financial stability (2nd G. L. S. Shackle biennial memorial lecture, St Edmund’s College, Cambridge, 6 March. LSE Financial Markets Group Paper Series. London School of Economics. London. Available online at www.lse.ac.uk/fmg/assets/documents/papers/special-papers/SP178.pdfGoogle Scholar
Gould, S. J. (1991). The self-manipulation of my pervasive, perceived vital energy through product use: An introspective-praxis perspective. Journal of Consumer Research, 18(September), 194207.Google Scholar
Gould, S. J. (1993). The circle of projection and introjection: An introspective investigation of a proposed paradigm involving the mind as a “consuming organ”. In Costa, K. A. & Belk, R. W. (Eds.), Research in Consumer Behavior (pp. 185230). Greenwich, CT: Association for Consumer Research.Google Scholar
Gould, S. J. (1995). Researcher introspection as a method in consumer research: Applications, issues and implications. Journal of Consumer Research, 21(Mach), 719722.Google Scholar
Gouldner, A. W. (1954). Patterns of Industrial Bureaucracy. Glencoe, IL: Free Press.Google Scholar
Granovetter, M. (1985). Economic action and social structure: The problem of embeddedness. American Journal of Sociology, 91(3, November), 481510.Google Scholar
Grant, A. T. K. (1977). Economic Uncertainty and Financial Structure. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Green, S. (1988). Understanding corporate culture and its relation to strategy. International Studies of Managment & Organization, 18(2, Summer), 628.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Griliches, Z. (1957). Hybrid corn: An exploration in the economics of technological change. Econmetrica, 25(4, October), 501522.Google Scholar
Grimsdale, P. (Writer). (1990). Nippon: Japan since 1945 (Part 5: Taking on Detroit). London: BBC.Google Scholar
Grove, A. S. (1996). Only the Paranoid Survive. New York: Doubleday Business.Google Scholar
Grüne-Yanoff, T., & Hertwig, R. (2016). Nudge versus Boost: How coherence are policy and theory? Minds and Machines, 26(1–2), 149183.Google Scholar
Grubb, M. D. (2015). Failing to choose the best price: Theory, evidence and policy. Review of Industrial Organization, 47 (3), 303340.Google Scholar
Grupp, H., & Maital, S. (2001). Managing New Product Development and Innovation: A Microeconomic Toolbox. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Güth, W., & Weiland, T. (2011). Aspiration formation and satisficing in search with(out) competition. New Zealand Economic Papers, 45(1–2, April–August), 2345.Google Scholar
Gutman, J. (1982). A means–end chain model based on consumer categorization processes. Journal of Marketing, 46(2, Spring), 6072.Google Scholar
Gutman, J., & Alden, S. D. (1985). Adolescents’ cognitive structures of retail stores and fashion consumption: A means–end chain analysis of quality. In Jacoby, J & Olson, J. C. (Eds.), Perceived Quality (pp. 99114). Lexington, MA: D. C. Heath (for New York University Institute of Retail Management)Google Scholar
Hall, R. L., & Hitch, C. J. (1939). Price theory and business behaviour. Oxford Economic Papers, Old Series 2(1), 1245.Google Scholar
Hamilton, C. (2003). Growth Fetish. Crows Nest: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Hanson, J. D., & Kysar, D. A. (1999a). Taking behavioralism seriously: The problem of market manipulation. New York University Law Review, 74(3), 630749.Google Scholar
Hanson, J. D., & Kysar, D. A. (1999b). Taking behavioralism seriously: Some evidence of market manipulation. Harvard Law Review, 112(7, May), 14201572.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hanson, P. G. (2013). The Joy of Stress. Atascadero, CA: SressworksGoogle Scholar
Hare, P. (2010). Vodka and Pickled Cabbage: Eastern European Travels of a Professional Economist. London: Athena PressGoogle Scholar
Harper, D. A. (1996). Entrepreneurship and the Market Process. London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Harper, D. A., & Earl, P. E. (1996). Growth of knowledge perspectives on business behaviour. In Earl, P. E. (Ed.), Management, Marketing and the Competitive Process (pp. 306328). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Harper, D. A., & Endres, A. M. (2010). Capital as a layer cake: A systems approach to capital and its multi-level structure. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 74(1), 3041.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harper, D. A., & Endres, A. M. (2012). The anatomy of emergence, with a focus upon capital formation. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 82(2), 352367.Google Scholar
Harper, D. A., & Endres, A. M. (2017). From Quaker Oats to Virgin Bridge: Brand capital as a complex adaptive system. Journal of Institutional Economics, 14(6, December), 10711096.Google Scholar
Harrigan, K. R. (1980). Strategies for Declining Businesses. Lexington, MA: Lexington Boos/D.C. Heath.Google Scholar
Hart, N. (2013). Alfred Marshall and Modern Economics. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Harvey, J. T. (2006). Psychological and institutional forces and the determination of exchange rates. Journal of Economics Issues, 40(1), 153170.Google Scholar
Harvey, J. T. (2009a). Currencies, Capital Flows and Crises: A Post Keynesian Analysis of Exchange Rate Determination. London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Harvey, J. T. (2009b). Currency market participants’ mental models and the collapse of the dollar 2001–2008. Journal of Economic Issues, 43(4), 931949.Google Scholar
Hawtrey, R. G. (1926). The Economic Problem. London: Longmans, Green & Co.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1952). The Sensory Order: An Inquiry into the Foundations of Theoretical Psychology. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Heath, C., & Heath, D. (2010). Switch: How to Change Things When Change is Hard. New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Heiner, R. A. (1983). The origin of predictable behavior. American Economic Review, 73(September), 560595.Google Scholar
Heiner, R. A. (1986). The economics of information when decisions are imperfect. In MacFadyen, A. J. & MacFadyen, H. W. (Eds.), Economic Psychology: Intersection in Theory and Application (pp. 293350). Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Hertwig, R. (2017). When to consider boosting: Some rules for policy-makers. Behavioral Public Policy, 1(3), 143162.Google Scholar
Heukelom, F. (2014). Behavioral Economics: A History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hey, J. D. (1982). Search for rules for search. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 3(1), 6581.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. R.(1935). Annual survey of economic theory: The theory of monopoly. Econometrica, 2(1, January).Google Scholar
Hicks, J. R. (1939). Value and Capital. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. R. (1974). The Crisis in Keynesian Economics. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. R., & Allen, R. G. D. (1934a). A reconsideration of the theory of value (Part I). Economica (New Series), 1(1, February), 5276.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hicks, J. R., & Allen, R. G. D. (1934b). A reconsieration of the theory of value (Part II). Economica (New Series), 1(2, May), 196219.Google Scholar
Hinkle, D. N. (2010 [1965]). The change of personal constructs from the viewpoint of a theory of construct implications. (PhD dissertation, Ohio State University, 1965). Personal Construct Theory and Practice, 7(Supp. No. 1), 161.Google Scholar
