Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-dh8gc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-03T00:12:55.315Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

4 - BIOECONOMY – Economically optimal spatial and inter-temporal fishing patterns in a metapopulation

from Part II - Effects of marine protected areas

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 August 2012

Joachim Claudet
Affiliation:
Centre National de la Recherche Scientifique (CNRS), Paris
Get access

Summary

Introduction

Over the past two decades, support for the creation of no-take areas as a means to curtail fishing, provide sources of relatively undisturbed habitats, and hedge against the uncertainties inherent in managing complex coupled human–natural systems has grown exponentially (Carr and Reed, 1993; Allison et al., 1998; National Research Council, 2001; Botsford et al., 2003; Gerber et al., 2003). Vocal opponents of marine reserves (i.e., no-take zones) are commercial and recreational fishermen, who already feel overburdened with regulations and are wary of the stated gains from marine reserves (Bernstein et al., 2004). Developing bioeconomic models that illuminate the trade-offs involved in creating a marine reserve can help reduce conflict over contentious sites and avoid disenfranchising various groups in the negotiation process.

Bioeconomic research on the value of using marine reserves for fishery management has focused on measuring the trade-offs in different governance regimes. Under open-access conditions, a typical assessment consists of comparing catch and biomass levels before and after the reserve is created (e.g., Beverton and Holt, 1957; Hannesson, 1998; Pezzey et al., 2000; Sanchirico and Wilen, 2001a; Rodwell et al., 2002; Sanchirico, 2005). Anderson (2002) and Hilborn et al. (2006) analyzed managing fisheries with closed areas and total allowable catches, which is a regulated open-access setting. Other research has investigated creating reserves in limited-entry fisheries where the amount of fishing effort is restricted (e.g., Holland and Brazee, 1996; Hastings and Botsford, 1999; Sanchirico, 2004) and the effects include catches along with profitability of the fishery. Across all of the governance regimes, reserves are beneficial for fishery management when the dispersal benefits (spillover of fish from the reserve to open areas) are greater than the opportunity cost of closing the area (lost catch or profit).

