Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-8ctnn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-22T19:12:35.611Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The light on the hill and the ‘right to work’

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 January 2023

Victor Quirk*
Affiliation:
The University of Newcastle, Australia, Australia
*
Victor Quirk, School of Humanities and Social Science and Centre of Full Employment and Equity, The University of Newcastle, Australia, Callaghan, NSW 2308, Australia. Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

In 1945 the Curtin Labor Government declared it had the capacity and responsibility to permanently eliminate the blight of unemployment from the lives of Australians in its White Paper ‘Full Employment in Australia’. This was the culmination of a century of struggle to establish the ‘right to work’, once a key objective of the 19th century labour movement. Deeply resented and long resisted by employer groups, the policy was abandoned in the mid-1970s, without an electoral mandate. Although the Australian Labor Party and union movement urged public vigilance to preserve full employment during 23 years of Liberal rule, after 1978 they quietly dropped the policy as the Australian Labor Party turned increasingly to corporate donors for the money they needed to stay electorally competitive. While few leading lights of today’s Labor movement care to discuss it, it is right that Australians celebrate this bold statement of our right to work, and the 30 years of full employment it heralded.

Type
Symposium: The White Paper and Full Employment
Copyright
© The Author(s) 2018

Introduction

On 30 May 1945, the Curtin government released its White Paper ‘Full Employment in Australia’ formally declaring its intention to permanently keep unemployment below 2% after the Second World War. Although the establishment of full employment was arguably the Australian Labor movement’s greatest strategic achievement of the 20th century, the anniversary passes each year without acknowledgement by either the Australian Labor Party (ALP) or ACTU. While recent Labor leaders have been keen to associate themselves with the Curtin and Chifley governments at an abstract level, embracing the lofty symbolism of the ‘light on the hill’ rhetoric (e.g. Reference GillardGillard, 2010), they never mention the key strategic issue Labor then pursued for ‘the betterment of mankind’ – the elimination of all but frictional unemployment (Reference ChifleyChifley, 1949).

For 32 years (1942–1974), successive Labor and Liberal governments used public sector employment and expenditure to supplement and fuel private sector demand for labour, to deliberately keep the rate of unemployment below 2%. This simple fact has enormous difficulty gaining traction in the minds of scholars who write about the period. When Labor MP Reference LeighAndrew Leigh (2014) searched for the explanation as to why workers and unions fared so well in the 30 years after the war, compared with their declining fortunes since the mid-1970s, the policy of keeping unemployment below 2% was not even acknowledged as a possible explanation. When Troy Branston wrote of Labor’s ongoing march toward the ‘light on the hill’, the policy that Chifley emphasised as crucial to leading us there was nowhere mentioned, not even in numerous references to ‘Post War Reconstruction’ or the ALP federal election campaigns between 1943 and 1972, in which Labor’s commitment to maintaining full employment was centre stage (Reference BramstonBramston, 2011; Reference ChifleyChifley, 1949).

Although central to Chifley’s thinking, there is scant recognition by today’s Labor leaders that in order for working people to have richer and freer lives, they need to have more power in their workplaces, which is determined by the prevailing level of labour under-utilisation, and how the unemployed are treated. The more fearful workers are of losing their jobs and incurring a protracted and painful episode of unemployment, the greater the capacity of employers to impose their will and demand more of them. Conversely, in times of labour scarcity, when jobs are plentiful, workers are empowered to seek better terms and conditions of employment.Footnote 1 This reality has been understood by policymakers for centuries, yet since workers won the right to vote, it is rarely publicly acknowledged for strategic reasons. Nevertheless, in the heat of debates over full employment proposals, as occurred in Britain during the WWII, the role of unemployment is sometimes plainly stated, as in this article from The Times (1943: 5):

Unemployment is not a mere accidental blemish in a private enterprise economy. On the contrary, it is part of the essential mechanism of the system, and has a definite function to fulfil. The first function of unemployment (which has always existed in open or disguised form) is that it maintains the authority of master over man. The master has normally been in a position to say: ‘If you do not want the job, there are plenty of others who do’. When the man can say: ‘If you do not want to employ me, there are plenty of others who will’, the situation is radically altered.