Hirsch, F. (1976). Social Limits to Growth. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hirschman, A. O. (1970). Exit, Voice and Loyalty. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (1988). Economics and Institutions: A Manifesto for a Modern Institutional Economics. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (1994). Optimisation and evolution: Winter’s critique of Friedman revisited. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 18(4, August), 413439.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (1997). The ubiquity of habits and rules. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 21(6), 663684.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2003). The hidden persuaders: Institutions and individuals in economic theory. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 27(2), 159175.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2004). Opportunism is not the only reason why firms exist: Why an explanatory emphasis on opportunism may mislead management strategy. Industrial and Corporate Change, 13(2), 401418.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2010). Choice, habit and evolution. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 20(1), 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hofstadter, D. R. (1979). Godel, Escher, Bach: An Eternll Golden Braid. Hassocks, Sussex: Harvester Press.Google Scholar
Holbrook, M. B. (1995). Consumer Research: Introspective Essays on the Study of Consumption. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.Google Scholar
Holmes, P. M. (1978). Industrial Pricing Behaviour and Devaluation. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Horne, D. (1964). The Lucky Country: Australia in the Sixties. Ringwood, VIC: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Hsiao, Y. C. (2018). An Experimental Investigation of the Secretary Problem: Factors Affecting Sequential Search. PhD dissertation, University of Canterbury.Google Scholar
Huising, R., & Silbey, S. (2018). From nudge to culture and back again: Coalface governance in the regulated organization. Annual Review of Law and Social Sciences, 14, 91114.Google Scholar
Hutchison, T. W. (1938). The Significance and Basic Postulates of Economics. London: Macmillan (reprinted in 1965, New York: Augustus M. Kelley).Google Scholar
Hutchison, T. W. (1977a). Keynes Versus the Keynesians …?: An Essay in the Thinking of J. M. Keynes and the Accuracy of its Interpretation by his Followers. London: Institute of Economic Affairs.Google Scholar
Hutchison, T. W. (1977b). Knowledge and Ignorance in Economics. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Ironmonger, D. S. (1972). New Commodities and Consumer Behaviour. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Irving, J. (1978). P. W. S. Andrews and the Unsuccessful Revolution. Ph.D. dissertation, University of Wollongong, NSW.Google Scholar
Irving, J. L., & Feschback, S. (1954). Personality differences associated with responsiveness to fear-arousing communications. Journal of Personality, 23(2), 178188.Google Scholar
Irwin, H. S. (1937). The nature of risk assumption in the trading on organized exchanges. American Economic Review, 27(2, June), 267278.Google Scholar
Iyengar, S. S., & Lepper, M. R. (2000). When choice is demotivating: Can one desire too much of a good thing? Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 79(6), 9951006.Google Scholar
Jackson, D., Turner, H. A., & Wilkinson, F. (1972). Do Trade Unions Cause Inflation? University of Cambridge Department of Applied Economics Occasional Paper 36. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Jacobsen, L. (2017). Andrews’, P. W. S Manufacturing Business reconsidered. Review of Political Economy, 29(2), 190208.Google Scholar
Jefferson, M. (1983). Economic uncertainty and business decision-making. In Wiseman, J (Ed.), Beyond Positive Economics? Proceedings of Section F (Economics) of the British Association for the Advancement of Science, York 1981 (pp. 132159). London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Jefferson, M. (2012). Shell scenarios: What really happened in the 1970s and what may be learned for current world prospects. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 79, 186197.Google Scholar
Jefferson, M. (2014). The passage of time: Shackle, Shell and scenarios. In Earl, P. E. & Littleboy, B. (Eds.), G. L. S. Shackle (Great Thinkers in Economics) (pp. 190214). Basingstoke: Palagrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Jevons, W. S. (1905). Essays on Economics. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Jolls, C., Sunstein, C. R., & Thaler, R. H. (1998). A behavioral approach to law and economics. Stanford Law Review, 50, 14711550.Google Scholar
Jones, J. M., & Jetten, J. (2011). Recovering from strain and enduring pain: Multiple group memberships promote resilience in the face of physical challenges. Social Psychology and Personality Science, 2(3), 239244.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. (2011). Thinking, Fast and Slow. New York: Farrar, Strauss & Giroux.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. H. (1986). Fairness as a constraint on profit seeking entitlements in the market. American Economic Review, 76(4, September), 728741.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. H. (1990). Experimental tests of the endowment effect and the Coase theorem. Journal of Political Economy, 98(6), 13251348.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L & Thaler, R. H. (1991). Anomalies: The endowment effect, loss aversion and status quo bias. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1m Winter), 193206.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1972). Subjective probability: A judgment of representativeness. Cognitive Psychology, 3(3), 430454.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263291.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. (1955). An Expenditure Tax. London: George Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Kamstra, M., Kramer, L., & Levi, M. (2002). Winter Blues: A SAD Stock Market Cycle. Working Paper. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta. Atlanta, GA.Google Scholar
Kaptein, M. (2017). The battle for business ethics: A struggle theory. Journal of Business Ethics, 144(2, August), 343361.Google Scholar
Katona, G. (1951). Psychological Analysis of Economic Behavior. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Katona, G. A. (1960). The Powerful Consumer: Psychological Studies of the American Economy. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Katona, G., & Strumpel, B. (1976). Consumer investment versus business investment. Challenge, 18(6, January), 1216.Google Scholar
Katzev, R. D., & Johnson, T. R. (1983). A social-psychological analysis of residential electricity consumption: The impact of minimal justification techniques. Journal of Economic Psychology, 3(3–4), 267284.Google Scholar
Katzev, R. D., & Johnson, T. R. (1984). Comparing the effects of monetary incentives and foot‐in‐the‐door strategies in promoting residential electricity conservation. Journal of Applied Social Psychology, 14(1), 1227.Google Scholar
Kay, N. M. (1979 The Innovating Firm: A Behavioural Theory of Corporate R&D. London: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Kay, N. M. (1982). The Evolving Firm: Strategy and Structure in Industrial Organization. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Kay, N. M. (1984). The Emergent Firm: Knowledge, Ignorance and Surprise in Economic Organization. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Kay, N. M. (1997). Pattern in Corporate Evolution. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Kelly, G. A. (1955). The Psychology of Personal Constructs. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Kelly, G. A. (1963). A Theory of Personality. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Kelly, G. A. (1969). The autobiography of a theory. In Maher, B (Ed.), Clinical Psychology and Personality Theory: The Collected Papers of G. A. Kelly. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Kets de Vries, M. F. R., & Miller, D. (1984). The Neurotic Organization: Diagnosing and Changing Counterproductive Styles of Management. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass.Google Scholar
