Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-j824f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-05T11:11:18.227Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

2 - Is Government Regulation the Solution?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 July 2014

Terry L. Anderson
Affiliation:
Property and Environment Research Center
Gary D. Libecap
Affiliation:
University of California, Santa Barbara
Get access

Summary

As discussed in Chapter 1, we have a multitude of demands for environmental goods and services. Whether it is clean air and water, tropical rainforests, habitat for polar bears, open spaces, controls on carbon emissions, whales, or energy conservation, we are willing to spend time and money on getting more of the environmental goods we want. The problems we face are how to respond to changing demands, how to tradeoff competing demands against one another, and how to balance these with the desires for other goods and services in the economy. Addressing these questions requires that environmental policies be efficient or as cost-effective as possible. This chapter examines the role of government regulations as a way of improving environmental quality – which is the traditional approach – and compares it to environmental markets.

There are many different ways to produce environmental goods, ranging from markets with well-specified private property rights, the subject of Chapter 3, to governmental regulation, the solution considered in detail here. One reason for choosing government rather than markets is the potential for markets to fail in fully accounting for social costs and benefits.

As discussed in Chapter 1, we have a multitude of demands for environmental goods and services. Whether it is clean air and water, tropical rainforests, habitat for polar bears, open spaces, controls on carbon emissions, whales, or energy conservation, we are willing to spend time and money on getting more of the environmental goods we want. The problems we face are how to respond to changing demands, how to tradeoff competing demands against one another, and how to balance these with the desires for other goods and services in the economy. Addressing these questions requires that environmental policies be efficient or as cost-effective as possible. This chapter examines the role of government regulations as a way of improving environmental quality – which is the traditional approach – and compares it to environmental markets.

Type
Chapter
Information
Environmental Markets
A Property Rights Approach
, pp. 21 - 52
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2014

