Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-dh8gc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-16T15:18:17.944Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

7 - The logic of mechanistic explanations in the social sciences

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 June 2012

Michael Schmid
Affiliation:
Bundeswehr Munich University
Pierre Demeulenaere
Affiliation:
Université de Paris IV
Get access

Summary

Statement of the problem

This chapter draws together some philosophical (Bunge 2004; Little 1998) as well as sociological arguments (Balog 2006; Hedström 2005; Manicas 2006) in favor of an explanatory and realistic research program for the social sciences. As I shall show, such a program presupposes that social scientific explanations are to be couched in the form of microfoundational multi-level explanations of macroscopic states of affair with reference to a substantive theory of individual action.

The logic of scientific explanations

The background to my subject was described by Carl Hempel when he proposed that the social sciences call only those explanations successful that can satisfy a series of “conditions of adequacy” (Hempel 1965: 247ff.). Among these are that the explanandum can be logically deduced from the explanans; moreover, that the explanans should contain at least one deductively necessary nomological proposition or “law”; further, that the propositions of an explanatory argument should be empirically confirmable; and finally, that the propositions of the explanans must be true.

Against this explanatory scheme quite different criticisms were brought forth that increasingly denied the capacity of the social sciences to furnish explanations of the kind that Hempel defended (Bayertz 1980).

