Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-8bhkd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-05T06:17:08.013Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

3 - Do we expect natural selection to produce rational behaviour?

from Part I - Rational and optimal decision making

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 November 2011

Anil K. Seth
Affiliation:
University of Sussex
Tony J. Prescott
Affiliation:
University of Sheffield
Joanna J. Bryson
Affiliation:
University of Bath
Get access

Summary

Summary

We expect that natural selection has resulted in behavioural rules that perform well, however, animals (including humans) sometimes make bad decisions. Researchers account for these with a variety of explanations; we concentrate on two of them. One is that the outcome is a side-effect; what matters is how a rule performs (in terms of reproductive success). Several rules may perform well in the environment in which they evolved, but their performance may differ in a ‘new’ environment (e.g., the lab). Some rules may perform very badly in this environment. We use the debate about whether animals follow the matching law rather than maximising their gains as an illustration. A second possibility is that we were wrong about what is optimal. The general idea here is that the setting in which optimal decisions are investigated is too simple and may not include elements that add extra degrees of freedom to the situation.

Introduction

The theme of this volume is modelling natural action selection. In this chapter we are concerned with modelling the action of natural selection. Selecting the best action when making a decision can be of great importance to an individual's fitness; we often term making the right choice as being ‘rational’. Ultimately, however, decision-making processes are products of an individual's evolutionary history, influenced to a greater or lesser degree by natural selection. Here we are concerned with whether we should expect ‘rational’ behaviour to be a product of naturally selected systems. In a general sense, rationality involves thinking and behaving reasonably and logically, but the term holds different meanings for researchers in different intellectual fields. The meaning and implications of the term ‘rationality’ have been discussed at great length. We do not intend to try to review all of these here, but use the categorisations of Kacelnik (2006) as a guide (for further introductions to the debate, see Manktelow and Over, 1993; Moser, 1990; Wilson, 1974). The general area of evolution and rationality is vast and our coverage is highly selective; many issues have not been considered. For other topics and perspectives, see Bernardo and Welch (2001), Bogacz et al. (this volume), Bateson and Healy (2005), Binmore (1997), Cooper (2001), Dickson (2006, 2008), Kirkpatrick et al. (2006), Nozick (1993), Pothos and Busemeyer (2009), Rieskamp et al. (2006), Robson (2002; 2003), Shafir and Le Boeuf (2002), Sober (1981), Stein (1996), and Waldman (1994).

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abrams, P. A 1986 Adaptive responses of predators to prey and prey to predators: the failure of the arms race analogyEvolution 40 1229CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Abrams, P. A 1993 Why predation rate should not be proportional to predator densityEcology 74 726CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adler, F. RKarban, R 1994 Defended fortresses or moving targets: another model of inducible defenses inspired by military metaphorsAm. Nat 144 813CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alferink, L. ACritchfield, T. SHitt, J. LHiggins, W. J 2009 Generality of the matching law as a descriptor of basketball shot selectionJ. Appl. Behav. Anal. 42 592CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aoki, SKurosu, U 2004 How many soldiers are optimal for an aphid colonyJ. Theor. Biol 230 313CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Arkes, H. RAyton, P 1999 The sunk cost and Concorde effects: are humans less rational than lower animals?Psychol. Bull 125 591CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K. J 1951 Social Choice and Individual ValuesNew YorkWileyGoogle Scholar
