Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-mlc7c Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-09T08:56:55.858Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

3.2 - Principal–agent theory and nonprofit accountability

from 3 - Economic theories of nonprofit organizations

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 August 2011

Richard Steinberg
Affiliation:
IUPUI
Klaus J. Hopt
Affiliation:
Max-Planck-Institut für ausländisches und internationales Privatrecht, Germany
Thomas Von Hippel
Affiliation:
Max-Planck-Institut für ausländisches und internationales Privatrecht, Germany
Get access

Summary

Introduction

This synthetic literature review briefly summarizes general literature on principal–agent problems, then shows how this literature has been or can be adapted to look at nonprofit governance, accountability, and performance. It concludes with discussions of differences between agency problems in the for-profit and nonprofit sectors and difficulties in developing normative theories of accountability.

Nonprofit organizations should be accountable to their legitimate stakeholders. Of course they should. This proposition seems so obvious that public regulators, watchdog agencies, major funders, and nonprofit managers use it every day, despite the vacuous nature of the statement. What does accountability mean? Who is a legitimate stakeholder? What if stakeholders disagree? The form of the statement suggests substance, lending legitimacy to thin arguments. For example, some implicitly replace “legitimate stakeholders” with a single category, privileging, say, donors. Then they assert something like “donors want fundraising costs to be as low as possible”, so that a high-cost charity lacks accountability. That argument seems sensible until one remembers that donors are not the only class of stakeholders, and that other mission-critical stakeholders (like indigent clients) might be harmed if fundraising costs (and hence revenues) are too low. Another example, familiar to many readers, is a nonprofit university. The list of arguably legitimate stakeholders here is staggeringly long: students, faculty, staff, administrators, donors, alumni, sports fans, private foundations, local tax authorities, for-profit research partners, employers, curators, politicians, advocates, and undoubtedly others.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abzug, R. and Webb, N. J. (1999). “Relationships between Nonprofit and for-Profit Organizations: A Stakeholder Perspective”. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly 28:416–431.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, J. (2006). “Leadership Giving in Charitable Fund-Raising”. Journal of Public Economic Theory 8(1):1–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baber, W. R., Daniel, P. L. and Roberts, A. A. (2002). “Compensation to Managers of Charitable Organizations: An Empirical Study of the Role of Accounting Measures of Program Activities”. The Accounting Review 77(3):679–693.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ballou, J. P. and Weisbrod, B. A. (2003). “Managerial Rewards and the Behavior of For-profit, Governmental and Nonprofit Organizations: Evidence from the Hospital Industry”. Journal of Public Economics 87(9–10):1895–1920.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barbeito, C. L. and Bowman, J. P. (1998). Nonprofit Compensation and Benefits Practices. Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley and Sons.Google Scholar
Ben-Ner, A. (1986). “Nonprofit Organizations: Why Do They Exist in Market Economies?”, in Rose-Ackerman, S. (ed.), The Economics of Nonprofit Institutions: Studies in Structure and Policy. New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 94–113.Google Scholar
Ben-Ner, A. (2002). “The Shifting Boundaries of the Mixed Economy and the Future of the Nonprofit Sector”. Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics 73(1):1–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ben-Ner, A. and Jones, D. (1995). “Employee Participation, Ownership, and Productivity: A Theoretical Framework”. Industrial Relations 34(4):532–554.Google Scholar
Ben-Ner, A., and Putterman, L. (1999). “Values and Institutions in Economic Analysis”, in Ben-Ner, A. and Putterman, L. (eds.), Economics, Values, and Organization. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, pp. 3–72.Google Scholar