Kets de Vries, M. F. R., & Miller, D. (1988). Personality, culture and organization. In Albanese, P. J. (Ed.), Psychological Foundations of Economic Behavior (pp. 8299). New York: Praeger.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. (1921). A Treatise on Probability. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. (1930). Economic possibilities for our grandchildren (parts I and II). The Nation and Athenaeum, 48(2, October 11 [part I]; 3, October 18 [part II]), 3637; 96–98.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. (1936). The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Keynes, J. M. (1937). The general theory of employment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 51(2, February), 209223.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. (1940). How to Pay for the War: A Radical Plan for the Chancellor of the Exchequer. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Kilmann, R., Saxton, M. J., & Serpa, R. (Eds.). (1985). Gaining Control of the Corporate Culture. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass.Google Scholar
Kindleberger, C. P. (1978). Manias, Panics and Crashes. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
King, J. E. (2016). Katona and Keynes. History of Economics Review, 64(1), 6475.Google Scholar
Klein, B., & Leffler, K. B. (1981). The role of market forces in assuring contractual performance. Journal of Political Economy, 89(4, August), 615641.Google Scholar
Klein, B. H. (1977). Dynamic Economics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Koestler, A. (1975). The Act of Creation. London: Picador.Google Scholar
Koestler, A. (1979). Janus: A Summing Up. London: Picador.Google Scholar
Koppl, R., & Whitman, D. G. (2004). Rational choice hermeneutics. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 55(3, November), 295317.Google Scholar
Kotler, P., & Levy, S. (1971). Demarketing, yes, demarketing. Harvard Business Review, 49(6), 7480.Google Scholar
Koutsobinas, T. (2014). Keynes as the first behavioral economist: The case of the attribution substitution heuristic. Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 37(2), 337355.Google Scholar
Koutsobinas, T. (2021). Attribute substitution, earlier-generation economic approaches and behavioural economics. Review of Social Economy, Published online 23 January, DOI: 10.1080/00346764.2021.1874498.Google Scholar
Kreps, D. M. (1990). Corporate culture and economic theory. In Alt, J. E. & Shepsle, A. (Eds.), Perspective on Positive Political Economy (pp. 90143). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Laaksonen, P. (1994). Consumer Involvement: Concepts and Research. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Lakatos, I. (1970). Falsificaton and the methodology of scientific research programmes. In Lakatos, I. & Musgrave, A. (Eds.), Criticism and the Growth of Knowledge (pp. 91196). London: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lamfalussy, A. (1961). Investment and Growth in Mature Economies: The Case of Belgium. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Lancaster, K. J. (1966a). A new approach to consumer theory. Journal of Political Economy, 75(2, April), 132157.Google Scholar
Lancaster, K. J. (1966b). Change and innovation in the technology of consumption. American Economic Review, 56(1, March), 1423.Google Scholar
Langer, E. J. (1991). Mindfulness: Choice and Control of Everyday Life. London: HarperCollinns.Google Scholar
Langlois, R. N. (2003). The vanishing hand: The changing dynamics of industrial capitalism. Industrial and Corporate Change, 12(2), 351385.Google Scholar
Langlois, R. N., & Robertson, P. L. (1995). Firms, Markets and Economic Change: A Dynamic Theory of Business Institutions. London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Latsis, S. J. (1972). Situational determinism in economics. British Joural for the Philosophy of Science, 23(3, August), 207245.Google Scholar
Lavoie, D. (1990). Hermeneutics, subjectivity and the Lester/Machlup debate: Towards a more anthropological approach to empirical economics. In Samuels, W. J. (Ed.), Economics as Discourse: An Analysis of the Language of Economics (pp. 167184). New York: Springer.Google Scholar
Layard, R. (2011). Happiness: Lessons from a New Science (2nd ed.). London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Lazonick, W. (1990) Competitive Advantage on the Shopfloor. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Lazonick, W. (1991) Business Organization and the Myth of the Market Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lea, S. E. G., Mewse, A. J., & Wrapson, W. (2012). The psychology of debt in poor households in Britain. In Brubaker, R., Lawless, R. M., & Tabb, C. J. (Eds.), A Debtor World: Interdisciplinary Perspective on Debt (pp. 151166). Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Lea, S. E. G., Webley, P., & Levine, R. M. (1993). The economic psychology of consumer debt. Journal of Economic Psychology, 14(1, March), 85119.Google Scholar
Lee, F. S. (1984). Full cost pricing: A new wine in a new bottle. Australian Economic Papers, 23(42), 155166.Google Scholar
Lee, F. S. (1999). Post Keynesian Price Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Leff, N. H. (1985). Optimal investment choice for developing countries: Rational theory and rational decision-making. Journal of Development Economics, 18(2–3, August), 335360.Google Scholar
Leibenstein, H. (1950). Bandwagon, snob, and Veblen effects in the theory of consumers’ demand. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 64(2, May), 183207.Google Scholar
Leibenstein, H. (1966). Allocative efficiency vs. “X-efficiency.” American Economic Review, 56(3, June), 392414.Google Scholar
Leibenstein, H. (1976). Beyond Economic Man: A New Foundation for Economics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Leibenstein, H. (1978). General X-Efficiency Theory and Economic Development. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Leibenstein, H. (1981). The inflation process: A micro-behavioral analysis. American Economic Review, 71(2), 368373.Google Scholar
Leibenstein, H. (1989). The Collected Essays of Harvey Leibenstein, Volume 2: X-Efficiency and Microeconomic Theory (edited by Button, K). Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Lenton, A. P., & Stewart, A. (2008). Changing her ways: The number of options and mate-standard strength impact mate choice strategy and satisfaction. Judgment and Decision Making, 3(7, October), 501511.Google Scholar
Lester, R. A. (1946). Shortcomings of marginal analysis for wage–empmloyment problems. American Economic Review, 36, 6382.Google Scholar
Linder, S. B. (1970). The Harried Leisure Class. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Loasby, B. J. (1967). Making location policy work. Lloyds Bank Review, 83(January), 3447.Google Scholar
Loasby, B. J. (1973). The Swindon Project. London: Pitman.Google Scholar
Loasby, B. J. (1976). Choice, Complexity and Ignorance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Loasby, B. J. (1978). Whatever happened to Marshall’s theory of value? Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 25(1, February), 112.Google Scholar
Loasby, B. J. (1982). The entrepreneur in economic theory. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 29(3, November), 235245.Google Scholar
Loasby, B. J. (1983). Knowledge, learning and enterprise. In Wiseman, J. (Ed.), Beyond Positive Economics? (pp. 104121). London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Loasby, B. J. (1989). The Mind and Method of the Economist. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Loasby, B. J. (1990). Problem-solving institutions. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 37(2), 197201.Google Scholar
