Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-fbnjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-06T11:00:17.608Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

8 - Economic Consequences of Terrorism and Natural Disasters: The Computable General Equilibrium Approach

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 December 2017

Ali E. Abbas
Affiliation:
University of Southern California
Milind Tambe
Affiliation:
University of Southern California
Detlof von Winterfeldt
Affiliation:
University of Southern California
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2017

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Arrow, K., Chenery, H., Minhas, B., & Solow, R. (1961). Capital-labor substitution and economic efficiency. Review of Economics and Statistics, 45, 225250.Google Scholar
Arrow, K., & Hahn, F. (1971). General competitive analysis. San Francisco, CA: Oliver and Boyd, Edinburgh; Holden-Day.Google Scholar
Boisvert, R. (1992). Indirect losses from a catastrophic earthquake and the local, regional, and national interest. In Indirect economic consequences of a catastrophic earthquake (pp. 204–266). Washington, DC: FEMA.Google Scholar
Brookshire, D., & McKee, M. (1992). Other indirect costs and losses from earthquakes: issues and estimation. In Indirect economic consequences of a catastrophic earthquake (pp. 235–267). Washington, DC: FEMA.Google Scholar
Bruno, M., Dougherty, C., & Fraenkel, M. (1970). Dynamic input-output, trade and development. In Carter, A. P. & Brody, A. (Eds.), Applications of input-output analysis (pp. 48–69). Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Burfisher, M. (2011). Introduction to computable general equilibrium models. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burns, W., & Slovic, P. (2010). Predicting and modeling public response to a terrorist strike. In Slovic, P. (Ed.), The feeling of risk: New directions in the perception of risk (pp. 285–306). London: Earthscan Publishing.Google Scholar
Chenery, H., & Clark, P. (1959). Interindustry economics. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Debreu, G. (1959). Theory of value: An axiomatic analysis of economic equilibrium. New Haven, CT: Cowles Foundation, Yale University Press, pp. xi+114.Google Scholar
Dervis, K., de Melo, J., & Robinson, S. (1982). General equilibrium models for development policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Dixon, P. B., Giesecke, J. A., Rimmer, M. T., & Rose, A. (2011b). The economic costs to the U.S. of closing its borders: A computable general equilibrium analysis. Defence and Peace Economics, 22(1), 8597.Google Scholar
Dixon, P. B., Johnson, M., & Rimmer, M. T. (2011a). Economy-wide effects of reducing illegal immigrants in U.S. employment. Contemporary Economic Policy, 29(1), 1430.Google Scholar
Dixon, P. B., Koopman, R. B., & Rimmer, M. T. (2013). The MONASH style of CGE modeling: A framework for practical policy analysis. In Dixon, P. B. & Jorgenson, D. W. (Eds.), Handbook of computable general equilibrium modeling (chapter 2). Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Dixon, P. B., Lee, B., Muehlenbeck, T., Rimmer, M. T., Rose, A. Z., & Verikios, G. (2010). Effects on the U.S. of an H1N1 epidemic: Analysis with a quarterly CGE model. Journal of Homeland Security and Emergency Management, 7(1), Article 75.Google Scholar
Dixon, P. B., Osborne, S., & Rimmer, M. T. (2007b). The economy-wide effects in the United States of replacing crude petroleum with biomass. Energy and Environment, 18(6), 709722.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dixon, P. B., Parmenter, B. R., Sutton, J., & Vincent, D. P. (1982). ORANI: A multisectoral model of the Australian economy. Contributions to Economic Analysis 142. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Dixon, P. B., & Rimmer, M. T. (2002). Dynamic general equilibrium modelling for forecasting and policy: A practical guide and documentation of MONASH. Contributions to Economic Analysis 256. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Company, pp. xiv+338.Google Scholar
Dixon, P. B., & Rimmer, M. T. (2004). The US economy from 1992 to 1998: Results from a detailed CGE model. Economic Record, 80 (Special Issue), pp. S13S23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dixon, P. B., & Rimmer, M. T. (2010). Validating a detailed, dynamic CGE model of the U.S. Economic Record, 86 (Special issue), pp. 2234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dixon, P. B., & Rimmer, M. T. (2011). You can’t have a CGE recession without excess capacity. Economic Modelling, 28(1–2), 602613.Google Scholar