Bénabou, R. and Tirole, J. (2003). “Intrinsic and Extrinsic Motivation”. Review of Economic Studies 70:489–520.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berle, A. and Means, G. (1932). The Modern Corporation and Private Property. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Bilodeau, M. (1992). “Voluntary Contributions to United Charities”. Journal of Public Economics 48:119–133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilodeau, M. (2000). Profitable Nonprofit Firms. Working Paper. Indianapolis, IN: IUPUI Dept. of Economics.Google Scholar
Bilodeau, M. and Slivinski, A. (1996). “Volunteering Nonprofit Entrepreneurial Services”. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 31:117–127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilodeau, M. and Slivinski, A. (1997). “Rival Charities”. Journal of Public Economics 66:449–467.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilodeau, M. and Slivinski, A. (1998). “Rational Nonprofit Entrepreneurship”. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 7:551–571.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilodeau, M. and Steinberg, R. (2006). “Donative Nonprofit Organizations”, in Kolm, S.-C., and Mercier-Ythier, J. (eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Giving, Altruism, and Reciprocity, Volume 2. Amsterdam: Elsevier/North-Holland, pp. 1271–1333.Google Scholar
Borjas, G., Frech III, H. E., and Ginsberg, P. B. (1983). “Property Rights and Wages: The Case of Nursing Homes”. Journal of Human Resources 18:231–246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borzaga, C. and Tortia, E. (2006). “Worker Motivations, Job Satisfaction, and Loyalty in Public and Nonprofit Social Services”. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly 35(2):225–248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowman, W. (2006). “Should Donors Care about Overhead Costs? Do they Care?”. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly 35:388–310.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brickley, J. A. and Lawrence Van Horn, R. (2000). Incentives in Nonprofit Organizations: Evidence from Hospitals. Rochester, NY: The Bradley Policy Research Center Financial Research and Policy Working Paper No. FR 00–02.Google Scholar
Brickley, J. A. and Lawrence Van Horn, R. (2002). “Managerial Incentives in Nonprofit Organizations: Evidence from Hospitals”. The Journal of Law and Economics XLV:227–251.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brickley, J. A., Lawrence Van Horn, R., and Wedig, G. (2003). Board Structure and Executive Compensation in Nonprofit Organizations: Evidence from Hospitals. Working Paper available at www.simon.rochester.edu/fac/vanhon/conferencepapers/BVW_Governance.pdf.CrossRef
Brody, E. (2006). “The Legal Framework for Nonprofit Organizations”, in Powell, W. W and Steinberg, R. (eds.), The Nonprofit Sector: A Research Handbook, Second edn., New Haven: Yale University Press, pp. 243–266.Google Scholar
Brown, E. and Slivinski, A. (2006). “Nonprofits and the Market”, in Powell, W. W. and Steinberg, R. (eds.), The Nonprofit Sector: A Research Handbook, Second edn., New Haven: Yale University Press, pp. 140–158.Google Scholar
Buelens, A., Pepermans, R., Flion, I., and Mentens, C. (1999). “Differences in Motivation to Manage Between the Profit and Nonprofit Sector”. In Pepermans, R., Flion, I., and Ardts, J. C. A. (eds.), Managerial Behaviour: Empirical Studies on Management Development and Socialisation. Leuven, Belgium: Acco.Google Scholar
Caers, R., Du Bois, C., Jegers, M., De Gieter, S., Schepers, C., and Pepermans, R. (2006). “Principal-agent Relationships on the Stewardship-agency Axis”. Nonprofit Management and Leadership 17(1):25–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Callen, J. L., Klein, A., and Tinkelman, D. (2003). “Board Composition, Committees, and Organizational Efficiency: The Case of Nonprofits”. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly 32:493–520.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collard, D.. (1975). “Edgeworth's Propositions on Altruism”. The Economic Journal 85:355–360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Core, J. E., Guay, W. R. and Verdi, R. S. (2006). “Agency Problems of Excess Endowment Holdings in Not-for-Profit Firms”. Journal of Accounting and Economics 41(3):307–333.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deci, E. (1971). “Effects of Externally Mediated Rewards on Intrinsic Motivation”. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology XVIII:105–115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Desai, M. A. and Yetman, R. J. (2006). Constraining Managers without Owners: Governance of the Not-for-Profit Enterprise. SSRN working paper 661301, available online.