Bateson, M 2002 Context-dependent foraging choices in risk-sensitive starlingsAnim. Behav 64 251CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bateson, MHealy, S. D 2005 Comparative evaluation and its implications for mate choiceTrends Ecol. Evol 20 659CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bateson, MHealy, S. DHurly, T. A 2002 Irrational choices in hummingbird foraging behaviourAnim. Behav 63 587CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bateson, MHealy, S. DHurly, T. A 2003 Context-dependent foraging decisions in rufous hummingbirdsProc. R. Soc. Lond. Ser. B. Biol. Sci 270 1271CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Baum, W. M 1974 On two types of deviation from matching laws: bias and under-matchingJ. Exp. Anal. Behav 22 231CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belinsky, RGonzalez, FStahl, J 2004 Optimal behavior and concurrent variable interval schedulesJ. Math. Psychol 48 247CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernardo, A. EWelch, I 2001 On the evolution of overconfidence and entrepreneursJournal Econ. Manage. Strat 10 301CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, K 1997 Rationality and backward inductionJ. Econ. Met 4 23CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blomquist, G 1986 A utility maximization model of driver traffic safety behaviorAccident Anal. Prev 18 371CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Busemeyer, J. RTownsend, J. T 1993 Decision field-theory: a dynamic cognitive approach to decision-making in an uncertain environmentPsychol. Rev 100 432CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buss, D. MHaselton, M. GShackelford, T. KBleske, A. LWakefield, J. C 1998 Adaptations, exaptations, and spandrelsAm. Psychol 53 533CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Cervero, R 2003 Road expansion, urban growth, and induced travel: a path analysisJ. Amer. Plan. Assoc 69 145CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christen, Uvon Herrath, M. G 2005 Infections and autoimmunity: good or badJ. Immunol. 174 7481CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Clark, C. W 1994 Antipredator behavior and the asset-protection principleBehav. Ecol 5 159CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, W. S 2001 The Evolution of ReasonCambridgeCambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cuthill, I. CMaddocks, S. AWeall, C. VJones, E. K. M 2000 Body mass regulation in response to changes in feeding predictability and overnight energy expenditureBehav. Ecol 11 189CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dall, S. R. XMcNamara, J. MCuthill, I. C 1999 Interruptions to foraging and learning in a changing environmentAnim. Behav 57 233CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Darwin, C 1839 Journal of Researches into the Geology and Natural History of the Various Countries Visited by H.M.S. Beagle, Under the Command of Captain Fitzroy, R.N. from 1832 to 1836Henry ColburnLondonGoogle Scholar
Day, TProulx, S. R 2004 A general theory for the evolutionary dynamics of virulenceAm. Nat 163 E40CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Dickson, E. S 2006 Rational choice epistemology and belief formation in mass politicsJ. Theor. Polit 18 454CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dickson, E. S 2008 Expected utility violations evolve under status-based selection mechanismsJ. Theor. Biol 254 650CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fantino, E 1969 Choice and rate of reinforcementJ. Exp. Anal. Behav 12 723CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fantino, EAbarca, N 1985 Choice, optimal foraging, and the delay-reduction hypothesisBehav. Brain Sci 8 315CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fantino, EDavison, M 1983 Choice: some quantitative relationsJ. Exp. Anal. Behav 40 1CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fantino, EDunn, R 1983 The delay-reduction hypothesis: extension to three-alternative choiceJ. Exp. Psychol.-Anim. Behav. Process 9 132CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fantino, EPreston, R. ADunn, R 1993 Delay reduction: current statusJ. Exp. Anal. Behav 60 159CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fawcett, T. WJohnstone, R. A 2003 Optimal assessment of multiple cuesProc. R. Soc. Lond. Ser. B. Biol. Sci 270 1637CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ferster, C. BSkinner, B. F 1957 Schedules of ReinforcementEnglewood Cliffs, NJPrentice HallCrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Frank, S. A. 1996 Models of parasite virulenceQuart. Rev. Biol 71 37CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Goodwin, PNoland, R. B 2003 Building new roads really does create extra traffic: a response to Prakash et alAppl. Econ 35 1451CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gould, S. J 1997 The exaptive excellence of spandrels as a term and prototypeProc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 94 10750CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Grafen, A 1999 Formal Darwinism, the individual-as-maximizing-agent analogy and bet-hedgingProc. R. Soc. Lond. Ser. B. Biol. Sci 266 799CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haccou, PIwasa, Y 1995 Optimal mixed strategies in stochastic environmentsTheor. Popul. Biol 47 212CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hammerstein, PHagen, E. H 2005 The second wave of evolutionary economics in biologyTrends Ecol. Evol 20 604CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hampton, S. J 2004 Domain mismatches, scruffy engineering, exaptations