Dixon, P. B., & Rimmer, M. T. (2013). Validation in CGE modeling. In Dixon, P. B. & Jorgenson, D. W. (Eds.), Handbook of Computable General Equilibrium Modeling (chapter 19) Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Dixon, P. B., Rimmer, M. T., & Roberts, B. W. (2014). Restricting employment of low-paid immigrants: A general equilibrium assessment of the social welfare implications for legal U.S. wage-earners. Contemporary Economic Policy, 32(3), 639652.Google Scholar
Dixon, P. B., Rimmer, M. T., & Tsigas, M. E. (2007a). Regionalizing results from a detailed CGE model: macro, industry and state effects in the U.S. of removing major tariffs and quotas. Papers in Regional Science, 86(1), 3155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Domestic Nuclear Detection Office (DNDO). (2013). Spreadsheet of consequence information for attacks using improvised nuclear devices, sent to the National Center for Risk and Economic Analysis of Terrorism Events (CREATE), University of Southern California. For Official Use Only/FOUO.Google Scholar
Evans, H. D. (1972). A general equilibrium analysis of protection: The effects of protection in Australia. Contributions to Economic Analysis 76. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Company.Google Scholar
Fox, A., Powers, W., & Winston, A. (2008). Textile and apparel barriers and rules of origin: What’s left to gain after the agreement on textiles and clothing? Journal of Economic Integration, 23(3), 656684.Google Scholar
Gehlhar, M., Somwaru, A., Dixon, P. B., Rimmer, M. T., & Winston, A. R. (2010). Economywide implications from US bioenergy expansion. American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings, 100(3), 172177.Google Scholar
Giergenzer, G., & Selten, R. (Eds.) (2002). Bounded rationality: The adaptive toolbox. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Giesecke, J. A. (2011). Development of a large-scale single U.S. region CGE model using IMPLAN data: A Los Angeles County example with a productivity shock application. Spatial Economic Analysis 6(3).Google Scholar
Giesecke, J. A., Burns, W., Barret, A., Bayrak, E., Rose, A., Slovic, P., & Suher, M. (2012). Assessment of the regional economic impacts of catastrophic events: CGE analysis of resource loss and behavioral effects of an RDD attack scenario. Risk Analysis, 32(4), 583600.Google Scholar
Harrison, J., Horridge, J. M., Jerie, M., & Pearson, K. R. (2014). GEMPACK manual, GEMPACK Software, ISBN 978-1-921654-34-3, available at www.copsmodels .com/gpmanual.htm.Google Scholar
Heal, G., & Kunreuther, H. (2007). Modeling interdependent risks. Risk Analysis, 27(3), 621634.Google Scholar
Heatwole, N., Rose, A., Dixon, P., Rimmer, M., Wittwer, G., & Wei, D. (2014). Modeling the temporal and spatial consequences of nuclear terrorism events. Final report to the U.S. Domestic Nuclear Detection Office (DNDO) by the National Center for Risk and Economic Analysis of Terrorism Events (CREATE), University of Southern California.Google Scholar
Hertel, T. (Ed.) (1997). Global trade analysis: Modeling and applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Horridge, J. M., Madden, J. R., & Wittwer, G. (2005). Impact of the 2002–03 drought on Australia. Journal of Policy Modeling, 27(3), 285308.Google Scholar
Horridge, M., Meeraus, A., Pearson, K., & Rutherford, T. (2013). Software platforms: GAMS and GEMPACK. In Dixon, P. B. & Jorgenson, D. W. (Eds.), Handbook of computable general equilibrium modeling (chapter 20, pp. 1331–1382). Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Johansen, L. (1960). A multisectoral Study of economic growth. Contributions to Economic Analysis 21. Amsterdam: North-Holland Publishing Company, pp. x+177.Google Scholar
Jorgenson, D., Jin, H., Slesnick, D., & Wilcoxen, P. (2013). An econometric approach to general equilibrium modeling. In Dixon, P. B. & Jorgenson, D. W. (Eds.), Handbook of computable general equilibrium modeling (chapter 17). Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Kajitani, Y., & Tatano, H. (2009). Estimation of lifeline resilience factors based on empirical surveys of Japanese industries. Earthquake Spectra, 25(4), 755776.Google Scholar
Kasperson, R., Renn, O., Slovic, P., Brown, H., Emel, J., Goble, R., Kasperson, J., & Ratick, S. (1988). The social amplification of risk: a conceptual framework. Risk Analysis, 8(2), 177187.Google Scholar
Leontief, W. W. (1936). Quantitative input-output relations in the economic system of the United States. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 18(3), 105125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leontief, W. W. (1941). The structure of the American economy 1919–1929. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Manne, A. S. (1963). Key sectors of the Mexican economy 1960–1970. In Manne, A. S. & Markowitz, H. M. (Eds.), Studies in process analysis (pp. 379–400). New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