Loasby, B. J. (1998). The organisation of capabilities. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 35(2), 136160.Google Scholar
Loasby, B. J. (2000). How do we know? In Earl, P. E. & Frowen, S. F. (Eds.), Economics as an Art of Thought: Essays in Memory of G.L.S. Shackle (pp. 124). London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Loasby, B. J. (2004). Hayek’s theory of the mind. In Koppl, R. (Ed.), Evolutionary Psychology and Economic Theory. Advances in Austrian Econoomics, Volume 7 (pp. 101134). Oxford: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Lodge, D. (1975). Changing Places. London: Martin Secker & Warburg.Google Scholar
Loomes, G., & Sugden, R. (1982). Regret theory: An alternative theory of rational choice under uncertainty. Economic Journal, 92(368), 805824.Google Scholar
Lorsch, J. W. (1986). Managing culture: The invisible barrier to strategic change. California Management Review, 28(2, Winter), 95109.Google Scholar
Lowenstein, G. (1987). Anticipation and the valuation of delayed consumption. Economic Journal, 97(387, September), 666684.Google Scholar
Lowenstein, G., & Thaler, R. H. (1989). Anomalies: Intertemporal choice. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3(4, Fall), 181193.Google Scholar
Luce, M. F., Bettman, J. R., & Payne, J. W. (2001). Emotional Decisions: Tradeoff Difficulty and Coping in Consumer Choice. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Lutz, M. A., & Lux, K. (1979). The Challenge of Humanistic Economics. Menlo Park, CA: Benjamin–Cummings Publishing.Google Scholar
Lutz, M. A., & Lux, K. (1988). Humanistic Economic: The New Challenge. New York: Bootstrap Press.Google Scholar
Lydall, H. F. (1959). The distribution of employment income. Econometrica, 27(1, January), 110115.Google Scholar
Macaulay, , S. C., Steen, J., & Kastelle, T. (2017). The search environment is not (always) benign: Reassessing the risks of organizational search. Industrial and Corporate Change, published online 27 November. doi:10.1093/icc/dtx045Google Scholar
Machlup, F. (1946). Marginal analysis and empirical research. American Economic Review, 36(4, September), 519534.Google Scholar
Mack, A., & Rock, I. (1998). Inattention Blindness. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Macmillan, P. J. (2015). Thinking Like an Expert Lawyer: Measuring Specialist Legal Expertise Through Think-Aloud Problem Solving and Verbal Protocol Analysis. PhD dissertation, Bond University, QLD.Google Scholar
Maddison, D., Rehdanz, K., & Welsch, H. (Eds.). (2020). Handbook on Wellbeing, Happiness and the Environment. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Maital, S. (1982). Mind, Markets and Money: Psychological Foundations of Economic Behavior. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
March, J. G. (1988). Decisions and Organizations. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
March, J. G., & Simon, H. A. (1958). Organizations. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Markey-Towler, B. (2018). An Architecture of the Mind. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Marris, R. L. (1964). The Economic Theory of “Managerial” Capitalism. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marschak, J. (1968 ). Economics of inquiring, communicating, decidin. American Economic Review, 58(2, May), 118.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. (1890). Principles of Economics (1st ed.). London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. (1923). Industry and Trade (4th ed.). London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Martin, J. P. (1978). X-inefficiency, managerial effort and protection. Economica, 45(179, August), 273286.Google Scholar
Maslow, A. H. (1943). A theory of human motivation. Psychological Review, 50(4), 370396.Google Scholar
Maslow, A. H. ([1954] 1970). Motivation and Personality (2nd ed.). New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Maslow, A. H. (1971). The Farther Reaches of Human Nature. New York: Viking.Google Scholar
Mason, R. S. (1981). Conspicuous Consumption: A Study of Exceptional Consumer Behaviour. Farnborough: Gower (New York: St Martin’s Press.Google Scholar
Mason, R. S. (1998). The Economic of Conspicuous Consumption: Theory and Thought Since 1799. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
McClelland, D. C. (1961). The Achieving Society. Princeton, NJ: Van Nostrand.Google Scholar
McCracken, G. (1988). Culture and Consumption: New Approaches to the Symbolic Character of Consumer Goodes and Activities. Bloomington and Indianapolis: Indiana University Press.Google Scholar
McDermott, S., Linahan, K., & Squires, B. (2009). Older people living in squalor. Australian Social Work, 62(2), 245257.Google Scholar
McDonald, I. M. (2017). “We will end up being a third-rate economy … a banana republic:” How behavioural economics can improve macroeconomic outcomes. Australian Economic Review, 50(2), 137151.Google Scholar
McWilliams, D. (2008a). State must act as a safeguard. Business Post, 20 September. Available online at www.davidmcwilliams.ie/state-must-act-as-a-safeguard/Google Scholar
McWilliams, D. (2008b). State guarantees can avert depression. Business Post, 27 September. Available online at www.davidmcwilliams.ie/state-guarantees-can-avert-depression/Google Scholar
McWilliams, D. (Writer). (2009). Addicted to Money. Sydney and Dublin: Electric Pictures, Screen Australia, Screen West, Radio Telefis Eireann, ABC and S4C.Google Scholar
Means, G. C. (1935). Industrial prices and their relative inflexibility. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 30(190, June), 401413.Google Scholar
Means, G. C. (1972). The administered-price theory reconfirmed. American Economic Review, 62(3, June), 292306.Google Scholar
Meeks, G. (1977). Disappointing Marriage: A Study of the Gains from Merger. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mehta, J. (2013). The discourse of bounded rationality in academic and policy arenas: Pathologising the errant consumer. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 37(6, November), 12431261.Google Scholar
Menger, C. ([1871] 1950). Principles of Economics. Glencoe, IL: Free Press (English translation by J. Dingwall and B. F. Hoselitz).Google Scholar
Miller, D., & Friesen, P. H. (1984). Organizations: A Quantum View. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Miller, G. A. (1956). The magical number seven, plus or minus two: Some limits on our capacity for processing information. Psychological Review, 101(2), 343352.Google Scholar
Miller, R., Williams, P., & O’Neill, M. (2018). The Healthy Workplace Nudge: How Healthy People, Culture and Buildings Lead to Higher Performance. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley.Google Scholar
Minsky, H. P. (1957). Central banking and money market changes. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 71(2, May), 171187.Google Scholar
Minsky, H. P. (1975). John Maynard Keynes. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Minsky, H. P. (1982a). Can “It” Happen Again? Essays on Instability and Finance. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe (Published in the UK as Inflation, Recession and Economic Recovery. Brighton, Wheatsheaf, 1982).Google Scholar
Minsky, H. P. (1982b). The financial instability hypothesis: A restatement. In Arestis, P & Skouras, T (Eds.), Post Keynesian Economic Theory (pp. 2455). Brighton: Wheatsheaf/Armonk, NY: M.E. Sharpe.Google Scholar
Minsky, H. P. (1986). Stabilizing an Unstable Economy. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Minter, A. (2019). Secondhand: Travels in the New Global Garage Sale. London: Bloomsbury.Google Scholar
Mosley, P. (1976). Towards a “satisficing” theory of economic policy. Economic Journal, 86(341, March), 5972.Google Scholar