Dickinson, D. and Villeval, M. C. (2008). “Does Monitoring Decrease Work Effort? The Complementarity between Agency and Crowding-Out Theories”. Games and Economic Behavior 63(1):56–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duggan, M. (2002). “Hospital Market Structure and the Behavior of Not-for-Profit Hospitals: Evidence from Responses to California's Disproportionate Share Model”. Rand Journal of Economics 33(3):433–446.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ehrenberg, R., Cheslock, J., and Epifantseva, J. (2000). Paying Our Presidents: What do Trustees Value?Cambridge, MA: NBER Working Paper 7886.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Erus, B. and Weisbrod, B. A. (2003). “Objective Functions and Compensation Structures in Nonprofit and For-Profit Organizations: Evidence from the ‘Mixed’ Hospital Industry”, in Glaeser, E. L. (ed.) The Governance of Not-For-Profit Institutions. Chicago: University of Chicago and NBER.Google Scholar
Fama, E. F. and Jensen, M. C.. (1983). “Separation of Ownership and Control”. Journal of Law and Economics 26:301–326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feldstein, M. S. (1971). The Rising Cost of Health Care. Washington, DC: Information Resources Press.Google Scholar
Fisman, R. and Hubbard, R. G. (2003). “The role of nonprofit endowments”, in Glaeser, E. (ed.), The Governance of Not-For-Profit Organizations. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 217–234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisman, R. and Hubbard, R. G. (2004). “Precautionary Savings and the Governance of Nonprofit Organizations”. Journal of Public Economics 89(11–12):2231–2243.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Francois, P. (2001). “Employee Care and the Role of Nonprofit Organizations”. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 157:443–464.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, R. (1996). “What Price the High Moral Ground?” Southern Economic Journal 63:1–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, B. S. (1997). Not Just for the Money: An Economic Theory of Personal Motivation. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Frey, B. S. (2000). “Leistung durch Leistungslohn? Grenzen marktlicher Anreizsysteme für das Managerverhalten”, in Frese, E. and Hax, H. (eds.), Das Unternehmen im Spanungsfeld von Planung und Marktkontrolle. Dusseldorf, Germany: Verlagsgruppe Handelsblatt, pp. 67–95.Google Scholar
Frey, B. S. and Oberholzer-Gee, F. (1997). “The Cost of Price Incentives: An Empirical Analysis of Motivation Crowding-out”. American Economic Review LXXXVII:746–755.Google Scholar
Frey, B. S. and Götte, L. (1999). Does Pay Motivate Volunteers? Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, University of Zurich, Working Paper No. 9.
Frey, B. S. and Jegen, R. (2001). “Motivation Crowding Theory: A Survey of Empirical Evidence”. Journal of Economic Surveys 15(5):589–611.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frumkin, P. and Keating, E. (2001). The Price of Doing Good: Executive Compensation in Nonprofit Organizations. Working Paper No. 8, Hauser Center for Nonprofit Organizations, Harvard University.Google Scholar
Frumkin, P. and Kim, M. (2001). “Strategic Positioning and the Financing of Nonprofit Organizations”. Public Administration Review 61(3):266–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gary, S. N. (1999). “Regulating the Management of Charities: Trust Law, Corporate Law, and Tax Law”. University of Hawaii Law Review 21(2):593–697.Google Scholar
Gibbons, R. (1998). “Incentives in Organizations”. Journal of Economic Perspectives 12(4):115–132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glaeser, E. (ed.) (2002). The Governance of Not-for-Profit Organizations. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Glaeser, E. and Shleifer, A. (2001). “Not-for-profit entrepreneurs”. Journal of Public Economics 81:99–116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gneezy, U. and Rustichini, A. (2000). “Pay Enough or Don't Pay at All”. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115:791–810.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grabowski, D. and Hirth, R. (2003). “Competitive Spillovers Across Non-Profit and For-Profit Nursing Homes”. Journal of Health Economics 22(1):1–22.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Greenlee, J. and Gordon, T. (1998). “The Impact of Professional Solicitors on Fund Raising in Charitable Organizations”. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly 27(3):277–299.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hager, M. A., Pollak, T., and Rooney, P. H. (2004). What we Know about Overhead Costs in the Nonprofit Sector. Nonprofit Overhead Cost Project: Facts and Perspectives Brief no. 1. Online at http://nccsdataweb.urban.org/kbfiles/313/Brief%201.pdf.