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alexander, Peter. 1968. “Rational behaviour and psychoanalytical explanation,” in Care, Norman S. and Landesman, Charles (eds.), Readings in the Theory of Action. Bloomington and London: Indiana University Press, 159–78.Google Scholar
Balog, Andreas. 1989. Rekonstruktion von Handlungen. Opladen: Westdeutscher Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Balog, Andreas. 2001. Neue Entwicklungen in der soziologischen Theorie. Stuttgart: Lucius & Lucius.Google Scholar
Balog, Andreas. 2006. Soziale Phänomene. Identität, Aufbau und Erklärung. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.Google Scholar
Baurmann, Michael. 1996. Der Markt der Tugend. Recht und Moral in der liberalen Gesellschaft. Eine soziologische Untersuchung. Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck).Google Scholar
Bayertz, Kurt. 1980. Wissenschaft als historischer Prozess. Die antipositivistische Wende in der Wissenschaftstheorie. München: Wilhelm Fink Verlag.Google Scholar
Bayertz, Kurt. 2004. Warum überhaupt moralisch sein?München: C.H. Beck Verlag.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1976. The Economic Approach to Human Behavior. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Blau, Peter M. 1977. Inequality and Heterogeneity. A Primitive Theory of Social Structure. New York and London: The Free Press and Collier Macmillan.Google Scholar
Blau, Peter M. 1994. Structural Contexts of Opportunities. Chicago and London: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Boehm, Christopher. 1987. Blood Revenge. The Enactment and Management of Conflict in Montenegro and Other Tribal Societies. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.Google Scholar
Boudon, Raymond. 1977. “Soziale Bedingtheit und Freiheit des Individuums. Das Problem des homo sociologicus,” in Eichner, Klaus and Habermehl, Werner (eds.), Probleme der Erklärung sozialen Verhaltens. Meisenheim: Verlag Anton Hain, 214–76.Google Scholar
Boudon, Raymond. 1979. Widersprüche sozialen Handelns. Neuwied and Darmstadt: Luchterhand Verlag.Google Scholar
Boudon, Raymond. 1986. Theories of Social Change. A Critical Appraisal. Cambridge:Polity Press.Google Scholar
Boudon, Raymond. 2003. Raison, bonnes raisons. Paris: Presses universitaires de France.Google Scholar
Bourdieu, Pierre. 1992. Die verborgenen Mechanismen der Macht, Schriften zu Politik und Kultur 1. Hamburg: VSA-Verlag.Google Scholar
Bromberger, Sylvain. 1966. “Why-questions,” in Colodny, Robert G. (ed.), Mind and Cosmos. Essays in Contemporary Science and Philosophy. University of Pittsburgh Press, 86–111.Google Scholar
Bunge, Mario. 1967. Scientific Research II. The Search for Truth, 3rd rev. edn. Berlin, Heidelberg and New York: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bunge, Mario. 1979. Causality and Modern Science. New York: Dover Publications.Google Scholar
Bunge, Mario. 2004. “How does it work? The search for explanatory mechanisms,” Philosophy of the Social Sciences 34: 182–210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, Colin. 1996. The Myth of Social Action. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cartwright, Nancy. 1989. Natures Capacities and their Measurement. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Coleman, James S. 1986. Individual Interests and Collective Action. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Coleman, James S. 1990. Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, MA and London: The Belknap Press.Google Scholar
Danto, C. Arthur. 1965. Analytical Philosophy of History. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Dray, William. 1957. Laws and Explanation in History. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Elster, Jon. 1979. Ulysses and the Sirens. Studies in Rationality and Irrationality. Cambridge and Paris: Cambridge University Press and Édition de la Maison des Sciences de L'Homme.Google Scholar
Elster, Jon. 2000. Ulysses Unbound. Studies in Rationality, Precommitment, and Constraints. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Esser, Hartmut. 1993. Soziologie. Allgemeine Grundlagen. Frankfurt and New York: Campus Verlag.Google Scholar
Esser, Hartmut. 2000. Soziologie. Spezielle Grundlagen, Band 2: Die Konstruktion der Gesellschaft. Frankfurt and New York: Campus Verlag.Google Scholar
Esser, Hartmut. 2000a. Soziologie. Spezielle Grundlagen, Band 3: Soziales Handeln. Frankfurt and New York: Campus Verlag.Google Scholar
Esser, Hartmut. 2002. “Was könnte man (heute) unter einer ‘Theorie mittlerer Reichweite’ verstehen?” in Mayntz, Renate (ed.), Akteure – Mechanismen – Modelle. Zur Theoriefähigkeit makro-sozialer Analysen. New York and Frankfurt: Campus Verlag, 128–50.Google Scholar
Esser, Hartmut. 2003. “Die Rationalität der Werte. Die Typen des Handelns und das Modell der soziologischen Erklärung,” in Albert, Gert, Bienfait, Agathe, Sigmund, Steffen and Wendt, Claus (eds.), Das Max Weber-Paradigma. Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck, 153–87.Google Scholar
Esser, Hartmut. 2004. Soziologische Anstöße. Frankfurt and New York: Campus Verlag.Google Scholar
Gambetta, Diego. 1993. The Sicilian Mafia. The Business of Private Protection. Cambridge, MA and London: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell. 2002. Trust and Trustworthiness. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell. 2003. Indeterminacy and Society. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hedström, Peter. 2005. Dissecting the Social. On the Principles of Analytical Sociology. Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hedström, Peter, Swedberg, Richard and Udéhn, Lars. 1998. “Popper's situational analysis in contemporary sociology,” Philosophy of the Social Sciences 28: 339–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heelan, Paul A. 1981. “Verbandstheoretische Betrachtung des Erkenntnisfortschritts,” in Radnitzky, Gerard and Andersson, Gunnar (eds.), Voraussetzungen und Grenzen der Wissenschaft. Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck), 339–46.Google Scholar
