Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-t5tsf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-06T10:15:50.685Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

21 - Endogenous birth and death of political parties in dynamic party competition

from Part III - Action selection in social contexts

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 November 2011

Anil K. Seth
Affiliation:
University of Sussex
Tony J. Prescott
Affiliation:
University of Sheffield
Joanna J. Bryson
Affiliation:
University of Bath
Get access

Summary

‘Spatial’ models of political competition

People who talk about politics talk sooner or later about positions of political actors, be these citizens, voters, activists, or politicians. It is hard to have a serious discussion about the substance of real politics without referring to where key actors stand on important matters. Position implies distance (between two positions); distance implies movement; movement involves direction and can only be described relative to some benchmark. Indeed, it is difficult to analyse real political competition without using positional language and reasoning. This is why the spatial model is one of the ‘workhorse’ models of political science (Cox, 2001).

Spatial models of party competition typically involve two species of agent: voters and politicians. Voters have preferences about political outcomes. Politicians compete for voters’ support by offering policy packages, in essence promised outcomes that appeal to these preferences. Voters’ preferences are typically assumed to be single-peaked over the set of potential outcomes. This implies an ideal point for each voter, describing the most-preferred outcome. Less-preferred outcomes are described as points in some cognitive space that are increasingly far from this ideal. Although not a logical necessity, many models of party competition assume the set of voter ideal points to be both exogenously given and mapped into a common space. Basis vectors of real-world political spaces are typically interpreted as policy dimensions. Examples of such policy dimensions include economic left-right, social liberal-conservative, and foreign policy hawk-dove. In the ‘proximity-voting’ models that are common characterisations of voting in large electorates, each voter is assumed to support the politician offering the policy package closest to their ideal point. More complex assumptions may be made about strategic behaviour by voters. While these may be appropriate in small voting bodies where the voter has some realistic rational expectation that a single vote will affect the outcome, we do not consider these assumptions realistic in relation to voting in very large electorates, which is the setting we concern ourselves with here. Hinich and Munger provide an accessible introduction to spatial models of party competition (Hinich and Munger, 1994, 1997). Austen-Smith and Banks provide a comprehensive technical overview (2000, 2005).

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aurenhammer, F 1991 Voronoi diagrams: a survey of a fundamental geometric data structureACM Comput. Surv. 23 345CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Austen-Smith, DBanks, J. S 1988 Elections, coalitions and legislative outcomesAmer. Pol. Sci. Rev. 82 405CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Austen-Smith, DBanks, J. S 2000 Positive Political Theory I: Collective PreferenceAnn Arbor, MIUniversity of Michigan PressGoogle Scholar
Austen-Smith, DBanks, J. S 2005 Positive Political Theory II: Strategy and StructureAnn Arbor, MIUniversity of Michigan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, TCoate, S 1997 An economic model of representative democracyQuart. J. Econ. 112 85CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brooks, S. PGelman, A 1998 General methods for monitoring convergence of iterative simulationsJ. Comput. Graph. Stat. 7 434Google Scholar
Cox, G 1997 Making Votes Count: Strategic Coordination in the World's Electoral SystemsCambridge:Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, G 2001 Introduction to the Special IssuePolit. Anal 9 189CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Marchi, S 1999 Adaptive models and electoral instabilityJ. Theor. Polit. 11 393CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Marchi, S 2003 A computational model of voter sophistication, ideology and candidate position-takingComputational Models in Political EconomyKollman, KMiller, J. HPage, S. ECambridge, MA:MIT Press143Google Scholar
Dhillon, A 2005 Political parties and coalition formation. In Group Formation in Economics: Networks, Clubs, and CoalitionsDemange, GWooders, MCambridgeCambridge University Press, pp. 289–311Google Scholar
Downs, A 1957 An Economic Theory of DemocracyNew YorkHarper & RowGoogle Scholar
Du, QFaber, VGunzburger, M 1999 Centroidal Voronoi tessellations: applications and algorithmsSoc. Indust. Appl. Math. Rev. 41 637Google Scholar
Fowler, J. HLaver, M 2008 A tournament of party decision rulesJ. Confl. Res. 52 68CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fowler, J. HSmirnov, O 2005 Dynamic parties and social turnout: an agent-based modelAmer. J. Sociol. 110 1070CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glimcher, P. WDorris, M. CBayer, H. M 2005 Physiological utility theory and the neuroeconomics of choiceGame. Econ. Behav. 52 213CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hinich, M. JMunger, M. C 1994 Ideology and the Theory of Political ChoiceAnn Arbor, MIUniversity of Michigan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hinich, M. JMunger, M. C 1997 Analytical PoliticsCambridgeCambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kedar, O 2005 When moderate voters prefer extreme parties: policy balancing in parliamentary electionsAmer. Pol. Sci. Rev 99 185CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kollman, KMiller, J 1992 Adaptive parties in spatial electionsAmer. Polit. Sci. Rev. 86 929CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kollman, KMiller, J 1998 Political parties and electoral landscapesBrit. J. Polit. Sci. 28 139CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kollman, KMiller, J 2003 Computational Models in Political EconomyCambridge, MA:MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Laver, M 2005 Policy and the dynamics of political competitionAmer. Polit. Sci. Rev. 99 263CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laver, MSchilperoord, M 2007 Spatial models of political competition with endogenous political partiesPhil. Trans. R. Soc. B 362 1711CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Laver, MSergenti, E 2007
Laver, MSergenti, E 2011 Party Competition: An Agent-Based ModelPrincetonPrinceton University PressGoogle Scholar
Lloyd, S. P 1982 Least squares quantization in PCMIEEE T. Inform. Theory 28 129CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Okabe, ABoots, BSugihara, KChiu, S. N 2000 Spatial Tessellations: Concepts and Applications of Voronoi DiagramsNew YorkJohn WileyCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Osborne, M 2000 Entry-deterring policy differentiation by electoral candidatesMath. Soc. Sci. 40 41CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, K. A 1991 Models of Multiparty Electoral CompetitionNew YorkHarwood Academic PublishersGoogle Scholar
Sutton, R. SBarto, A. G 1998 Reinforcement Learning: An IntroductionCambridge, MAMIT PressGoogle Scholar
Teramoto, SDemaine, E 2006 265

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×