Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-s2hrs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-05T12:56:40.629Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

5 - Gilpin approaches War and Change: a classical realist in structural drag

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 September 2014

Jonathan Kirshner
Affiliation:
Cornell University
G. John Ikenberry
Affiliation:
Princeton University, New Jersey
Get access

Summary

Introduction

Robert Gilpin’s War and Change in World Politics, flirting with its twentieth printing three decades after it was first published, is much more than a classic text dutifully absorbed by graduate students preparing for their comprehensive exams – it remains a work of enduring, theoretical insights that are immediately relevant for understanding contemporary international relations. Why does War and Change remain vital, for both scholars and statesmen, after all these years? A tempting and fashionable answer might be that as a deductive, structuralist argument, it is free from the minutiae of the current events of its day, or any day, and is thus timeless. And it is possible to read the book this way, encouraged by the author’s occasional resort to stentorian, deterministic prose (“it has always been thus and always will be,” p. 210). But in fact, War and Change endures in spite of its structuralism, not because of it. That structural machine, so carefully pieced together over the course of the volume, like many “deductive” frameworks proffered by scholars of international relations then and now, was in fact much rooted in (and shaped by) the transient concerns of its time – and it got those concerns wrong. War and Change was motivated by the late 1970s alarm about American decline in comparison with the “rising challenger” of the Soviet Union. These themes also inform the book’s incongruous epilogue, which concludes on a “cautiously optimistic note” that belies the inescapable (and compelling) pessimistic logic of the preceding chapters. Epilogue notwithstanding, the machine expected hegemonic war, and the machine was wrong.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2014