Although unemployment is typically treated as only a technical macroeconomic problem, as Reference KaleckiMichal Kalecki (1943) observed during the full employment debate in wartime Britain, it is at heart about power, that is, a political question:

although most economists are now agreed that full employment may be achieved by government spending, this was by no means the case even in the recent past. Among the opposers of this doctrine there were (and still are) prominent so-called ‘economic experts’ closely connected with banking and industry. This suggests that there is a political background in the opposition to the full employment doctrine, even though the arguments advanced are economic. That is not to say that people who advance them do not believe in their economics, poor though this is. But obstinate ignorance is usually a manifestation of underlying political motives.

So in remembering the 1945 White Paper, Labor’s pledge to industrially and socially empower workers with full employment, we are confronted with the contrast with today’s ALP. How is it that full employment was so central to Labor’s mission back then, but not now? How did such a contentious policy survive changes of government over 30 years? What ended it, and why did the Labor party not restore the policy when in office? This discussion seeks to address these issues, drawing on research into the history of opposition to full employment aimed at informing a campaign for its restoration.Footnote 2

Why was full employment established?

John Curtin and his cabinet were sufficiently preoccupied with defending the country from immanent invasion, and knew big business would mobilise vehement opposition to full employment, so why did they pursue this policy in the Second World War? Two key reasons stand out. First, establishing permanent full employment was an objective of the labour movement since the mid-19th century known as the ‘right to work’ (RTW). Second, and more pragmatically, faced with the challenge of uniting and mobilising the Australian people for total war, a credible promise of post-war full employment addressed the divisive bitter legacies of the interwar years.

The Right to Work

The Right to Work was once a key demand of the labour movement, alongside the right to collectively bargain over wages and conditions, the right to parliamentary representation and the 8-hour day. It held that governments were responsible for ensuring people had work, by offering decent jobs to those the private sector chose not to employ.Footnote 3 While the other labour movement goals were gradually conceded to workers by the early 20th century, the RTW was not (Reference BrownBrown, 1971; Reference BurnettBurnett, 1994; Reference QuirkQuirk, 2008).Footnote 4

It arose from long-standing European traditions of undertaking public works in recessions, and was coined as a term in 1830s France in the writing of Luis Blanc and others (Reference BlancBlanc, 1848). It was established in Paris in February 1848, and its withdrawal 4 months later provoked 3 days of hand-to-hand street fighting in which 6000 workers lost their lives. The episode prompted the accusation by Alexis De Tocqueville that full employment was a slippery slope to communism (Reference McKayMcKay, 1965; Reference QuirkQuirk, 2007; Reference SeniorSenior, 1973: 52–53).

The Paris experiment was sufficiently well known among British Parliamentarians in 1886, as to be widely cited as a good reason not to proceed with long called-for public works, after 20,000 unemployed rioted in Trafalgar Square demanding work. Most speakers in the debate warned of the dire consequences of conceding a ‘right to work’ (Reference QuirkQuirk, 2008). The Right to Work was a key policy objective of the first three ‘Independent Labor Party’ members elected to the House of Commons in 1893. James Keir-Hardie, the most prominent advocate of the policy, went on to introduce a ‘Right to Work Bill’ from opposition in 1907.Footnote 5 Liberal government politicians came under such intense lobbying from their unemployed constituents that half crossed the floor to support its second reading, before the bill was finally rejected. Labor leader Ramsay Macdonald dropped the policy from Labor’s platform in exchange for the establishment of parliamentary salaries by the Liberal Government, in 1911, in the wake of the Osbourne caseFootnote 6 (Reference BrownBrown, 1971; Reference McLeanMcLean, 1975; Reference QuirkQuirk, 2008).