Type
Chapter
Information
Marine Protected Areas
A Multidisciplinary Approach
, pp. 99 - 120
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Allison, G. W.Lubchenco, J.Carr, M. H. 1998 Marine reserves are necessary but not sufficient for marine conservationEcological Applications 8 S79Google Scholar
Anderson, L. 2002 A bioeconomic analysis of marine reservesNatural Resource Modeling 15 311Google Scholar
Ascher, U. M.Petzold, L. R. 1998 Computer Methods for Ordinary Differential Equations and Differential-Algebraic EquationsPhiladelphiaSociety for Industrial and Applied Mathematics (SIAM)
Bernstein, B.Iudicello, S.Stringer, C. 2004
Beverton, R. J. H.Holt, S. J. 1957 On the Dynamics of Exploited Fish PopulationsLondon: Ministry of Agriculture, Fisheries and Food
Botsford, L. W.Smith, B. D.Quinn, J. F. 1994 Bimodality in size distributions: red sea urchin as an exampleEcological Applications 4 42Google Scholar
Botsford, L. W.Micheli, F.Hastings, A. 2003 Principles for the design of marine reservesEcological Applications 13 25Google Scholar
Browman, H. I.Stergiou, K. I. 2004 Perspectives on ecosystem-based approaches to the management of marine resourcesMarine Ecology Progress Series 274 269Google Scholar
Brown, G. M.Roughgarden, J. 1997 A metapopulation model with private property and a common poolEcological Economics 22 65Google Scholar
Bryson, A. E. 1999 Dynamic OptimizationReading, MAAddison Wesley
Caley, M. J.Carr, M. H.Hixon, M. A. 1996 Recruitment and the population dynamics of open marine populationsAnnual Review of Ecology and Systematics 27 477Google Scholar
Carr, M. H.Reed, D. C. 1993 Conceptual issues relevant to marine harvest refuges: examples from temperate reef fishesCanadian Journal of Fisheries and Aquatic Sciences 50 2019Google Scholar
Clark, C. W. 1990 Mathematical Bioeconomics: The Optimal Management of Renewable ResourcesNew YorkJohn Wiley
Clark, C. W.Munro, G. 1975 Economics of fishing and modern capital theory: a simplified approachJournal of Environmental Economics and Management 2 92Google Scholar
Costello, C.Polasky, S. 2008 56 1
Cowen, R. K.Lwiza, K. M. M.Sponaugle, S.Paris, C. B.Olson, D. B. 2000 Connectivity of marine populations: open or closedScience 287 857Google Scholar
Cowen, R. K.Paris, C. B.Srinivasan, A. 2006 Scaling connectivity in marine populationsScience 311 522Google Scholar
Crutchfield, J. A.Zellner, A. 1962 Economic Aspects of the Pacific Halibut FisheryWashington, DC:US Department of the Interior
Gerber, L. R.Botsford, L. W.Hastings, A. 2003 Population models for marine reserve design: a retrospective and prospective synthesisEcological Applications 13 S47Google Scholar
Grafton, R. Q.Kompas, T.Lindenmayer, D. 2005 Marine reserves with ecological uncertaintyBulletin of Mathematical Biology 67 957Google Scholar
Hannesson, R. 1998 Marine reserves: what will they accomplishMarine Resource Economics 13 159Google Scholar
Hart, D. R.Sissenwine, M. P. 2009 Marine reserve effects on fishery profits: a comment on White . (2008)Ecology Letters 12 E9Google Scholar
Hastings, A.Botsford, L. 1999 Equivalence in yield from marine reserves and traditional fisheries managementScience 284 1537Google Scholar
Hilborn, R.Quinn, T. P.Schindler, D. E.Rogers, D. E. 2003 Biocomplexity and fisheries sustainabilityProceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 100 6564Google Scholar
Hilborn, R.Micheli, F.Leo, G. D. 2006 Integrating marine protected areas with catch regulationCanadian Journal of Fisheries and Aquatic Sciences 63 642Google Scholar
Holland, D. S.Brazee, R. J. 1996 Marine reserves for fisheries managementMarine Resource Economics 11 157Google Scholar
Kamien, M. L.Schwartz, N. L. 1991 Dynamic Optimization: The Calculus of Variations and Optimal Control in Economics and ManagementNew York: North-Holland
Kritzer, J. P.Sale, P. F. 2004 Metapopulation ecology in the sea: from Levins’ model to marine ecology and fisheries scienceFish and Fisheries 5 131Google Scholar
Levin, P. S.Fogarty, M. J.Murawski, S. A.Fluharty, D. 2009 Integrated ecosystem assessments: developing the scientific basis for ecosystem-based management of the oceanPLoS Biol 7Google Scholar
McLeod, K. L.Lubchenco, J.Palumbi, S. R.Rosenberg, A. 2005
Murawski, S. A. 2007 Ten myths concerning ecosystem approaches to marine resource managementMarine Policy 31 681Google Scholar
National Research Council 2001 Marine Protected Areas: Tools for Sustaining Ocean EcosystemsWashington, DC
Neubert, M. G. 2003 Marine reserves and optimal harvestingEcology Letters 6 843Google Scholar
Pezzey, J. C. V.Roberts, C. M.Urdal, B. T. 2000 A simple bioeconomic model of a marine reserveEcological Economics 33 77Google Scholar
Polacheck, T. 1990 Year round closed areas as a management toolNatural Resource Modeling 4 327Google Scholar
Quinn, T. J.Deriso, R. B. 1999 Quantitative Fishery DynamicsNew York
Rodwell, L.Barbier, E.Roberts, C.McClanahan, T. 2002 A model of tropical marine reserve–fishery linakgesNatural Resource Modeling 15 453Google Scholar
Sanchirico, J. N. 2004 Designing a cost-effective marine reserve network: a bioeconomic metapopulation analysisMarine Resource Economics 19 46Google Scholar
Sanchirico, J. N. 2005 Additivity properties in metapopulation models: implications for the assessment of marine reservesJournal of Environmental Economics and Management 49 1Google Scholar
Sanchirico, J. N.Wilen, J. E. 1999 Bioeconomics of spatial exploitation in a patchy environmentJournal of Environmental Economics and Management 37 129Google Scholar
Sanchirico, J. N.Wilen, J. E. 2001 A bioeconomic model of marine reserve creationJournal of Environmental Economics and Management 42 257Google Scholar
Sanchirico, J. N.Wilen, J. E. 2001 Dynamics of spatial exploitation: a metapopulation approachNatural Resource Modeling 14 391Google Scholar
Sanchirico, J. N.Wilen, J. E. 2005 Optimal spatial management of renewable resources: matching policy scope to ecosystem scaleJournal of Environmental Economics and Management 50 23Google Scholar
Sanchirico, J. N.Wilen, J. E. 2010 Economically optimal management of a metapopulationSpatial EcologyCantrell, S.Cosner, C.Ruan, S.Chapman and Hall317
Sanchirico, J. N.Malvadkar, U.Hastings, A.Wilen, J. E. 2006 When are no-take zones an economically optimal fishery management strategyEcological Applications 16 1643Google Scholar
Schaefer, M. B. 1957 Some considerations of population dynamics and economics in relation to management of marine fisheriesJournal of the Fisheries Research Board of Canada 14 669Google Scholar
Scott, A. D. 1955 The fishery: the objectives of sole ownershipJournal of Political Economy 63 116Google Scholar
Shanks, A.Grantham, B.Carr, M. 2003 Propagule dispersal distance and the size and spacing of marine reservesEcological Applications 13 S159Google Scholar
Steele, M. A. 1997 Population regulation by post-settlement mortality in two temperate reef fishesOecologia 112 64Google Scholar
Tuck, G. N.Possingham, H. P. 1994 Optimal harvesting strategies for a metapopulationBulletin of Mathematical Biology 56 107Google Scholar
Tuck, G. N.Possingham, H. P. 2000 Marine protected areas for spatially structured exploited stocksMarine Ecology Progress Series 192 89Google Scholar
Warner, R. R.Cowen, R. K. 2002 Local retention of production in marine populations: evidence, mechanisms, and consequencesBulletin of Marine Science 70 245Google Scholar
White, C. 2009 Density dependence and the economic efficacy of marine reservesTheoretical Ecology 2 127Google Scholar
White, C.Kendall, B. E.Gaines, S.Siegel, D. A.Costello, C. 2008 Marine reserve effects on fishery profitEcology Letters 11 370Google Scholar
Wilen, J. E. 2006 78 529

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×