McClelland, G., Schulze, W., & Hurd, B. (1990). The effect of risk beliefs on property values: A case study of a hazardous waste site. Risk Analysis, 10, 485497.Google Scholar
McGuire, M. G. (1987). Defence economics. In Eatwell, J., Milgate, M. & Newman, P (Eds.), The new Palgrave dictionary of economics (pp. 760–762). London: McMillan.Google Scholar
Park, J. Y., Moore, J. E., & Richardson, H. W. (2013). The Gulf oil spill and economic impacts: Extending the National Interstate Economic Model (NIEMO) to account for induced impacts. Journal of Homeland Security and Emergency Management, 10(1), 231244.Google Scholar
Pearson, K. R., & Codsi, G. (1991). The update and multi-step version of TABLO: User guidelines. GEMPACK document No 30, Impact Project, ISSN 1030–2514. University of Melbourne. Available from the Centre of Policy Studies, Victoria University, Melbourne.Google Scholar
Rose, A. (1995). Input-output economics and computable general equilibrium models. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 6(3), 295304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose, A. (2004). Defining and measuring economic resilience to disasters. Disaster Prevention and Management, 13(4), 307314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose, A. (2009). Economic resilience to disasters. CARRI Research Report #8, ORNL.Google Scholar
Rose, A. (2015). Macroeconomic consequences of terrorist attacks: Estimation for the analysis of policies and rules. In Mansfield, C. & Smith, V. K. (Eds.), Benefit transfer for the analysis of DHS policies and rules (pp. 172–200). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Rose, A., & Guha, G. (2004). Computable general equilibrium modeling of electric utility lifeline losses from earthquakes. In Okuyama, Y. & Chang, S. (eds.), Modeling spatial economic impacts of natural hazards (pp. 119–142). Heidelberg: Springer.Google Scholar
Rose, A., & Guha, G. & Liao, S. (2005). Modeling regional economic resilience to disasters: A computable general equilibrium analysis of water service disruptions. Journal of Regional Science, 45(1), 75112.Google Scholar
Rose, A., Liao, S., & Bonneau, A. (2011). Regional economic impacts of a Verdugo earthquake disruption of Los Angeles water supplies: A computable general equilibrium analysis. Earthquake Spectra, 27(3), 881906.Google Scholar
Rose, A., Oladosu, G., Lee, B., & Beeler Asay, G. (2009). The economic impacts of the 2001 terrorist attacks on the World Trade Center: A computable general equilibrium analysis. Peace Economics, Peace Science, and Public Policy 15, Article 6.Google Scholar
Rose, A., Oladosu, G., & Liao, S. (2007). Business interruption impacts of a terrorist attack on the electric power system of Los Angeles: Customer resilience to a total blackout. Risk Analysis, 27, 1331.Google Scholar
Sandee, J. (1960). A long-term planning model for India. New York: Asia Publishing House and Calcutta: Statistical Publishing Company.Google Scholar
Scarf, H. E. (1967). On the computation of equilibrium prices. In Fellner, W. (Ed.), Ten essays in honor of Irving Fisher. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Scarf, H. E. (1973). The computation of economic equilibria. New Haven, CT/London: Yale University Press, pp. x + 249.Google Scholar
Shoven, J. B., & Whalley, J. (1984). Applied general-equilibrium models of taxation and international trade: An introduction and survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 22(3), 10071051.Google Scholar
Slovic, P. (1987). Perception of risk. Science, 236(4799), 280285.Google Scholar
Sue Wing, I., Rose, A., & Wein, A. (2016). Economic consequences of the ARkStorm scenario. Natural Hazards Review, 17(4), 1–10.Google Scholar
U.S. International Trade Commission. (2004, 2007, 2009, 2011, 2013). The economic effects of significant U.S. import restraints: Fourth, fifth, sixth, seventh & eighth update. Investigation no. 332-325, Publications 3701, 3906, 4094, 4253, 4440.Google Scholar
Wittwer, G. (Ed.) (2012). Economic modeling of water: The Australian CGE experience. Dordrecht, Heidelberg, Germany: Springer.Google Scholar
Zahniser, S., Hertz, T., Dixon, P. B., & Rimmer, M. T. (2012). Immigration policy and its possible effects on U.S. agriculture and the market for hired farm labor: A simulation analysis. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 94(2), 477482.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×