Hallock, K. F. (2002). “Managerial Pay and Governance in American Nonprofits”. Industrial Relations 41(3):377–406.Google Scholar
Handy, F. (1995). “Reputation as Collateral: An Economic Analysis of the Role of Trustees of Nonprofits”. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly 24(4):293–306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Handy, F. and Katz, E. (1998). “The Wage Differential between Nonprofit Institutions and Corporations: Getting More by Paying Less?”. Journal of Comparative Economics 26:246–261.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansmann, H. (1980). “The Role of Nonprofit Enterprise”. Yale Law Journal 89:835–901.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansmann, H. (1990). “Why Do Universities Have Endowments?” Journal of Legal Studies 29:3–42.CrossRef
Hirth, R. A. (1999). “Consumer Information and Competition Between Nonprofit and For-Profit Nursing Homes”. Journal of Health Economics 18:219–240.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Holmstrøm, B. (1982). “Moral Hazard in Teams”. Bell Journal of Economics 13:324–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holmstrøm, B. and Milgrom, P. (1991). “Multitask Principal-Agent Analyses: Incentive Contracts, Asset Ownership, and Job Design”. The Journal of Law, Economics, and Organizations 7:24–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Irvin, R. A. (2005). “State Regulation of Nonprofit Organizations: Accountability Regardless of Outcome”. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly 34(2):161–178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ito, T. and Domian, D. (1987). “A Musical Note on the Efficiency Wage Hypothesis-Programmings, Wages and Budgets of American Symphony Orchestras”. Economics Letters 25:95–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
James, E. (1983). “How Nonprofits Grow: A Model”. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 2:350–65.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
James, E. (1986). “Comments”, in Rose-Ackerman, S. (ed.), The Economics of Nonprofit Institutions: Studies in Structure and Policy. New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 154–8.Google Scholar
Jobome, G. O. (2006). “Management Pay, Governance and Performance: The Case of Large UK Nonprofits”. Financial Accountability and Management 22(4):331–358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Khanna, J., Posnett, J., and Sandler, T. (1995). “Charity Donations in the UK: New Evidence based on Panel Data”. Journal of Public Economics 56:257–272.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koebel, C. T., Dyck, R., and Steinberg, R. (1998). “Public-Private Partnerships for Affordable Housing: Definitions and Applications in an International Perspective”, in Koebel, C. T. (ed.), Shelter and Society: Theory, Research, and Policy for Nonprofit Housing. Albany: SUNY Press, pp. 39–70.Google Scholar
Krashinsky, M. (1986). “Transactions Costs and a Theory of the Nonprofit Organization”, in Rose-Ackerman, S. (ed.), The Economics of Nonprofit Institutions: Studies in Structure and Policy. New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 114–132.Google Scholar
Krishnan, R., Yetman, M. H., and Yetman, R. J. (2006). “Expense Misreporting in Nonprofit Organizations”. Accounting Review 81(2):399–420.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leete, L. (2001). “Whither the Nonprofit Wage Differential? Estimates from the 1990 Census”. Journal of Labor Economics 19:136–170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leete, L. (2006). “Work in the Nonprofit Sector”, in Powell, W. W. and Steinberg, R. (eds.), The Nonprofit Sector: A Research Handbook. Second Edition. New Haven: Yale University Press, pp. 159–179.Google Scholar
Malani, A. and Choi, A. (2005). Are Non-Profit Firms Simply For-Profits in Disguise? Evidence from Executive Compensation in the Nursing Home Industry. Working Paper available at www.law.uchicago.edu/files/malani/nursing_home.pdf, accessed June 20, 2007.