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Keohane, Nathaniel O. and Olmstead, Sheila M. (2007), Markets and the Environment, Washington D.C.: Island Press, 65–83Google Scholar
Baland, Jean-Marie and Platteau, Jean-Philippe (1996), Halting Degradation of Natural Resources: Is there a Role for Rural Communities? New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Stavins, Robert N. (2007), “Market-Based Environmental Policies: What Can We Learn from U.S. Experience (and Related Research)?” in Freeman, Jody and Kolstad, Charles D., eds., Moving to Markets in Environmental Regulation, New York: Oxford University Press, 25, 3–32Google Scholar
Kolstad, Charles D. (2011), Environmental Economics, 2nd Edition, New York: Oxford University Press, 223Google Scholar
Hardin, Garrett (1968), “The Tragedy of the Commons,” Science 162: 1243–1248Google ScholarPubMed
Coase, Ronald H. (1974), “The Lighthouse in Economics,” Journal of Law and Economics 17(2): 357–376CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haddock, David D. (2007), “Irrelevant Externality Angst,” Journal of Interdisciplinary Economics 19(1): 3–18CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hay, Bruce, Stavins, Robert, and Vietor, Richard H.K., eds. (2005), Environmental Protection and the Social Responsibility of Firms, Washington D.C.
Krutilla, John (1967), “Conservation Reconsidered,” American Economic Review, Volume 57(4): 777–786Google Scholar
Demsetz, Harold (1969), “Information and Efficiency: Another Viewpoint,” Journal of Law and Economics 12(1): 1–22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M. and Tullock, Gordon (1962), The Calculus of Consent, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Volden, Craig and Wiseman, Alan E. (2007), “Bargaining in Legislatures over Particularistic and Collective Goods,” American Political Science Review, 101(1): 79–92CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gordon, H. Scott (1954), “The Economic Theory of A Common-Property Resource: The Fishery,” Journal of Political Economy 62(2): 124–142CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scott, Anthony (1955), “The Fishery: The Objectives of Sole Ownership,” Journal of Political Economy 63(2): 116–124CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald (1960), “The Problem of Social Cost,” Journal of Law and Economics 3: 1–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cheung, Steven N.S. (1970), “The Structure of a Contract and the Theory of a Non-Exclusive Resource,” Journal of Law and Economics 13(1): 49–70Google Scholar
Umbeck, John (1981), “Might Makes Right: A Theory of the Foundation and Initial Distribution of Property Rights,” Economic Inquiry 19(1): 38–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acheson, James M. and Gardner, Roy J. (2005), “Spatial Strategies and Territoriality in the Maine Lobster Industry,” Rationality and Society 17(3): 309–341CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yablonski, Brian (2009), “The National Parks: America's Best IdeaPERC Reports 27(3)Google Scholar
Costello, Christopher, Gaines, Steven, and Lynham, John, 2008, “Can Catch Shares Prevent Fisheries from Collapse?Science 321, September 19: 1677–1678CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Glennon, Robert (2002), Water Follies: Groundwater Pumping and the Fate of America's Fresh WatersWashington DC: Island PressGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor (1990), Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action, New York: Cambridge University Press, 104–139CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snyder, J. Herbert (1954), “The Economics of Groundwater Mining,” Journal of Farm Economics 36(4): 600–610CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hotelling, Harold (1931), “The Economics of Exhaustible Resources.” Journal of Political Economy 39(2): 137–175CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Libecap, Gary D. (1989), Contracting for Property Rights, New York: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Pigou, A. C. (1932), The Economics of Welfare, 4th edition, London: Macmillan: 183–184Google Scholar
Dahlman, Carl (1979), “The Problem of Externality,” Journal of Law and Economics, 22(1): 141–162CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bator, Francis M. (1957), “The Simple Analytics of Welfare Maximization,” American Economic Review 47(1): 22–59Google Scholar
Hayek, F.A. (1945), “The Use of Knowledge in Society, American Economic Review 35(4): 519–530Google Scholar
Segerson, Kathleen (1988), “Uncertainty and Incentives for Nonpoint Pollution Control,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 15: 87–98CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xepapadeas, A.P. (1992), “Environmental Policy Design and Dynamic Nonpoint-Source Pollution,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 23: 22–39CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Horan, Richard D., Shortle, James S., and Abler, David G. (1998), “Ambient Taxes When Polluters have Multiple Choices,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 36: 186–199CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, Ronald N. and Libecap, Gary D. (1982), “Contracting Problems and Regulation: The Case of the Fishery,” American Economic Review 72(5): 1005–1022Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur (1965), The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Anderson, Terry L., Arnason, Ragnar, and Libecap, Gary D. (2011), “Efficiency Advantages of Grandfathering in Rights-Based Fisheries Management,” Annual Review of Resource Economics
Wiener, Jonathan Baert (2007), “Think Globally, Act Globally; The Limits of Local Climate Change Policies.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 155: 101–119Google Scholar
Bushnell, James B., and Mansur, Erin J. (2011), “Vertical Targeting and Leakage in Carbon Policy,” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 10(3): 263–267CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joskow, Paul L. and Schmalensee, Richard (1998), “The Political Economy of Market-Based Environmental Policy: The U.S. Acid Rain Program,” Journal of Law and Economics 41(April): 37–83CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fullerton, Don and Metcalf, Gilbert E. (1997), “Environmental Taxes and the Double-Dividend Hypothesis: Did You Really Expect Something for Nothing?” Cambridge, MA: NBER Working Paper w6199CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, Ronald N. and Libecap, Gary D. (2003), “Transaction Costs and Coalition Stability under Majority Rule,” Economic Inquiry 41(2): 193–207CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tullock, Gordon (2008), “Public Choice,” in Durlauf, Steven N. and Blume, Lawrence E., eds., The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd Edition, New York: Palgrave MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Johnson, Ronald N. and Libecap, Gary D. (2001), “Information Distortion and Competitive Remedies in Government Transfer Policies: The Case of Ethanol,” Economics of Governance 2(2): 101–134CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pigou, A.C. (1912), Wealth and Welfare, London: Macmillan, 247–248Google Scholar