Mosley, P. (1981). The Treasury Committee and the making of economic policy. Political Quarterly, 52(3), 348355.Google Scholar
Mosley, P. (1984). The Making of Economic Policy: Theory and Evidence from Britain and the United States since 1945. Brighton: Wheatsheaf.Google Scholar
Moss, S. J. (1981). The Economic Theory of Business Strategy: An Essay in Dynamics Without Equilibrium. Oxford: Martin Robertson.Google Scholar
Motz, B., Mallon, M., & Quick, J. (2021). Automated educative nudges to reduce missed assignments in college. IEEE Transactions on Learning Technologies. doi:10.1109/TLT.2021.3064613Google Scholar
Munkirs, J. R. (1985). The Transformation of American Capitalism: From Competitive Market Structures to Centralized Private Sector Planning. Armonk, NY: M, E. Sharpe, Inc.Google Scholar
Murray, H. A. (1938). Explorations in Personality. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Muth, J. F. (1959). Rational expectations and the theory of price movements. Econometrica, 29(3, July), 315º333.Google Scholar
Neild, R. (2002). Public Corruption: The Dark Side of Social Evolution. London: Anthem Press.Google Scholar
Neilson, D. H. (2019). Minsky. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Nelson, P. (1970). Information and consumer behavior. Journal of Political Economy, 78(2, March–April), 311329.Google Scholar
Nelson, R. R., & Winter, S. G. (1982). An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Nicosia, F. M. (1966). Consumer Decision Processes: Marketing and Advertising Implications. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice–Hall.Google Scholar
Nightingale, J. (1997). Anticipating Nelson and Winter: Jack Downie’s theory of evolutionary economic change. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 7(1), 147167.Google Scholar
Nightingale, J. (1998). Jack Downie’s Competitive Process: The first articulated population ecological model in economics. History of Political Economy, 30(3), 369412.Google Scholar
Nisbett, R. E., & Ross, L. (1980). Human Inference: Strategies and Shortcomings of Social Judgment. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Norman, A., et al. (2004). On the computational complexity of consumer decision rules. Computational Economics, 23(2), 173-192.Google Scholar
O’Connor, M. P., & Spash, C. L. (Eds.). (1999). Valuation and the Environment: Theory, Method and Practice. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
O’Donnell, C. J. (2018). Productivity and Efficiency Analysis: An Economic Approach to Measuring and Explaining Managerial Performance. Singapore: Springer Singapore.Google Scholar
O’Donoghue, T., & Rabin, M. (1999). Doing it now or doing it later. American Economics Review, 89(1, March), 103124.Google Scholar
OECD. (2017). Behavioural Insights and Public Policy: Lessons from Around the World. Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
Olshavsky, R. W., & Granbois, D. H. (1979). Consumer decision-making – Fact or fiction? Journal of Consumer Research, 6(2, September), 93100.Google Scholar
Olson, J. C., & Reynolds, T. J. (1983). Understanding consumers’ cognitive structures: Implications for advertising strategy. In Percy, L & Woodside, A. (Eds.) Advertising and Consumer Psychology (pp. 7790). Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, D. C. Heath.Google Scholar
Ormerod, P. (1998). Butterfly Economics. London: Faber & Faber.Google Scholar
OSC (Open Science Collaboration) (2015). Estimating the reproducibility of psychological science. Science, 349(6251 [28 August]), aac4716.Google Scholar
Packard, V. (1957). The Hidden Persuaders. London: Longmans Green.Google Scholar
Papadimitriou, D. B., & Wray, L. R. (Eds.) (2019). The Elgar Companion to Hyman Minsky. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Paroush, J. (1965). The order of acquisition of consumer durables. Econmetrica, 33(1, January), 225235.Google Scholar
Parsons, S. D. (2000). Shackle and the project of the enlightenment: Realism, time and imagination. In Earl, P. E & Frowen, S. F (Eds.), Economics as an Art of Thought: Essays in Memory of G. L. S. Shackle (pp. 124148). London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Payne, J. W. (1976). Task complexity and contingent processing in decision making: An information search and protocol analysis. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 16(2), 366387.Google Scholar
Payne, J. W., Bettman, J. R., & Johnson, E. J. (1993). The Adaptive Decision Maker. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Peneder, M., & Woerter, M. (2014). Competition, R&D and innovation: Testing the inverted-U in a simultaneous system. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 24(3, July), 653687.Google Scholar
Penrose, E. (1959). The Theory of the Growth of the Firm. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
PEP (1965). Thrusters and Sleepers: A Study of Attitudes in Industrial Management (A PEP Report). London: George Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Peters, G., Ruiter, R. A., & Kok, G. (2014). Threatening communication: A critical re-analysis and a revised meta-analytic test of fear appeal theory. Health Psychology Review, 7(S1), S831.Google Scholar
Piketty, T. (2014). Capitalism in the Twenty-First Century (translated by A. Goldhammer). Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Pil, F. K., & Cohey, S. K. (2006). Modularity: Implications for imitation, innovation and sustained advantage. Academy of Management Review, 31(4, October), 9951011.Google Scholar
Pincock, S. (2009). Researcher quits over science agency interference. Nature News, 4 December. Available online at www.nature.com/news/2009/091204/full/news.092009.091126.htmlGoogle Scholar
Pitelis, C. N. (2007). A behavioral resource-based view of the firm: The synergy of Cyert and March (1963) and Penrose (1959). Organization, 18(3, May/June), 478490.Google Scholar
Polanyi, M. (1962). Personal Knowledge. New York: Harper Torchbooks.Google Scholar
Polanyi, M. (1967). The Tacit Dimension. Garden City, NY: Doubleday Anchor.Google Scholar
Pooley, C., et al. (2011). Understanding Walking and Cycling: Summary of Key Findings and Recommendations. Lancaster: Lancaster University.Google Scholar
Port, I. S. (2019). The Birth of Loud: Leo Fender, Les Paul, and the Guitar-Pioneering Rivalry That Shaped Rock “n” Roll. New York: Scribner.Google Scholar
Potts, J. (2000). The New Evolutionary Microeconomics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Potts, J. (2019). Innovation Commons: The Origins of Economic Growth. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Pyatt, F. G. (1964). Priority Patterns and the Demand for Household Durable Goods. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Quine, W., van O. (1951). Two dogmas of empiricism. Philosophical Review, 60(1, January), 2043.Google Scholar
Quote Investigator (2016). Using money you haven’t earned to buy things you don’t need to impress people you don’t like. QuoteInvestigator, 21 April, https://quoteinvestigator.com/2016/04/21/impress/Google Scholar
Rabin, M., & Thaler, R. H. (2001). Anomalies: Risk aversion. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15(1), 219232.Google Scholar
Rauch, J. (2018). The Happiness Curve: Why Life Gets Better After Midlife. London: Bloomsbury Publishing.Google Scholar
Raviv, S. (2018). The genius neuroscientist who might hold the key to true AI. Retrieved from www.wired.com/story/karl-friston-free-energy-principle-artificial-intelligence/Google Scholar
Rawson, R. A. (2006). Meth and the brain: The meth epidemic. Frontline, 14 February. Retrieved from www.pbs.org/wgbh/pages/frontline/meth/body/methbrainnoflash.htmlGoogle Scholar
Rayo, L., & Becker, G. S. (2007). Evolutionary efficiency and happiness. Journal of Political Economy, 115(2), 302337.Google Scholar