A more comprehensive ‘Right to Work’ system than that of Keir-Hardie was proposed for Queensland by its Premier Ted Theodore in his impressive Unemployed Workers Bill of 1919, which provoked unprecedented employer opposition. Entailing large-scale infrastructure projects, regulation of local government works, unemployment insurance and other measures, it reflected a clear grasp of the economic role of the public sector in maintaining high stable private sector demand for labour. I argue elsewhere (Reference QuirkQuirk, 2009) that a 4-year financial blockade (1920–1924) that was placed on Queensland by the London financial houses was more likely provoked by the Unemployed Workers Bill than by the Pastoral Lease act typically cited by prominent historians as the cause (Reference FitzgeraldFitzgerald, 1994; Reference SchedvinSchedvin, 1971: 40; Reference TheodoreTheodore, 1919, Reference Theodore1924).

Big business hostility to Theodore when he later became Australia’s Treasurer during the 1930s Depression reflected a fear that he would reflate the economy before the depression had achieved its purpose of lowering the cost of production in Australia as they intended it should. He was blocked at every turn by foreign and domestic financiers and a hostile Senate, his plans vilified in the press, but two close observers of his struggle, caucus colleagues Curtin and Chifley, went on to promote and apply much of what he (and later Keynes) argued for, in the course of institutionalising full employment during the Second World War (Reference AhamedAhamed, 2009; Reference BlackBlack, 2001; Reference DenningDenning, 1982; Reference FitzgeraldFitzgerald, 1994; Reference KeynesKeynes, 1936; Reference QuirkQuirk, 2009, Reference Quirk2010; Reference TheodoreTheodore, 1932).

Shoring up national support for the war

The Second World War created a momentum for full employment that proved too much for its opponents to resist. Conservative expenditure on war preparations from 1939 to 1941 demonstrated that Commonwealth spending could significantly bring down unemployment, just as Theodore had earlier argued (Reference FitzgeraldFitzgerald, 1994; Reference FordeForde, 1971). With the mobilisation for total war in early 1942, following Japanese raids on Pearl Harbour and Darwin, unemployment rapidly fell below 2%. This prompted public questioning as to how this could be, given the bitter memories many had of the Depression, when no money could be found to employ people, including war veterans, leaving their families destitute and many evicted from their homes. How was it that money was suddenly in abundant supply, sufficient to employ everybody, just because there was another war to fight? They recalled the opposition of the banks, big business and conservative politicians to Theodore’s reflation plans, and their assertions that he would cause a Weimar-style hyper-inflation. How then could Australia be operating with such a low level of unemployment?

More pointed scepticism was directed at recruitment propaganda that echoed the promises made during the previous war, that soldiers would return to a land fit for heroes. The First World War veterans returned to chronic high unemployment, negligible social security and industrial violence, where they were set upon by anti-union ‘white army’ groups in which former officers played prominent roles (Reference CathcartCathcart, 1988; Reference EvattEvatt, 1942; Reference MooreMoore, 1989).

The need to shore up national unity and commitment to the war effort, and their long-standing advocacy of the RTW, led the Curtin government to use the promise of post-war full employment to give Australian workers a future worth fighting for. To dispel doubts that they meant to carry out what they promised, in November 1942 the Curtin Government held Australia’s first constitutional convention since the federation of the nation in 1901, to seek a 6-year post-war extension of the economic controls granted under the constitution during war-time hostilities, to preserve full employment during demobilisation (Reference CurtinCurtin, 1942). In declaring his government’s commitment to post-war full employment, Curtin promised that the shameful neglect of the previous war’s veterans would not be repeated. Attorney General Reference EvattDr Evatt (1942) led the convention, declaring:

With the lesson that it took a war to teach us, we can no longer assert that the problem of unemployment is insoluble, that men are out of work only because they are unfit for work or unwilling to work, that financial policy prevents their employment, that the task of maintaining full employment is not a responsibility of the national Government.