and spandrelsTheor. Psychol 14 147CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harley, C. B 1981 Learning the evolutionarily stable strategyJ. Theor. Biol 89 611CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Herrnstein, R. J 1961 Relative and absolute strength of response as a function of frequency of reinforcementJ. Exp. Anal. Behav 4 267CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herrnstein, R. J 1970 On the law of effectJ. Exp. Anal. Behav 13 244CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hey, J. D 2002 Experimental economics and the theory of decision making under risk and uncertaintyGeneva Pap. Risk Ins 27 5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heyman, G. MHerrnstein, R. J 1986 More on concurrent interval-ratio schedules: a replication and reviewJ. Exp. Anal. Behav 46 331CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Heyman, G. MLuce, R. D 1979 Operant matching is not a logical consequence of maximizing reinforcement rateAnim. Learn. Behav 7 133CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heyman, G. MTanz, L 1995 How to teach a pigeon to maximize overall reinforcement rateJ. Exp. Anal. Behav 64 277CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Houston, A. I 1983 Optimality theory and matchingBehav. Anal. Lett 3 1Google Scholar
Houston, A. I 1986 The matching law applies to wagtails’ foraging in the wildJ. Exp. Anal. Behav 45 15CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Houston, A. I 1986 The optimal flight velocity for a bird exploiting patches of foodJ. Theor. Biol 119 345CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Houston, A. I 1987 The control of foraging decisionsQuantitative Analysis of BehaviourCommons, M. LKacelnik, AShettleworth, S. JHillsdale, NJLawrence Erlbaum41Google Scholar
Houston, A. I 1991 Violations of stochastic transitivity on concurrent chains: Implications for theories and choiceJ. Exp. Anal. Behav 55 323CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Houston, A. I 1997 Natural selection and context-dependent valuesProc. R. Soc. Lond. Ser. B. Biol. Sci 264 1539CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Houston, A. I 2008 Matching and ideal free distributionsOikos 117 978CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Houston, A. I 2009 Flying in the face of natureBehav. Proces 80 295CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Houston, A. I 2009 San Marco and evolutionary biologyBiol. Philos 24 215CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Houston, A. ICarbone, C 1992 The optimal allocation of time during the diving cycleBehav. Ecol 3 255CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Houston, A. IMcNamara, J 1981 How to maximize reward rate on two variable-interval paradigmsJ. Exp. Anal. Behav 35 367CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Houston, A. IMcNamara, J. M 1988 A framework for the functional analysis of behaviorBehav. Brain Sci 11 117CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Houston, A. IMcNamara, J. M 1989 The value of food: effects of open and closed economiesAnim. Behav 37 546CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Houston, A. IMcNamara, J. M 1999 Models of Adaptive Behaviour: An Approach Based on StateCambridgeCambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Houston, A. IMcNamara, J. MHeron, J. EBarta, Z 2003 The effect of foraging parameters on the probability that a dive is successfulProc. R. Soc. Lond. Ser. B. Biol. Sci 270 2451CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Houston, A. IMcNamara, J. MHutchinson, J. M. C 1993 General results concerning the trade-off between gaining energy and avoiding predationPhilos. Trans. R. Soc. Lond. Ser. B. Biol. Sci 341 375CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Houston, A. IMcNamara, J. MSteer, M. D 2007 Violations of transitivity under fitness maximizationBiol. Letters 3 365CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Houston, A. IStaddon, J. E. R 1981 Optimality principles and behavior: it's all for the bestBehav. Brain Sci 4 395CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Houston, A. ISteer, M. DKilleen, P. RThompson, W. A 2005 Predicting violations of transitivity when choices involve fixed or variable delays to foodModelling Natural Action Selection: An International WorkshopBryson, J. JPrescott, T. JSeth, A. KEdinburghAISB Press9Google Scholar