Reddaway, W. B. (1937). Special obstacles to full employment in a wealthy community. Economic Journal, 47(186, June), 297307.Google Scholar
Reynolds, T. J., & Gutman, J. (1983). Developing images for services through means–end chain analysis. In Berry, L. L., Shostack, G. L., & Upah, G. D. (Eds.) Emerging Perspectives in Service Marketing (pp. 4044). Chicago, IL: American Marketing Association.Google Scholar
Reynolds, T. J., & Gutman, J. (1984). Laddering: Extending the repertory grid methodology to attribute–consequence–value hierarchies. In Pitts, R. E & Woodside, A. (Eds.) Personal Values and Consumer Psychology (pp. 155167). Lexington, MA: D. C. Heath.Google Scholar
Reynolds, T. J., & Jamieson, L. F. (1985). Image representations: an analytic framework. In Jacoby, J & Olson, J. C. (Eds.) Perceived Quality (pp. 115138). Lexington, MA: D. C. Heath (for New York University Institute of Retail Management).Google Scholar
Richardson, G. B. (1953). Imperfect knowledge and economic efficiency. Oxford Economic Papers, 5(2, June), 136156.Google Scholar
Richardson, G. B. (1959). Equilibrium, expectations and information. Economic Journal, 69(274, June), 223237.Google Scholar
Richardson, G. B. (1960). Information and Investment. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Richardson, G. B. (1972). The organisation of industry. Economic Journal, 82(327, September), 883896.Google Scholar
Ritzer, G. (2004). The McDonaldization of Society. Thousand Oaks, CA: Pine Forge Press.Google Scholar
Robertson, P. L., & Langlois, R. N. (1994). Institutions, inertia and changing industrial leadership. Industrial and Corporate Change, 3(2), 359378.Google Scholar
Robinson, E. A. G. (1939). Review article on Oxford Economic Papers. Economic Journal, 49(September), 538543.Google Scholar
Robinson, J. (1964). Economic Philosophy. Harmondsworth: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Robson, A. J. (2001a). The biological basis of economic behavior. Journal of Economic Literature, 39(1, March), 1133.Google Scholar
Robson, A. J. (2001b). Why would nature give individuals utility functions? Journal of Political Economy, 109(4), 900914.Google Scholar
Robson, A. J. (2002). Evolution and human nature. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 16(2, Spring), 89106.Google Scholar
Roe, A. R. (1973). The case for flow of funds and national balance sheet accounts. Economic Journal, 83(330), 399420.Google Scholar
Rostow, W. W. (1960). The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ryle, G. (1949). The Concept of Mind. London: Hutchinson (republished 2009. London: Routledge).Google Scholar
Salter, W. E. G. (1960). Productivity and Technical Change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. (1938). A note on the pure theory of consumer’s behaviour. Economica (New Series), 5(17, February), 6171.Google Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. (1948). Consumption theory in terms of revealed preference. Economica, 15(60, November), 243253.Google Scholar
Saul, J. R. (1993). Voltaire’s Bastards: The Dictatorship of Reason in the West. Toronto, Ontario: Penguin.Google Scholar
Saunders, C., & Barber, A. (2008). Carbon footprints, life cycle analysis, food miles: Global trade trends and market issues. Political Science, 60(1), 7388.Google Scholar
Schein, E. H. (1984). Coming to a new awareness of organizational culture. Sloan Management Review, 24(2, Winter), 316.Google Scholar
Schimmack, U. (2018). Why the Journal of Personality and Social Psychology should retract article DOI: 10.1037/a0021524 “Feeling the future: Experimental evidence for anomalous retroactive influences on cognition and affect” by Daryl J. Bem.” Retrieved from https://replicationindex.wordpress.com/2018/01/05/why-the-journal-of-personality-and-social-psychology-should-retract-article-doi-10-1037-a0021524-feeling-the-future-experimental-evidence-for-anomalous-retroactive-influences-on-cognition-a/Google Scholar
Schoenberger, E. (1997). The Cultural Crisis of the Firm. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Schouten, J. W., & McAlexander, J. H. (1995). Subcultures of consumption: An ethnography of the new bikers. Journal of Consumer Rsearch, 22(1, June), 4361.Google Scholar
Schulte-Mecklenbeck, M., Kuhberger, A., & Ranyard, R. (2011). A Handbook of Process Tracing Methods for Decision Research. Hove and New York: Psychology Press.Google Scholar
Schumacher, E. F. (1973). Small is Beautiful: A Study of Economics as if People Mattered. London: Blond and Briggs.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. A. (1943). Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. London: George Allen & Unwin (new edition, 1992, London and New York, Routledge).Google Scholar
Schwartz, B. (2005). The Paradox of Choice: Why More is Less. New York: Harper Perennial.Google Scholar
Scitovsky, T. (1943). A note on profit maximisation and its implications. Review of Economic Studies, 11(1, Winter), 5760.Google Scholar
Scitovsky, T. (1944). Some consequences of the habit of judgin quality by price. Review of Economic Studies, 12(2, May), 100105.Google Scholar
Scitovsky, T. (1976). The Joyless Economy: An Inquiry into Human Satisfaction and Consumer Dissatisfaction. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Scitovsky, T. (1981). The desire for excitement in modern society. Kyklos, 34(1), 313.Google Scholar
Scitovsky, T. (1985). Pricetakers’ plenty: A neglected benefit of capitalism. Kyklos, 38(4, November), 517536.Google Scholar
Selznick, P. (1957). Leadership in Administration. Evanston, IL: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Sent, E.-M. (2004). Behavioral economics: How psychology made its (limited) way back into economics. History of Political Economy, 36(4), 735760.Google Scholar
Shackle, G. L. S. (1943). The expectational dynamics of the individual. Economica, 10(38, May), 99129.Google Scholar
Shackle, G. L. S. (1949). Expectation in Economics. Cambridge: Camrbidge University Press.Google Scholar
Shackle, G. L. S. (1955a). Uncertainty in Economics and Other Reflections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Shackle, G. L. S. (1961). Decision, Order and Time in Human Affairs. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Shackle, G. L. S. (1972). Epistemics and Economics: A Critique of Economic Doctrines. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Shackle, G. L. S. (1974). Keynesian Kaleidics. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.Google Scholar
Shackle, G. L. S. (1979). Imagination and the Nature of Choice. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.Google Scholar
Shackle, G. L. S. (1988). Business, Time and Thought (edited by Frowen, S. F). London and Basingstoke: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Shefrin, H. M., & Thaler, R. H. (1988). The behavioral life-cycle hypothesis. Economic Inquiry, 26(4, October), 609643.Google Scholar
Shepherd, M. (2018). Climate change or global warming? Three reasons not to be distracted by the name game. Forbes Magazine, 13 April. Available online at www.forbes.com/sites/marshallshepherd/2018/04/13/climate-change-or-global-warming-three-reasons-not-to-be-distracted-by-the-name-game/?sh=430d1c325088Google Scholar
Shiller, R. J. (2013). Robert J. Shiller facts: Biographical. The Novel Prize, www.nobelprize.org/prizes/economic-sciences/2013/shiller/facts/Google Scholar
Shiller, R. J. (2020). Narrative Economics: How Stories Go Viral and Drive Major Economic Events. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Shiozawa, Y., Morioka, M., & Taniguchi, K. (2019). Microfoundations of Evolutionary Economics. Tokyo: Springer Japan.Google Scholar
Shove, E., Pantzar, M., & Watson, M. (2012). The Dynamics of Practice: Everyday Life and How It Changes. London: Sage.Google Scholar