Medema, Steven G. (2009), The Hesitant Hand: Taming Self-Interest in the History of Economic Ideas. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, George (1971), “The Theory of Economic Regulation,” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2: 3–21CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laffont, J.J. and Tirole, J. (1991), “The Politics of Government Decision Making. A Theory of Regulatory Capture,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 106(4): 1089–1127CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peltzman, (1976), “Toward a More General Theory of Regulation,” Journal of Law and Economics 19(2): 211–240CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peltzman, Sam (1998), Political Participation and Government Regulation, Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Krueger, Anne O. (1974), “The Political Economy of the Rent-Seeking Society,” American Economic Review 64(3): 291–303Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon (1967), “The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies, and Theft,” Western Economic Journal 5(3): 224–232Google Scholar
Johnson, Ronald N. and Libecap, Gary D. (1994), The Federal Civil Service and the Problem of Bureaucracy: The Economics and Politics of Institutional Change, Chicago: University of Chicago Press and NBER, 96–125CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keohane, Nathaniel O., Revesz, Richard L., and Stavins, Robert N. (1998), “The Choice of Regulatory Instruments in Environmental Policy,” Harvard Environmental Law Review 22: 313–345Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S. (1983), “A Theory of Competition among Pressure Groups for Political Influence,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 98(3): 371–400CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Homans, Frances R. and Wilen, James E. (1997), “A Model of Regulated Open Access Resource Use,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 32: 1–27CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Vernon L. (1969), “On Models of Commercial Fishing,” The Journal of Political Economy, 77(2): 181–198CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leal, Donald R. (2005), “Fencing the Fishery: A Primer on Rights Based Fishing,” in Leal, Donald R., Ed., Evolving Property Rights in Marine Fisheries, Lanham, MD: Rowman and LittlefieldGoogle Scholar
Hannesson, Rögnvaldur (2004), The Privatization of the Oceans, Cambridge, MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Gutierrez, Nicolas L., Hilborn, Ray, and Defeo, Omar (2011), “Leadership, Social Capital and Incentives Promote Successful Fisheries,” Nature 470: 386–389CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Myers, Ransom A. and Worm, Boris (2003), “Rapid Worldwide Depletion of Predatory Fish Communities,” Nature 423: 280–283CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Devine, Jennifer A., Baker, Krista D., and Haedrich, Richard L. (2006), “Fisheries: Deep-Sea Fishes Qualify as Endangered,” Nature 439, 29CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Worm, Boris, et al. (2009), “Rebuilding Global Fisheries,” Science 325, 578–585.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Arnason, Ragnar (2002), “A Review of International Experiences with ITQ,” Annex to Future Options for UK Fishing Management, Report to the Department for the Environment, Food and Rural Affairs, CEMARE, University of PortsmouthGoogle Scholar
Shotton, Ross, 2000, “Current Property Rights Systems in Fisheries Management,” in Shotton, Ross, ed. Use of Property Rights in Fisheries Management, Proceedings of the FishRights99 Conference, Fremantle Western Australia, RomeGoogle Scholar
Grafton, R.Q., Squires, D., and Fox, K.J. (2001), “Private Property and Economic Efficiency: A Study of a Common-Pool Resource, Journal of Law and Economics, 43(2): 679–713CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Casey, K.E., Dewees, C.M., Turris, B.R., Wilen, J.E. (1995), “The Effects of Individual Vessel Quotas in the British Columbia Halibut Fishery,” Marine Resource Economics 10: 211−30CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krier, Jame E. and Ursin, Edmund (1977). Pollution and Policy: A Case Essay on California and Federal Experience with Motor Vehicle Air Pollution, 1940–1975. Berkeley: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Ackerman, Bruce and Hassler, William T. (1981), Clean Coal/Dirty Air: or How the Clean Air Act Became a Multibillion-Dollar Bail-Out for High-Sulfur Coal Producers, New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Crandall, Robert T. (1981) in the Bell Journal of Economics 12(2): 677–682CrossRef
Freeman, Jody and Kolstad, Charles D., 2007, “Prescriptive Environmental Regulations versus Market-Based Incentives,” in Freeman, Jody and Kolstad, Charles D., eds., Moving to Markets in Environmental Regulation: Lessons from Twenty Years of Experience, New York: Oxford University Press, 3–16Google Scholar
Pashigian, Peter B. (1985), “Environmental Regulation: Whose Self-Interests are Being Protected?Economic Inquiry 23(4): 551–584CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goklany, Indur M. (1999), Clearing the Air: The Real Story of the War on Air Pollution. Washington D.C.: The Cato InstituteGoogle Scholar
Lueck, Dean (1989), “The Economic Nature of Wildlife Law,” Journal of Legal Studies 18(2): 291–324CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lueck, Dean (2002), “The Extermination and Conservation of the American Bison,” Journal of Legal Studies 31(June): S609–S652CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, M. Scott (2011), “Buffalo Hunt: International Trade and the Virtual Extinction of the North American Bison,” American Economic Review 101 (December 2011): 3162–3195
Farrow, Scott (1995), “Extinction and Market Forces: Two Case StudiesEcological Economics 13: 115–123CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ando, Amy Whritenour (2003), “Do Interest Groups Compete? An Application to Endangered Species,” Public Choice 114(1–2): 137–159CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ando, Amy Whritenour (1999), “Waiting to be Protected under the Endangered Species Act: The Political Economy of Regulatory Delay.” Journal of Law and Economics 42(1): 29–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stroup, Richard L. (1995), “The Endangered Species Act: Making Innocent Species the Enemy, PERC Policy Series
Lueck, Dean and Michael, Jeffrey A. (2003), “Preemptive Habitat Destruction under the Endangered Species Act,” Journal of Law and Economics, 46(1): 27–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, Terry L. and Hill, Peter J. (1983), “Privatizing the Commons: An Improvement?Southern Economic Journal 50(2): 438–450CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×