Houston, A. ISumida, B. H 1987 Learning rules, matching and frequency-dependenceJ. Theor. Biol 126 289CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hurly, T. AOseen, M. D 1999 Context-dependent, risk-sensitive foraging preferences in wild rufous hummingbirdsAnim. Behav 58 59CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hutchinson, J. M. CGigerenzer, G 2005 Simple heuristics and rules of thumb: where psychologists and behavioural biologists might meetBehav. Processes 69 97CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Iwasa, YHigashi, MYamamura, N 1981 Prey distribution as a factor determining the choice of optimal foraging strategyAm. Nat 117 710CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Janssen, W. HTenkink, E 1988 Considerations on speed selection and risk homeostasis in drivingAccident Anal. Prev 20 137CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Jokela, JSchmid-Hempel, PRigby, M. C 2000 Dr Pangloss restrained by the Red Queen: steps towards a unified defence theoryOikos 89 267CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kacelnik, A 2006 Meanings of rationalityRational Animals?Hurley, SNudds, MOxfordOxford University Press, pp. 87–106Google Scholar
Kacelnik, ABateson, M 1996 Risky theories: the effects of variance on foraging decisionsAm. Zool 36 402CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D 2003 Maps of bounded rationality: psychology for behavioral economicsAm. Econ. Rev 93 1449CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keeler, T. E 1994 Highway safety, economic behavior, and driving environmentAm. Econ. Rev 84 684Google Scholar
Kramer, D. L 1988 The behavioral ecology of air breathing by aquatic animalsCan. J. Zool 66 89CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirkpatrick, MRand, A. SRyan, M. J 2006 Mate choice rules in animalsAnim. Behav 71 1215CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lima, S. L 1998 Stress and decision making under the risk of predation: recent developments from behavioral, reproductive, and ecological perspectivesAdvances in the Study of Behavior: Stress and Behavior 27 215CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luce, R. D 1959 Individual Choice Behaviour: A Theoretical AnalysisNew YorkJohn WileyGoogle Scholar
Luce, R. D 1977 The choice axiom after twenty yearsJ. Math. Psychol 15 215CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luce, R. DRaiffa, H 1957 Games and DecisionsNew YorkJohn WileyGoogle Scholar
Luce, R. DSuppes, P 1965 Preference, utility, and subjective probabilityHandbook of Psychology IIILuce, R. DBush, R. RGalanter, ENew YorkJohn Wiley249Google Scholar
Manktelow, K. IOver, D. E 1993 Rationality: Psychological and Philosophical PerspectivesLondonRoutledgeGoogle Scholar
March, J. G 1996 Learning to be risk aversePsychol. Rev 103 309CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mazur, J. E 2000 Two- versus three-alternative concurrent-chain schedules: a test of three modelsJ. Exp. Psychol. Anim. Behav. Process 26 286CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
McDowell, J. J 1989 Two modern developments in matching theoryBehav. Analyst 12 153CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
McNamara, J. M 1982 Optimal patch use in a stochastic environmentTheor. Popul. Biol 21 269CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McNamara, J. M 1990 The policy which maximizes long-term survival of an animal faced with the risks of starvation and predationAdv. Appl. Probab 22 295CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McNamara, J. M 1995 Implicit frequency-dependence and kin selection in fluctuating environmentsEvol. Ecol 9 185CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McNamara, J. M 1996 Risk-prone behaviour under rules which have evolved in a changing environmentAm. Zool 36 484CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McNamara, J. MBarta, ZHouston, A. IRace, P 2005 A theoretical investigation of the effect of predators on foraging behaviour and energy reservesProc. R. Soc. Lond. Ser. B. Biol. Sci 272 929CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
McNamara, J. MBuchanan, K. L 2005 Stress, resource allocation, and mortalityBehav. Ecol. Sociobiol 16 1008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McNamara, J. MHouston, A. I 1980 The application of statistical decision: theory to animal behaviourJ. Theor. Biol 85 673CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
McNamara, J. MHouston, A. I 1985 Optimal foraging and learningJ. Theor. Biol 117 231CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McNamara, J. MHouston, A. I 1986 The common currency for behavioral decisionsAm. Nat 127 358CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McNamara, J. MHouston, A. I 1987 Partial preferences and foragingAnim. Behav 35 1084CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McNamara, J. MHouston, A. I 1987 Memory and the efficient use of informationJ. Theor. Biol 125 385CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McNamara, J. MHouston, A. I 1987 Foraging in patches: there's more to life than the marginal value theoremQuantitative Analyses of BehaviorCommons, M. LKacelnik, AShettleworth, S. JHillsdale, NJLawrence Erlbaum Associates23Google Scholar