Full employment was also a stated post-war goal of other allied nations, including Britain and the USA, although business interests managed to derail the US 1945 Full Employment Bill (Reference TrumanTruman, 1952).Footnote 7 It was consistent with the goal of achieving freedom from want, one of ‘four freedoms’ that President F.D. Roosevelt, pledged would guide the post-war order (Reference EvattEvatt, 1942).Footnote 8 Australia, usually represented by H.V. Evatt, was at the forefront of advocating global adoption of full employment at various international conferences during and after the war (Reference McIntyreMcIntyre, 2015).

For his part, Robert Menzies opposed the policy on the philosophical grounds that the economic security of full employment would stifle progress:

You cannot have progress and absolute security at the same time. That, perhaps, puts into one sentence the entire difference between the political philosophy of this Government and my own…to say that the taking of risks is now an old-fashioned idea, and that the one thing that matters is absolute security, is…a denial of the whole genius of our people throughout their history. (Reference MenziesMenzies, 1943: 248)

Reference Griffen-FoleyGriffen-Foley (2003) attributes Menzies’ political resurrection (after being overthrown as United Australia Party leader in 1941) and ascent to the leadership of the new Liberal Party in 1945, to his success in defeating the 1944 post-war powers referendum. Curtin held the referendum after the conservative states reneged on undertakings given at the 1942 convention to temporarily cede the powers to the Commonwealth. Nevertheless, the government published its White Paper in May 1945, declaring itself irrevocably committed to full employment.

‘Full Employment in Australia’: The 1945 White Paper

The document begins by declaring the Right to Work, resolving that it will henceforth be the responsibility of the Commonwealth government to ensure decent work is available to all who want it. Then follows an explanation of how this will be achieved and how foreseeable problems will be addressed. It explained unemployment as a deficiency in aggregate demand, noting the characteristics of the sectors of the economy that contribute to that demand: Net foreign expenditure on Australian output is inherently unstable and ultimately beyond the capacity of government to control. Private capital expenditure occurs when investors anticipate it is warranted by a demand for more output, and stops when demand drops, so that investors pro-cyclically amplify shifts they detect in aggregate demand. Because public expenditure on current services and public capital expenditure can be fairly precisely controlled, these would be varied to stimulate private sector consumption and investment as required in downturns, to maintain high and stable demand. This was a reversal of the previous orthodoxy of cutting public expenditure in economic downturns. A high stable level of aggregate demand would thus be maintained sufficient to employ the available factors of production, especially labour.

Work would not be created for its own sake, but to meet a pressing need in the community and the economy for improved public services and infrastructure. Modernising public infrastructure would boost productivity, while a proactive public employment service would anticipate and address skill shortages and facilitate labour mobility.

The White Paper also acknowledged the limits to which aggregate expenditure could increase output. Once the economy was operating at full employment, further expenditure would only lead to increased prices. Inflation control thus required that any additional (private or public) spending at full employment was offset by expenditure cuts elsewhere.

The paper also set out special measures to deal with the immediate post-war situation where around 1 million workers would have to be reintegrated into the civilian economy from the armed services and various war-related industries. Housing construction was a key priority for the immediate post-war, while industry assistance was to be provided for manufacturing and agricultural sectors in retooling for the civilian economy. Because of the failure of the 1944 post-war powers referendum, the paper highlighted the need for cooperation between the Commonwealth and States (Commonwealth of Australia (CoA), 1945).

The institutionalisation of full employment

Whereas some of the targets for housing construction in the first few years were not met, largely due to materials shortages, the plan generally succeeded. Aggregate demand was augmented through public sector employment and expenditure, while keeping a large portfolio of fully blueprinted and costed public works projects on standby should there be a slump in the economy (The Canberra Times, 1949: 4; Reference CoombsCoombs, 1958).