Milgrom, P. and Roberts, J. (1992). Economics, Organization and Management. London: Prentice Hall.
Miller, J. (2002). “The Board as a Monitor of Organizational Activity”. Nonprofit Management and Leadership 12(4):429–450.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirvis, P. and Hackett, E. (1983). “Work and Work Force Characteristics in the Nonprofit Sector”. Monthly Labor Review 106(4):3–12.Google ScholarPubMed
Mocan, H. N. and Tekin, E. (2003). “An Analysis of Employer-Employee Matched Data of Child Care Workers”. Review of Economics and Statistics 85:38–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nash, J. (1953). “Two-person Cooperative Games.” Econometrica 21:128–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ortmann, A. (1996). “Modern Economic Theory and the Study of Nonprofit Organizations: Why the Twain Shall Meet”. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly 25:470–484.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ortmann, A. and Schlesinger, M. (2003). “Trust, Repute, and the Role of Nonprofit Enterprise”, in Anheier, H. and Ben-Ner, A. (eds.), The Study of Nonprofit Enterprise: Theories and Approaches. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Ortmann, A. and Squire, R. C. (1996). The Internal Organization of Colleges and Universities: A Game-Theoretic Analysis. New Haven, CT: Yale University Program on Nonprofit Organizations Working Paper No. 232.Google Scholar
Oster, S. (1998). “Executive Compensation in the Nonprofit Sector”. Nonprofit Management and Leadership 8(3):207–221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posnett, J. and Sandler, T. (1989). “Demand for Charity Donations in Private Non-Profit Markets: The Case of the U.K.” Journal of Public Economics 40(2):187–200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Preston, A. E. (1988). “The Nonprofit Firm: A Potential Solution to Inherent Market Failures”. Economic Inquiry 26:493–506.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Preston, A. E. (1989). “The Nonprofit Worker in a For-Profit World”. Journal of Labor Economics 7:438–463.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Preyra, C. and Pink, G. (2001). “Balancing Incentives in the Compensation Contracts of Nonprofit Hospital CEOs”. Journal of Health Economics 20(4):509–525.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rawls, J., Ullrich, R., and Nelson, O.. (1975). “A Comparison of Managers Entering or Reentering the Profit and Nonprofit Sectors”. Academy of Mangement Journal 18(3):616–623.Google Scholar
Roomkin, M. and Weisbrod, B. (1999). “Managerial Compensation in Incentives in For-Profit and Nonprofit Hospitals”. Journal of Law, Economics and Organizations 15(3):750–781.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1980). “United Charities: An Economic Analysis”. Public Policy 28:323–348.Google Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1981). “Do Government Grants to Charity Reduce Private Donations?”, in White, M. (ed.), Nonprofit Firms in a Three-Sector Economy. Washingon DC: The Urban Institute.Google Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1982). “Charitable Giving and ‘Excessive’ Fundraising”. Quarterly Journal of Economics 97:195–212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1987). “Ideals versus Dollars: Donors, Charity Managers, and Government Grants”. Journal of Political Economy 95:810–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1996). “Altruism, Nonprofits, and Economic Theory”. Journal of Economic Literature 34:701–728.Google Scholar
Ross, S. (1973). “The Economic Theory of Agency: The Principal's Problem”. American Economic Review 63(2):134–9.Google Scholar
Rubinstein, A. (1982). “Perfect Equilibrium in a Bargaining Model”. Econometrica 50:97–109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ruhm, C. and Borkoski, C. (2003). “Compensation in the Nonprofit Sector”. Journal of Human Resources 38:992–1021.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schlesinger, M. (1985). “Economic Models of Nonprofit Organizations: A Reappraisal of the Property Rights Approach”. Working Paper, JFK School, Harvard University.