McNamara, J. MHouston, A. I 1987 Starvation and predation as factors limiting population sizeEcology 68 1515CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McNamara, J. MHouston, A. I 1990 The value of fat reserves and the trade-off between starvation and predationActa Biotheor 38 1990CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McNamara, J. MHouston, A. I 1990 Starvation and predation in a patchy environmentLiving in a Patchy EnvironmentSwingland, I. RShorrocks, BOxfordOxford University Press23Google Scholar
McNamara, J. MHouston, A. I 1992 Risk-sensitive foraging: a review of the theoryBull. Math. Biol 54 355CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McNamara, J. MHouston, A. I 1994 The effect of a change in foraging options on intake rate and predation rateAm. Nat 144 978CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McNamara, J. MHouston, A. I 2009 Integrating function and mechanismTrends Ecol. Evol 24 670CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
McNamara, J. MHouston, A. ICollins, E. J 2001 Optimality models in behavioural biologySIAM Rev 43 413CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Medley, G. F 2002 The epidemiological consequences of optimisation of the individual host immune responseParasitology 125 S61CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Moser, P. K 1990 Rationality in Action: Contemporary ApproachesCambridgeCambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Myerson, JHale, S 1984 Practical implications of the matching lawJ. Appl. Behav. Anal 17 367CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Navarick, D. JFantino, E 1972 Transitivity as a property of choiceJ. Exp. Anal. Behav 18 389CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Navarick, D. JFantino, E 1974 Stochastic transitivity and unidimensional behavior theoriesPsychol. Rev 81 426CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Navarick, D. JFantino, E 1975 Stochastic transitivity and unidimensional control of choiceLearn. Motiv. 6 179CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Noland, R. BLem, L. L 2002 A review of the evidence for induced travel and changes in transportation and environmental policy in the US and the UKTransport. Res. D – Tr. E 7 1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norberg, R. Å 1981 Optimal flight speed in birds when feeding youngJ. Anim. Ecol 50 473CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nozick, R 1993 The Nature of RationalityPrinceton, NJPrinceton University PressGoogle Scholar
Oster, G. FWilson, E. O 1978 Caste and Ecology in the Social InsectsPrinceton University PressPrinceton, NJGoogle ScholarPubMed
Peltzman, S 1975 Effects of automobile safety regulationJ. Polit. Econ 83 677CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peterson, S. PHoffer, G. E 1994 The impact of airbag adoption on relative personal-injury and absolute collision insurance claimsJ. Consum. Res 20 657CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pierce, W. DEpling, W. F 1995 The applied importance of research on the matching lawJ. Appl. Behav. Anal 28 237CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Pothos, E. MBusemeyer, J. R 2009 A quantum probability explanation for violations of ‘rational’ decision theoryProc. R. Soc. Lond. Ser. B. Biol. Sci 276 2171CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rieskamp, JBusemeyer, J. RMellers, B. A 2006 Extending the bounds of rationality: evidence and theories of preferential choiceJ. Econ. Lit 44 631CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robson, A. J 2002 Evolution and human natureJ. Econ. Perspect 16 89CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robson, A. J 2003 The evolution of rationality and the Red QueenJ. Econ. Theory 111 1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Romagnani, S 2004 The increased prevalence of allergy and the hygiene hypothesis: missing immune deviation, reduced immune suppression, or bothImmunology 112 352CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sasaki, AEllner, S 1995 The evolutionarily stable phenotype distribution in a random environmentEvolution 49 337CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Savastano, H. IFantino, E 1994 Human choice in concurrent ratio-interval schedules of reinforcementJ. Exp. Anal. Behav 61 453CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Schuck-Paim, CPompilio, LKacelnik, A 2004 State-dependent decisions cause apparent violations of rationality in animal choicePLoS. Biol 2 2305CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Seth, A. K 1999 Evolving behavioural choice: an investigation into Herrnstein's matching lawAdvances in Artificial Life: Proceedings of the 5th European Conference (ECAL '99)Floreano, DNicoud, J.-DMondada, FBerlinSpringer-Verlag225CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seth, A. K 2001 Modeling group foraging: Individual suboptimality, interference, and a kind of matchingAdapt. Behav 9 67CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seth, A. K 2006 The ecology of action selection: insights from artificial lifePhilos. Trans. R. Soc. Lond. Ser. B. Biol. Sci 362 670Google Scholar