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Gilpin, Robert, War and Change in World Politics (Cambridge University Press, 1981), p. 210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilpin, Robert, “The Richness of the Tradition of Political Realism,” in Keohane, Robert O., ed., Neorealism and Its Critics (New York, NY: Columbia University Press, 1986), pp. 301–321, 306, 309.Google Scholar
Waltz, Kenneth, Theory of International Politics (New York, NY: Addison Wesley, 1979), pp. 65, 68.Google Scholar
Jervis, Robert, Perception and Misperception in International Politics (Princeton University Press, 1977), pp. 19–21.Google Scholar
Nye, Joseph, “Neorealism and Neoliberalism,” World Politics, Vol. 40, No. 2 (January 1988), pp. 235–251, esp. pp. 235, 242, 245.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolfers, Arnold, “The Goals of Foreign Policy,” in Wolfers, , Discord and Collaboration (Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 1962).Google Scholar
Strassler, Robert, The Landmark Thucydides: A Comprehensive Guide to The Peloponnesian War (New York, NY: Simon and Schuster, 1996)Google Scholar
Gilpin, Robert, “The Theory of Hegemonic War,” in Rothberg, Robert and Rabb, Theodore, The Origin and Prevention of Major Wars (Cambridge University Press, 1989), pp. 15–37, p. 23.Google Scholar
Morgenthau, Hans, In Defense of the National Interest (New York, NY: Knopf, 1951)Google Scholar
Kennan, George F., American Diplomacy, 1900–1950 (University of Chicago Press, 1951)Google Scholar
Krasner, Stephen, Defending the National Interest (Princeton University Press, 1978).Google Scholar
Gilpin, Robert, “Economic Interdependence and National Security in Historical Perspective,” in Knorr, Klaus and Traeger, Frank, eds., Economic Issues and National Security (Lawrence, KS: University Press of Kansas, 1977), pp. 19–66, p. 59.Google Scholar
Gilpin, Robert, “The Politics of Transnational Economic Relations,” International Organization, Vol. 25, No. 3 (Summer 1971), pp. 398–419, 401, 403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard, “My Early Beliefs,” in his Two Memoirs (London: Rupert Hart-Davis, 1949).Google Scholar
Kirshner, Jonathan, “Keynes, Legacies, and Inquiry,” Theory and Society, Vol. 38, No. 4 (2009), pp. 527–541.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carr, E.H., The Twenty Years’ Crisis, 1919–1939, 2nd edn. (New York, NY: St. Martin’s Press, 1946 [1939]), pp. 108, 132, 138; 145 (quote);CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kennan, George F., “The Sources of Soviet Conduct,” Foreign Affairs, Vol. 25 (July 1947), pp. 566–582Google Scholar
Kennan, George F., “Russia – Seven Years Later,” (1944) reprinted in Kennan, , Memoirs 1925–1950 (Boston, MA: Little, Brown & Co., 1967), pp. 503–531.Google Scholar
Mearsheimer, John, The Tragedy of Great Power Politics (New York, NY: Norton, 2001), p. 30.Google Scholar
Kirshner, Jonathan, “The Tragedy of Offensive Realism: Classical Realism and the Rise of China,” European Journal of International Relations, Vol. 18, No. 1 (March 2012), pp. 53–75CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spykman, Nicholas J., America’s Strategy in World Politics: The United States and the Balance of Power (New York, NY: Harcourt, Brace, and Co., 1942), p. 20.Google Scholar
Machiavelli, Niccolo, Discourses on Livy (University of Chicago Press, 1996, trans. Mansfield, Harvey and Tarcov, Nathan), p. 4;CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahler, Miles, “External Ambition and Economic Performance,” World Politics, Vol. 40, No. 4 (July 1988), pp. 419–451, 451CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgenthau, Hans, Scientific Man vs. Power Politics (University of Chicago Press, 1946), pp. 5, 42, 168, 195Google Scholar
Morgenthau, Hans, “The Evil of Politics and the Politics of Evil,” Ethics, Vol. 56, No. 1 (October 1945), pp. 1–18, 1, 13, 16–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, Robert, Gilovich, Thomas and Regan, Dennis, “Does Studying Economics Inhibit Cooperation?Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 7, No. 2 (Spring 1993), pp. 159–171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knight, Frank, Risk, Uncertainty and Profit (University of Chicago Press, 1971/1921), pp. 241, 311Google Scholar
Derman, Emanuel, Models Behaving Badly: Why Confusing Illusion with Reality Can Lead to Disaster, on Wall Street and in Life (New York, NY: Free Press, 2011).Google Scholar
Kindleberger, Charles P., “A Monetary Economist on Power Politics,” World Politics, Vol. 6, No. 4 (July 1954), pp. 507–514, 509–510CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kindleberger, Charles P., “Scientific International Politics,” World Politics, Vol. 11, No. 1 (October 1958), pp. 83–88, 86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marshall, Alfred, “Fragments,” in Pigou, A.C., ed., Memorials of Alfred Marshall (London: Macmillan, 1925), pp. 358–368, 360 (quote);Google Scholar
Marshall, Alfred, Principles of Economics (8th edn.) (London: Macmillan, 1920), esp. Book I, Chapter III, “Economic Generalizations or Laws,” pp. 30–33Google Scholar