Following the death of Curtin in 1945, Chifley’s government won a convincing victory at the 1946 election with the maintenance of full employment its key policy, against the Coalition’s offer of a 20% tax cut (The Canberra Times, 1946). The electoral backlash for opposing full employment forced the Liberals to commit to supporting it in 1947, prompting a debate in 1949 as to whether they intended to redefine the meaning of ‘full employment’ to between 6% and 8% unemployment, which they strenuously denied (The Argus, 1949a: 6). Nationally, fewer than 2000 people were unemployed out of a population of 8.5 million in the final year of the Chifley government, equivalent to about 7000 today. Establishment hostility to full employment was clearly evident, however, as reflected in this Sydney Morning Herald (SMH, 1949) editorial:

The plain truth is that in a labour market which favours the seller of services, workers have become less inclined to exert themselves. They have lost fear of unemployment, and, generally speaking, no other adequate stimulus to steady, conscientious effort has replaced that economic spur.

At his Federal election campaign launch in December that year, Reference ChifleyChifley (1949) warned the public of the hostility of business interests to full employment, and of the likelihood that a Menzies government would abandon the policy:

You cannot have discipline and efficiency — so critics say — unless you have a degree of unemployment. Not too much unemployment of course — that would be bad for business. Just a nice six or eight per cent of unemployment, just a quarter million or so out of work to keep the fear of the sack in the hearts of all the rest.

Full employment was so popular that it was only by neutralising the issue, by insisting a Liberal government would keep unemployment below 2%, using public sector job creation if need be, that Menzies’s pledge to end petrol rationing won him office in 1949.

But given the evident hostility it evoked among the Liberal Party’s business patrons, why was the full employment policy not abandoned during the historic 23 years of continuous Liberal rule?

How full employment survived under Menzies

By 1949, Chifley had succeeded in habituating the public to low unemployment. Weekly figures of 1000 or 2000 people unemployed rated little more than a paragraph in the metropolitan papers, not even on the front page (e.g. The Argus, 1949b). Their equivalent today would be front page headlines. Reference SchmidtSchmidt (1984) observed that electorates will punish governments harshly for even minute increases in the UE rate once they become accustomed to low unemployment over a prolonged period of time. Throughout Menzies’s record 16-year term in office, even the lightest pruning of public expenditure prompted opportunistic cries of ‘they’re abandoning full employment!’ from the Labor opposition and the unions, mindful of the damage this invariably inflicted on the government’s electoral support (e.g. The Argus, 1951; The Canberra Times, 1951). Ministers were regularly forced to publicly re-pledge their commitment to full employment, reinforcing public perceptions that the level of unemployment was a policy choice. Even in 1951, when facing a 20% inflation rate caused by the Korean War wool boom, the Liberal-Country coalition government successfully managed the issue with unemployment only briefly rising to 3%, yet even then it faced a near-fatal collapse of electoral support (Reference BarberBarber, 2011).Footnote 9

By the late 1960s, global business interests were growing restless (Reference TsokhasTsokhas, 1984), particularly with the unwillingness of governments to use unemployment to curb worker power. A 1970 report (‘Inflation the present problem’) produced by a new economic policy group within the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) discussed the ‘profit squeeze’ occurring in countries where sustained low unemployment had strengthened the bargaining capacity of workers. In competitive markets where increased labour costs were difficult to pass on to customers, full employment suppressed profits. Where the costs could be passed on, it produced inflation. The study also acknowledged the electoral risk to any government seeking to increase unemployment as a solution once the public was habituated to it being kept low (Reference KorpiKorpi, 1991, Reference Korpi2002):

People’s reaction to going bankrupt or being thrown out of a job may have been different in the 1930s when it could be thought that this was the result of a natural disaster. But today a serious recession would be clearly recognised to be the result of a deliberate policy being followed by the government. (OECD, 1970: 37)

It suggested the risk could be mitigated if an exogenous shock to the world economy were to occur, allowing governments to collectively push up unemployment while claiming it was the result of the shock and beyond their control (OECD, 1970). For Walter Reference KorpiKorpi (1991):

This policy statement, published well before the oil crisis, comes surprisingly close to recommending unemployment as a cure to inflation and the profit squeeze. (p. 335)

Within the OECD staff, [Gosta] Rehn argued against the formulations in this document, maintaining that it would be widely interpreted as an official recommendation for increasing levels of unemployment. His objections were overruled, and internationally the policy document came to be interpreted in the way Rehn had feared. (Reference KorpiKorpi, 2002: 20)