Schlesinger, M. and Gray, B. (2006). “Nonprofit Organizations and Health Care: Some Paradoxes of Persistent Scrutiny”, in Powell, W. W. and Steinberg, R. (eds.), The Nonprofit Sector: A Research Handbook, Second Edition. New Haven: Yale University Press, pp. 378–414.Google Scholar
Schwartz, A. (1998). “Incomplete Contracts”, in Newman, P. (ed.), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law. London: MacMillan, pp. 277–282.Google Scholar
Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (1997). “A Survey of Corporate Governance”. Journal of Finance 52:737–783.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Silverman, E. and Skinner, J. (2004). “Medicare Upcoding and Hospital Ownership”. Journal of Health Economics 23(4):369–389.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Simon, J., Dale, H., and Chisolm, L. (2006). “The Federal Tax Treatment of Nonprofit Organizations”, in Powell, W. W. and Steinberg, R. (eds.), The Nonprofit Sector: A Research Handbook, Second Edition. New Haven: Yale University Press, pp. 267–306.Google Scholar
Siqueira, K. and Sandler, T. (2004). “Collective Goods, Common Agency, and Third-Party Intervention”. Bulletin of Economic Research 56(1):1–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slivinski, A. (2002). “Team Incentives and Organizational Forms”. Journal of Public Economic Theory 4(2):185–206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sliwka, D. (2007). “Trust as a Signal of a Social Norm and the Hidden Costs of Incentive Schemes”. American Economic Review 97(3):999–1012.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Speckbacher, G. (2008a). “Nonprofit vs. Corporate Governance: An Economic Approach”. Nonprofit Management and Leadership 18(3):295–320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Speckbacher, G. (2008b). The Use of Incentives in Nonprofit Organizations. Vienna: Institute of Strategic Management and Management Control Working Paper, Vienna University of Economics and Business Administration.Google Scholar
Steinberg, R. (1986a). “The Revealed Objective Functions of Nonprofit Firms”. Rand Journal of Economics 17(4):508–526.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steinberg, R. (1986b). “Should Donors Care about Fund Raising?”, in Rose-Ackerman, S. (ed.), The Economics of Nonprofit Institutions: Studies in Structure and Policy. New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 347–366.Google Scholar
Steinberg, R. (1986c). “Optimal Contracts Need not be Contingent: The Case of Nonprofit Firms”, in Hyman, D. and Parkum, K. (eds.), Models of Health and Human Services in the Nonprofit Sector (conference volume, Association of Voluntary Action Scholars) Oct. 1986, pp. 87–102.
Steinberg, R. (1987). “Nonprofits and the Market”, in Powell, W. W. (ed.), The Nonprofit Sector: A Research Handbook. New Haven: Yale University Press, pp. 118–138.Google Scholar
Steinberg, R. (1990). “Profits and Incentive Compensation in Nonprofit Firms”. Nonprofit Management and Leadership 1(2):137–151.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steinberg, R. (1993). “How Should Antitrust Laws Apply to Nonprofit Organizations?”, in Young, D. R., Hollister, R. M., Hodgkinson, V. A., and Associates (eds.) Governing, Leading, and Managing Nonprofit Organizations. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, Inc., pp. 279–305.Google Scholar
Steinberg, R. (1997). “Competition in Contracted Markets”, in Perri 6 and J. Kendall (eds.) The Contract Culture in Public Services. Brookfield, VT: Ashgate Publishing Co., pp. 161–180.Google Scholar
Steinberg, R. (2006). “Economic Theories of Nonprofit Organizations”, in Powell, W. W. and Steinberg, R. (eds.), The Nonprofit Sector: A Research Handbook, Second Edition. New Haven: Yale University Press, pp. 117–139.Google Scholar
Steinberg, R. and Eckel, C. C. (1994). Tax Policy and the Objectives of Nonprofit Organizations in a Mixed-Sector Duopoly. Indianapolis, IN: Center on Philanthropy at Indiana University Working Paper.Google Scholar
