Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-t5tsf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-05T04:21:13.048Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

3 - Agricultural adjustment and the Mexico-USA free trade agreement

from Part One - Open economy analysis

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 August 2010

L. Alan Winters
Affiliation:
University of Birmingham
Get access

Summary

Introduction

On 10 June 1990, the presidents of Mexico and the USA agreed to negotiate a free trade agreement (FTA). Negotiations began in mid-1991, and were expected to be completed within about a year, implementation could start as early as 1993. The FTA would cap major structural reforms undertaken by Mexico over the last few years: trade liberalisation, domestic industrial deregulation and internal financial liberalisation, privatisation of public enterprises, and a successful renegotiation of the external debt.

One of the major issues is trade in agricultural products. Agricultural trade is probably the most distorted of all commodity flows taking place between the two countries. Moreover, agricultural trade intervention cannot be separated from domestic agricultural policies which, in turn, are intricately linked with politically volatile income distribution and labour market problems. This is especially important in Mexico, where land redistribution and agricultural regulation are an essential part of the heritage of the Mexican revolution. Agricultural reform will become necessary if a FTA includes agriculture. But the analysis of agricultural reform has to tackle the complicated interplay between efficiency losses and income distributional objectives underlying current agricultural policies.

Levy and van Wijnbergen (1991a) showed that land distribution and labour markets played an important role in determining the distributional impact of trade liberalisation in maize. Liberalising maize only would probably depress the demand for rural labour. On the other hand, fruit and vegetables, where the USA has trade barriers, is more labour intensive than maize. A comprehensive agreement might thus present less of a problem for rural labour markets than a liberalisation of maize alone.

Type
Chapter
Information
Open Economies
Structural Adjustment and Agriculture
, pp. 42 - 62
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 1992

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×