Shafir, S 1994 Intransitivity of preferences in honeybees: support for comparative-evaluation of foraging optionsAnim. Behav 48 55CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shafir, ELeBoeuf, R. A 2002 RationalityAnnu. Rev. Psychol 53 491CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Shafir, SWaite, T. ASmith, B. H 2002 Context-dependent violations of rational choice in honeybees () and gray jays ()Behav. Ecol. Sociobiol 51 180CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shettleworth, S. J 1985 Foraging, memory, and constraints on learningAnn. NY Acad. Sci 443 216CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Shettleworth, S. J 1989 Animals foraging in the lab: problems and promisesJ. Exp. Psychol. Anim. B 15 81CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shettleworth, S. JJordan, V 1986 Rats prefer handling food to waiting for itAnim. Behav 34 925CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shudo, EIwasa, Y 2001 Inducible defense against pathogens and parasites: Optimal choice among multiple optionsJ. Theor. Biol 209 233CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Shudo, EIwasa, Y 2004 Dynamic optimization of host defense, immune memory, and post-infection pathogen levels in mammalsJ. Theor. Biol 228 17CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Silberberg, AThomas, J. RBerendzen, N 1991 Human choice on concurrent variable-interval variable-ratio schedulesJ. Exp. Anal. Behav 56 575CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Simon, H. A 1978 Rationality as process and as product of thoughtAm. Econ. Rev 68 1Google Scholar
Smith, V. L 2003 Constructivist and ecological rationality in economicsAm. Econ. Rev 93 465CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sober, E 1981 The evolution of rationalitySynthese 46 95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Soltani, AWang, X. J 2006 A biophysically based neural model of matching law behavior: Melioration by stochastic synapsesJ. Neurosci 26 3731CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Spiga, RMaxwell, R. SMeisch, R. AGrabowski, J 2005 Human methadone self-administration and the generalized matching lawPsychol. Rec 55 525CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Squires, NFantino, E 1971 A model for choice in simple concurrent and concurrent-chains schedulesJ. Exp. Anal. Behav 15 27CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Stein, E 1996 Without Good Reason: The Rationality Debate in Philosophy and Cognitive ScienceOxfordClarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Stephens, D. WKerr, BFernandez-Juricic, E 2004 Impulsiveness without discounting: the ecological rationality hypothesisProc. R. Soc. Lond. Ser. B. Biol. Sci 271 2459CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Stephens, D. WKrebs, J. R 1986 Foraging TheoryPrinceton, NJPrinceton University PressGoogle Scholar
Strachan, D. P 1989 Hay-fever, hygiene, and household sizeBrit. Med. J 299 1259CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sugrue, L. PCorrado, G. SNewsome, W. T 2004 Matching behavior and the representation of value in the parietal cortexScience 304 1782CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sutherland, S 1994 Irrationality: The Enemy WithinLondon:Penguin BooksGoogle Scholar
Tenner, E 1996 Why Things Bite Back: New Technology and the Revenge EffectLondonFourth EstateGoogle Scholar
Todd, P. MGigerenzer, G 2000 How can we open up the adaptive toolboxBehav. Brain Sci 23 767CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, AKahneman, D 1981 The framing of decisions and the psychology of choiceScience 211 453CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, ASimonson, I 1993 Context-dependent preferencesManage. Sci 39 1179CrossRefGoogle Scholar
van Boven, MWeissing, F. J 2004 The evolutionary economics of immunityAm. Nat 163 277CrossRefGoogle Scholar
VanDam, N. MDeJong, T. JIwasa, YKubo, T 1996 Optimal distribution of defences: are plants smart investorsFunct. Ecol 10 128Google Scholar
Waite, T. A 2001 Background context and decision making in hoarding gray jaysBehav. Ecol 12 318CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Waite, T. A 2001 Intransitive preferences in hoarding gray jays ()Behav. Ecol. Sociobiol 50 116CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Waldman, M 1994 Systematic errors and the theory of natural selectionAm. Econ. Rev 84 482Google Scholar
Welton, N. JHouston, A. I 2001 A theoretical investigation into the direct and indirect effects of state on the risk of predationJ. Theor. Biol 123 275CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, B 1974 RationalityOxfordBasil BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Yazdanbakhsh, MKremsner, P. Gvan Ree, R 2002 Immunology: allergy, parasites, and the hygiene hypothesisScience 296 490CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×