Knight, Frank H., “‘What is Truth’ in Economics?Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 48, No. 1 (1940), pp. 1–32, 29–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rutten, Andrew, “But It Will Never Be Science, Either,” Journal of Economic History, Vol. 40, No. 1 (March 1980), pp. 137–142, 139, 141–142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgenthau, , Politics Among Nations: The Struggle for Power and Peace, 3rd edn (New York, NY: Alfred A. Knopf, 1960), pp. 20Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton’s paper, “The Methodology of Positive Economics,” in his Essays in Positive Economics (University of Chicago Press, 1953)Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard, “The General Theory of Employment,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 51, No. 2 (February 1937), pp. 209–223CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich, “The Use of Knowledge in Society,” American Economic Review, Vol. 35, No. 4 (September 1945), pp. 519–530Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (London: Macmillan, 1936), pp. 156–158.Google Scholar
Fearon, James, “Rationalist Explanations for War,” International Organization, Vol. 49, No. 3 (Summer 1995), pp. 379–414, 392.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirshner, Jonathan, “Rationalist Explanations for War?Security Studies, Vol. 10, No. 1 (Autumn 2000), pp. 143–150.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, Preston, ed., The Rational Expectations Revolution (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1994).Google Scholar
Brunner, Karl and Meltzer, Allan H., Money in the Economy: Issues in Monetary Analysis (Cambridge University Press, 1993), p. 42;Google Scholar
Lovell, Michael C., “Tests of the Rational Expectations Hypothesis,” American Economic Review, Vol. 76, No. 1 (1986), pp. 110–124, 122Google Scholar
Friedman, Benjamin, “Optimal Expectations and the Extreme Information Assumptions of ‘Rational Expectations’ Macromodels,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 5 (January 1979), pp. 23–41, 26–27CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frydman, Roman and Goldberg, Michael D., Imperfect Knowledge Economics: Exchange Rates and Risk (Princeton University Press, 2007), p. 54;Google Scholar
Frydman, Roman and Goldberg, Michael, Beyond Mechanical Markets: Asset Price Swings, Risk, and the Role of the State (Princeton University Press, 2011)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Muth, John, “Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements,” Econometrica, Vol. 29, No. 3 (July 1961), pp. 315–335, 316CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evans, George and Honkapohja, Seppo, “An Interview with Thomas J. Sargent,” Macroeconomic Dynamics, Vol. 9 (2005), pp. 561–583, 566.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colander, David, et al., “The Financial Crisis and the Systemic Failure of the Economics Profession,” Critical Review, Vol. 21, No. 2–3 (2009), pp. 249–267, 256CrossRefGoogle Scholar
May, Ernest, Strange Victory: Hitler’s Conquest of France (New York, NY: Hill and Wang, 2000)Google Scholar
Bloch, Marc, Strange Defeat (New York, NY: Norton 1999 [1940]).Google Scholar
Judt, Tony, Reappraisals: Reflections on the Forgotten Twentieth Century (New York, NY: Penguin, 2008)Google Scholar
Doran, Charles, “War and Power Dynamics: Economic Underpinnings,” International Studies Quarterly, Vol. 27, No. 4 (1983), pp. 419–441.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Logevall, Fredrik, Choosing War: The Lost Chance for Peace and the Escalation of War in Vietnam (Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1999), pp. 73–74, 78, 145, 298, 314, 388, 393Google Scholar
Kahin, George McT., Intervention: How America Became Involved in Vietnam (New York, NY: Anchor Books, 1987), pp. 260, 262, 286, 306, 366, 393, 399, 423, 426, 432Google Scholar
Schandler, Herbert Y., Lyndon Johnson and Vietnam: The Unmaking of a President (Princeton University Press, 1977), pp. 98, 109, 119–120, 129, 140–141, 197–198, 258, 263–264Google Scholar
Herring, George C., America’s Longest War: The United States and Vietnam, 1950–1975 (New York, NY: Knopf, 2nd edn., 1986), pp. 144–145, 146, 151, 161.Google Scholar
Ikenberry, G. John, ed., America Unrivaled: The Future of the Balance of Power (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 2002).Google Scholar
Kupchan, Charles, The Vulnerability of Empire (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1994).Google Scholar
Krasner, Stephen, “State Power and the Structure of International Trade,” World Politics, Vol. 28, No. 3 (1976), pp. 317–347, esp. p. 320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ikenberry, G. John, After Victory: Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the Rebuilding of Order after Major Wars (Princeton University Press, 2001).Google Scholar
Kirshner, Jonathan, “The Second Crisis in IPE Theory,” in Phillips, Nicola and Weaver, Catherine, ed., International Political Economy: Debating the Past, Present and Future (London: Routledge, 2011), pp. 203–209Google Scholar
Lobell, Steven E., Ripsman, Norrin M., and Taliaferro, Jeffrey W., Neoclassical Realism, The State, and Foreign Policy (Cambridge University Press, 2009)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose, Gideon, “Neoclassical Realism and Theories of Foreign Policy,” World Politics, Vol. 51, No. 1 (October 1998), pp. 144–172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirschman, Albert, National Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade (Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1980 [1945])Google Scholar
Abdelal, Rawi and Kirshner, Jonathan, “Strategy, Economic Relations, and the Definition of National Interests,” Security Studies, Vol. 9, No. 1–2 (Autumn 1999–Winter 2000), pp. 119–156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×