Steinberg, R. and Gray, B. (1993). “The Role of Nonprofit Enterprise in 1992: Hansmann Revisited”. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly 22:297–316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, J. E. (1987). “Principal and Agent”, in Eatwell, J., Milgate, M., and Newman, P. (eds.), The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. American edition, published in multiple volumes in 1989 as The New Palgrave: Allocation, Information, and Markets. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Theuvsen, L. (2004). “Doing Better While Doing Good: Motivational Aspects of Pay-for-Performance Effectiveness in Nonprofit Organizations”. Voluntas: International Journal of Voluntary and Nonprofit Organizations 15(2):117–136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tinkelman, D. (1999). “Factors Affecting the Relation between Donations to Not-for-Profit Organizations and an Efficiency Ratio”. Research in Governmental and Nonprofit Accounting 10:135–161.Google Scholar
Tinkelman, D. and Mankaney, K. (2007). “When is Administrative Efficiency Associated With Charitable Donations?”. Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly 36(1):41–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tirole, J. (1999). “Incomplete Contracts: Where do we Stand?Econometrica 67(4):741–782.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tittmus, R. M. (1970). The Gift Relationship. London, UK: Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Tschirhart, M. and Johnson, J. L. (1998). Infidels at the Gate and Rebels in the Ranks: Protection from Takeovers in Nonprofit Membership Organizations. Paper presented at the Association for Research on Nonprofit Organizations and Voluntary Action. November 5–7.
Tuckman, H. P. and Chang, C. F. (1993). “Accumulating Financial Surpluses in Nonprofit Organizations”, in Young, D. R., Hollister, R. M., Hodgkinson, V. A. and Associates (eds.), Governing, Leading, and Managing Nonprofit Organizations: New Insights from Research and Practice. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, pp. 253–278.Google Scholar
Horn, R. L. and Wedig, G. J. (2001). Governance and Conduct in the Market for Managed Health Insurance. Rochester, NY: Simon School of Business Working Paper No. FR 01–18.Google Scholar
Vesterlund, L. (2003). “The Informational Value of Sequential Fundraising”. Journal of Public Economics 87:627–657.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vesterlund, L. (2006). “Why Do People Give?”, in Powell, W. W. and Steinberg, R. (eds.), The Nonprofit Sector: A Research Handbook, Second Edition. New Haven: Yale University Press, pp. 568–590.Google Scholar
Wedig, G. (1994). “Risk, Leverage, Donations and Dividends-in-Kind: A Theory of Nonprofit Financial Behavior”. International Review of Economics and Finance 3:257–278.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weisbrod, B. (1975). “Toward a Theory of the Voluntary Nonprofit Sector in a Three-Sector Economy”, in Phelps, E. S. (ed.), Altruism, Morality, and Economic Theory. New York: Russell Sage Foundation, pp. 171–195.Google Scholar
Weisbrod, B. (1988). The Nonprofit Economy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Weisbrod, B. and Dominguez, N. (1986). “Demand for Collective Goods in Private Nonprofit Markets: Can Fund Raising Expenditures Help Overcome Free-Rider Behavior?”, Journal of Public Economics 30:83–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weisbrod, B. and Schlesinger, M. (1986). “Public, Private, Nonprofit Ownership and the response to Asymmetric Information: The Case of Nursing Homes”, in Rose-Ackerman, S. (ed.), The Economics of Nonprofit Institutions: Studies in Structure and Policy, pp. 133–151.
Wikipedia contributors. (2006). Principal-agent Problem Wikipedia, The Free Encyclopedia, http://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Principal-agent_problemandoldid=60032757 (accessed June 26, 2006).
Wittmer, D. (1991). “Serving the People or Serving for Pay: Reward Preferences Among Government, Hybrid Sector and Business Managers”. Public Productivity and Management Review 14(4):369–383.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×