Shrum, L. J., et al. (2013). Reconceptualizing materialism as identity goal pursuits: Functions, processes, and consequences. Journal of Business Research, 66, 11791185.Google Scholar
Sickles, R. C., & Zelenyuk, V. (2019). Measurement of Productivity and Efficiency: Theory and Practice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Silver, M. (1984). Enterprise and the Scope of the Firm. Oxford: Martin Robertson.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1947). Administrative Behavior. New York: Macmillan (3rd edition 1976. New York: Free Press).Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1951). A formal theory of the employment relationship. Econometica, 19(3, July), 293305.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1955). A behavioral model of rational choice. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 69(1, February), 99118.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1956). Rational choice and the structure of the environment. Psychological Review, 63(2), 129138.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1957a). Models of Man. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1957b). The compensation of executives. Sociometry, 20(1, March), 3235.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1959). Theories of decision-making in economics and behavioral science. American Economic Review, 49(3, June), 253283.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1962). The architecture of complexity. Proceedings of the American Philosophical Society, 106(6, December), 467482.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1969). The Sciences of the Artificial. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1976). From substantive to procedural rationality. In Latsis, S. J. (Ed.), Method and Appraisal in Economics (pp. 129148). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1982a). Models of Bounded Rationality, Volume 1: Economic Analysis and Public Policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1982b). Models of Bounded Rationality, Volume 2: Behavioral Economics and Business Organization. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1991). Models of My Life. New York, NY: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1992). Altruism and economics. Eastern Economic Journal, 18(1), 7383.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1993). Altruism and economics. American Economic Review, 83(2, May), 156161.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1997). Models of Bounded Rationality, Volume 3: Empirically Grounded Economic Research. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (2005). Darwinian altruism and economics. In Dopfer, K. (Ed.), The Evolutionary Foundations of Economics (pp. 8088). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A., & Chase, W. G. (1973). Skill in chess. American Scientist, 61(4, July–August), 394403.Google Scholar
Sjåstad, H., & Baumeister, R. F. (2018). The future and the will: Planning requires self-control and ego-depleiton leads to planning aversion. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 76(May), 127141.Google Scholar
Smircich, L. (1983). Concepts of culture and organizational analysis. Administrative Sciences Quarterly, 28(3, September), 339358.Google Scholar
Smith, A. ([1759] 1976). The Theory of Moral Sentiments (edited by Raphael, D. D and MacFie, A. L), Oxford: Clarendon Press, .Google Scholar
Smith, A. ([1795] 1980). The principles which lead and direct philosophical enquiries; illustrated by the history of astronomy. In Wightman, W. P. D. (Ed.), Essays on Philosophical Subjects (pp. 33105). Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, R. A. (1963). Corporations in Crisis. Garden City, NY: Doubleday.Google Scholar
Smith, R. P. (1975). Consumer Demand for Cars in the USA. University of Cambridge Department of Appiled Economics Occasional Paper No. 44. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, V. L. (1991). Papers in Experimental Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, V. L. (2008). Rationality in Economics: Constructivist and Ecological Forms. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Smyth, R. L. (1967). A price-minus theory of costs? Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 14(2, June), 110117.Google Scholar
Spash, C. L. (1999). Contingent valuation. In Earl, P. E & Kemp, S (Eds.), The Elgar Companion to Consumer Research and Economic Psychology (pp. 124134). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Spash, C. L. (2002). Greenhouse Economics: Value and Ethics. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Spash, C. L. (2010). The brave new world of carbon trading. New Political Economy, 15(2), 169195.Google Scholar
Spash, C. L. (Ed.) (2017). Routledge Handbook of Ecological Economics. Abingdon: Routledge.Google Scholar
Spellman, B. A. (2015). A short (personal) future history of revolution 2.0. Perspectives on Psychology, 100(6), 886899.Google Scholar
Spread, P. (2011). Situation as determinant of selection and valuation. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 35(2), 335-356.Google Scholar
Spurling, G. (1985). Industry and human resources. In Scutt, J. (Ed.), Poor Nation of the Pacific? Australia’s Future (pp. 7074). Sydney: George Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Staw, B. M. (1976). Knee-deep in the big muddy: A study of escalation of commitment to a chosen course of action. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 16(1), 2744.Google Scholar
Steinbruner, J. D. (1974). The Cybernetic Theory of Decision: New Dimensions of Political Analysis. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Sternberg, J. (2019). The Theft of a Decade: How the Baby Boomers Stole the Millennials’ Economic Future. New York: PublicAffairs.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. J. (1961). The economics of information. Journal of Political Economy, 69(3, June), 213225.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. J. (1976). The Xistence of X-efficiency. American Economic Review, 66(1, March), 213216.Google Scholar
Stigler, G. J., & Becker, G. S. (1977). De gusitbus non est disputandum. American Economic Review, 67(2, March), 7690.Google Scholar
Strotz, R. H. (1957). The empirical implications of a utility tree. Econometrica, 25(2, April), 269280.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. (2009). On nudging: A review of Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health, Wealth and Happiness by Richard H. Thaler and Cass R. Sunstein. International Journal of the Economics of Business, 16(3, November), 365373.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. (2018). “Better off,” as judged by themselves: A reply to Cass Sunstein. International Review of Economics, 65(1), 913.Google Scholar
Sunstein, C. R., & Thaler, R. H. (2003). Libertarian paternalism is not an oxymoron. University of Chicago Law Review, 70(4, Fall), 11591201.Google Scholar
Szmigin, I., & Rutherford, R. P. (2013). Shared values and the impartial spectator. Journal of Business Ethics, 114(1), 171182.Google Scholar
Tajfel, H., & Turner, J. C. (1979). An integrative theory of intergroup conflict. In Austin, W. G. & Worchel, S. (Eds.), The Social Psychology of Intergroup Relations (pp. 4447). Monterey, CA: Brooks/Cole.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (1980). Toward a positive theory of consumer choice. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 1(1), 3960.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (1985). Mental accounting and consumer choice. Marketing Science, 4(3, Summer), 199214.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (1992). The Winner’s Curse: Paradoxes and Anolmalies in Economioc Life. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (1999). Mental accounting matters. Journal of Behavoral Decision Making, 12(3, September), 183206.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H. (2015). Misbehaving: The Making of Behavioral Economics. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H., & Benartzi, S. (2004). Save more tomorrow: Using behavioral economics to increase employee saving. Journal of Political Economy, 112(1, pt. 2), S164S187.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H., & Shefrin, H. M. (1981). An economic theory of self-control. Journal of Political Economy, 89(2m April), 291406.Google Scholar