Hempel, Carl G. 1965. Aspects of Scientific Explanation and other Essays in the Philosophy of Science. New York and London: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Homans, George C. 1974. Human Behavior. Its Elementary Forms, 2nd edn. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. 1979. “Prospect theory. An analysis of decisions under risk,” Econometrica 47: 263–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koertge, Noretta. 1992. “Explanation and its problems,” The British Journal of Philosophy of Science 43: 85–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuran, Timur. 1998. “Social mechanisms of dissonance reduction,” in Hedström, Peter and Swedberg, Richard (eds.), Social Mechanisms. An Analytical Approach to Social Theory. Cambridge University Press, 147–71.Google Scholar
Lakatos, Imre. 1970. “Falsification and the methodology of scientific research programmes,” in Lakatos, Imre and Musgrave, Alan (eds.), Criticism and the Growth of Knowledge. Cambridge University Press, 91–195.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindenberg, Siegwart. 1977. “Individuelle Effekte, kollektive Phänomene und das Problem der Transformation,” in Eichner, Kurt and Habermehl, Werner (eds.), Problem der Erklärung sozialen Verhaltens. Meisenheim: Verlag Anton Hain, 46–84.Google Scholar
Lindenberg, Siegwart. 1985. “Rational choice and sociological theory. New pressures on economics and social science,” Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft 141: 244–55.Google Scholar
Lindenberg, Siegwart. 1992. “The method of decreasing abstraction,” in Coleman, James S. and Fararo, Thomas J. (eds.), Rational Choice Theory. Advocacy and Critique. Newbury Park, London and New Delhi: Sage Publications, 3–20.Google Scholar
Little, Daniel. 1991. Varieties of Social Explanation. An Introduction to the Philosophy of Social Science. Boulder: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Little, Daniel. 1998. Microfoundation, Method, and Causation. New Brunswick and London: Transaction Publishers.Google Scholar
Louch, A.R. 1966. Explanation and Human Action. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Luhmann, Niklas. 1997. Die Gesellschaft der Gesellschaft. Frankfurt: Suhrkamp Verlag.Google Scholar
McIntyre, Lee C. 1996. Laws and Explanations in the Social Sciences. Defending a Science of Human Behavior. Boulder: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Mahoney, James. 2001. “Beyond correlation analysis. Recent innovations in theory and method,” Sociological Forum 16: 575–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manicas, Peter T. 2006. A Realist Philosophy of Social Science. Explanation and Understanding. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayntz, Renate. 2002. “Zur Theoriefähigkeit makro-sozialer Analysen,” in: Mayntz, Renate (ed.), Akteure – Mechanismen – Modelle. Zur Theoriefähigkeit makrosozialer Analysen. Frankfurt and New York: Campus Verlag, 7–43.Google Scholar
Mayntz, Renate. 2004. “Mechanisms in the analysis of social macro-phenomena,” Philosophy of the Social Sciences 34: 237–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Merton, Robert K. 1964. Social Theory and Social Structure. New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Popper, Karl R. 1961. The Poverty of Historicism. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Popper, Karl R. 1966. The Open Society and its Enemies, Vol. ii. The High Tide of Prophecy: Hegel and Marx, 5th edn. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Sawyer, Keith. 2005. Social Emergence. Societies as Complex Systems. Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmid, Michael. 1998. Soziales Handeln und strukturelle Selektion. Beiträge zur Theorie sozialer Systeme. Opladen: Westdeutscher Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmid, Michael. 2004. Rationales Handeln und soziale Prozesse. Beiträge zur soziologischen Theoriebildung. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmid, Michael. 2006. Die Logik mechanismischer Erklärungen. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.Google Scholar
Schmid, Michael. 2009. “Theorien, Modelle und Erklärungen. Einige Grundprobleme des soziologischen Theorienvergleichs,” in Preyer, Gerhard (ed.), Neuer Mensch und kollektive Identität in der Kommunikationsgesellschaft. Karl Otto Hondrich zum Gedächtnis. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften, 323–59.Google Scholar
Schmid, Michael. 2009a. “Das Aggregationsproblem. Versuch einer methodologischen Analyse,” in Hill, Paul, Kalter, Frank, Kopp, Johannes, Kroneberg, Clemens and Schnell, Rainer (eds.), Hartmut Essers Erklärende Soziologie, Kontroversen und Perspektiven. Frankfurt and New York: Campus Verlag, 135–66.Google Scholar
Schweitzer, Urs. 1999. Vertragstheorie. Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck.Google Scholar
Scriven, Michael. 1959. “Truisms as the grounds for historical explanations,” in Gardiner, Patrick (ed.), Theories of History. New York and London: The Free Press and Collier Macmillan, 443–75.Google Scholar
Sened, Itai. 1997. The Political Institution of Private Property. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. 1983. Reason in Human Affairs. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Stegmüller, Wolfgang. 1980. Neue Wege der Wissenschaftsphilosophie. Berlin, Heidelberg and New York: Springer Verlag.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stinchcombe, Arthur L. 1975. “Merton's theory of social structure,” in Coser, Lewis A. (ed.), The Idea of Social Structure. Papers in Honor of Robert K. Merton. New York, Chicago, San Francisco and Atlanta: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 11–33.Google Scholar
Stinchcombe, Arthur L. 1993. “The conditions of fruitfulness of theorizing about mechanisms in the social sciences,” in Sørensen, Aage B. and Spilerman, Seymour (eds.), Social Theory and Social Policy. Essays in Honor of J.S. Coleman. Westport and London: Praeger, 23–41.Google Scholar
Ullmann-Margalit, Edna. 1977. The Emergence of Norms. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Wilson, Catherine. 2004. Moral Animals. Ideals and Constraints in Moral Theory. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Wippler, Reinhard. 1978. “The structural-individualistic approach in Dutch sociology. Towards an explanatory social science,” The Netherland Journal of Sociology 14, 135–55.Google Scholar
Woodward, James. 2003. Making Things Happen. A Theory of Causal Explanation. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Wright, Georg H. von. 1971. Explanation and Understanding. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×