Thaler, R. H., & Sunstein, C. R. (2008). Nudge: Improving Decisions About Health, Wealth and Happiness. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Thompson, C. J. (1996). Caring consumers: Gendered consumption meanings and the juggling lifestyle. Journal of Consumer Research, 22(4, March), 388407.Google Scholar
Thompson, M. (1979). Rubbish Theory: The Creation and Destruction of Value. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Thomson, M., MacInnis, D., & Park, C. W. (2005). The ties that bind: Measuring the strength of consumers’ emotional attachment to brands. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 15(1), 7779.Google Scholar
Tinbergen, N. (1951). The Study of Instinct. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Tomer, J. F. (2007). What is behavioral economics? Journal of Socio-Economics, 36(3), 463479. doi:10.1016/j.socec.2006.12.007Google Scholar
Townshend, H. (1937). Liquidity premium and the theory of value. Economic Journal 47(185, March), 157169.Google Scholar
Trevithick, J. A. (1976). Money wage inflexibility and the Keynesian labour supply function. Economic Journal, 86(342, June), 327332.Google Scholar
Tuck, M. (1976). How Do We Choose?: A Study in Consumer Behaviour. London: Methuen.Google Scholar
Tversky, A. (1969). Intransitivity of preferences. Psychological Review, 76(1), 3148.Google Scholar
Tversky, A. (1972). Elimination by aspects: A theory of choice. Psychological Review, 79(4, July), 281299.Google Scholar
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1971). Belief in the law of small numbers. Psychological Bulletin, 76(2), 105110.Google Scholar
Tylecote, A. (1981). The Causes of the Present Inflation. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Underhill, P. (2001). Call of the Mall: How We Shop. London: Profile.Google Scholar
Veblen, T. B. (1899). The Theory of the Leisure Class: An Economic Study of Institutions. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Veblen, T. B. (1914). The Instinct of Workmanship and the State of the Industrial Arts. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
von Neumann, J., & Morgenstern, O. (1944). Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Wallendorf, M., & Bruchs, M. (1993). Introspection in consumer research: Implementation and implications. Journal of Consumer Research, 20(September), 339359.Google Scholar
Wallis, J., Dollery, B., & Crase, L. (2009). Political economy and organizational leadership: A hope-based theory. Review of Political Economy, 21(1), 123143.Google Scholar
Wärneryd, K.-E. (1982). The life and work of George Katona. Journal of Economic Psychology, 2(1), 131.Google Scholar
Wärneryd, K.-E. (1999). The Psychology of Saving: A Study on Economic Psychology, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Waterson, M. (2003). The role of consumers in competition and competition policy. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 21(2, February), 129150.Google Scholar
Watzlawick, P., Weakland, J. H., & Fisch, R. (1974). Change: Principles of Problem Formation and Problem Resolution. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Weber, E. J. (2009). Wilfred Edward Graham Salter: The Merits of a Classical Economic Education. University of Western Australia Economics Discussion/Working Papers. Nedlands, WA.Google Scholar
Wells, W. D. (1975). Psychographics: A critical review. Journal of Marketing Research, 12(2, May), 196213.Google Scholar
Wigley, R. (2021). Born Digital: The Story of a Distracted Generation. London: Whitefox.Google Scholar
Wilkinson, N. (2012). An Introduction to Behavioral Economics (2nd ed.). Basingstoke: Palgrave.Google Scholar
Williams, P. (2013). Inside Anglo: The secret recordings. The Irish Independent, 24 June. Available online at www.independent.ie/business/irish/inside-anglo-the-secret-recordings-29366837.htmlGoogle Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1964). The Economics of Discretionary Behavior: Managerial Objectives in a Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1970). Corporate Control and Business Behavior. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1975). Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Anti-Trust Implications. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1985). The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets and Relational Contracting. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E., Wachter, M. L., & Harris, J. E. (1975). Understanding the employment relation: The analysis of idiosyncratic exchange. Bell Journal of Economics, 6(1, Spring), 250278.Google Scholar
Wilson, T. (1979). The price of oil: A case of negative marginal revenu. Journal if Industrial Economics, 27(4, June), 301315.Google Scholar
Winter, S. G. (1964). Economic “natural selection” and the theory of the firm. Yale Economic Essays, 4, 225272.Google Scholar
Winter, S. G. (1971). Satisficing, selection and the innovating remnant. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 85(2), 237261.Google Scholar
Winter, S. G., Szulanski, G., Ringov, D., & Jensen, R. J. (2012). Reproducing knowledge: Inaccurate replication and failure in franchise organizations. Organization Science, 23(3, May–June), 672685.Google Scholar
Witte, K., & Allen, M. (2000). A meta-analysis of fear appeals: Implications for effective public health campaigns. Education and Behavior, 27(5), 591615.Google Scholar
Wolf, C., jr. (1970). The present value of the past. Journal of Political Economy, 78(4), 783792.Google Scholar
Wolnizer, P. W. (2006). Auditing as Independent Authentication. Sydney, NSW: Sydney University Press.Google Scholar
Wood, A. (1978). A Theory of Pay. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Woods, C. (2002). Entrepreneurial Action: Casting the Entrepreneur in the Market Process. PhD dissertation, University of Auckland.Google Scholar
Woodward, J. (1965). Industrial Organization: Theory and Practice. London: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Woollett, G. J. (2007). Structural Change in the Australian Economy: The S-Shaped Curve Applied to Consumer Demand. PhD dissertation, University of Queensland, QLD.Google Scholar
Wray, L. R. (2008). Lesson from the subprime meltdown. Challenge, 51(2, March–April), 4068.Google Scholar
Wray, L. R. (2016). Why Minsky Matters: An Introduction to the Work of a Maverick Economist. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Wright, T. P. (1936). Factors affecting the cost of airplanes. Journal of Aeronautical Sciences, 3(4), 122128.Google Scholar
Ziman, J. (1978). Reliable Knowledge: An Exploration of Grounds for Belief in Science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Peter E. Earl, University of Queensland
  • Book: Principles of Behavioral Economics
  • Online publication: 18 October 2022
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009091053.015
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Peter E. Earl, University of Queensland
  • Book: Principles of Behavioral Economics
  • Online publication: 18 October 2022
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009091053.015
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Peter E. Earl, University of Queensland
  • Book: Principles of Behavioral Economics
  • Online publication: 18 October 2022
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009091053.015
Available formats
×