In April 1971, BHP Chairman Sir Colin Syme publicly called for more unemployment and for business to back the government in administering the ‘tough medicine’ that the workforce needed (Reference MaidenMaiden, 1971). When Treasury officials attempted to induce a recession a few months later, having understated the negative impact of proposed budget cuts to Liberal PM William McMahon, ACTU President Hawke accused:

It’s clearly an attempt to do something about prices which may be seen as a response to a suggestion of BHP’s Sir Colin Syme for the government to create a pool of unemployed. (The Age, 1971: 3)

McMahon strenuously denied the charge but his Industrial Relations Minister (Phillip Lynch), who went on to become Malcolm Fraser’s first Treasurer, was evidently more willing to associate himself with Sir Colin’s views and Treasury’s mindset. Couching his message in terms of an ultimatum to unions to curb their demands or face abandonment of full employment, he observed:

A prolonged period of employment security strongly enhances the bargaining power of unions and weakens the resistance of employers to unreasonable wage demands. In the past few years, trade union leaders have come to realise that they are in a strong position that they can dictate rather than negotiate terms and conditions of employment to employers. (Reference LynchLynch, 1972, quoted in Reference WindschuttleWindschuttle, 1979: 258–259)

These and similar comments expressed during the post war period, and prior to the OPEC oil shock, indicate the resentment of business leaders and their political advocates for the power full employment bestowed on workers. Most significantly, they also demonstrate an acceptance across the political spectrum at that time that governments can control the level of unemployment (Reference MitchellMitchell, 1998; Reference Mitchell and FaziMitchell and Fazi, 2017; Reference Mitchell and MuyskenMitchell and Muysken, 2008; Reference QuirkQuirk, 2004).

Abandonment of full employment

The abandonment of full employment in Australia (1974–1975) is inextricably bound with the story of the Whitlam government: its poisonous relationship with the Federal bureaucracy it inherited after 23 years of Liberal-Country Party rule, the inflation surge bequeathed to them by the outgoing McMahon government, the Organisation of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) oil shock, the wage-price spiral this produced and the controversy surrounding the timing of Whitlam’s removal from office.

Treasury officials were acting to induce a recession long before the OPEC shock, and the 1970s wage-price spiral, against the expressed wishes of governments they were obliged to serve. McMahon, himself a former Treasurer, was given ‘unanimous’ advice by Treasury that the 1971 budget would not adversely affect employment. He then heard from former colleagues of dissenting views within the Treasury, and, realising he’d been misled, spent heavily to avoid a recession and stop as much unemployment appearing as he could prior to the December 1972 election (Reference Weller and CuttWeller and Cutt, 1976: 24; Reference WhitlamWhitlam, 1985: 205). This was the initial cause of the inflation the Whitlam Government immediately faced on winning power. It was soon exacerbated by the quadrupling of the world price of oil by the OPEC a few months later.Footnote 10 Militant unions, free of any fear of losing their jobs, then aggressively sought nominal wage increases to preserve the real value of their incomes, which employers passed on as higher prices, creating a price-wage spiral. A 1973 referendum to give the government control over wages and prices was lost in the face of opposition by both business and the ACTU under Bob Hawke (Reference WhitlamWhitlam, 1985).

The Treasury policy to abandon full employment was implemented (on its second attempt) by Treasury officials acting without informing the Whitlam government during 1974, although it took another year for the unemployment they induced to push well over the 30-year norm of 2%. Whitlam admits he approved a credit squeeze in September 1973 in the face of a sharp increase in inflation, but claims Treasury understated the depth and duration of its contraction, denying it would cause unemployment to rise, and withheld the data that would have indicated otherwise, just as they did with McMahon (Reference WhitlamWhitlam, 1985: 204–205). In May 1974, during the double dissolution election campaign, Russel Prowse, Assistant General Manager of the Bank of New South Wales told the Nine Television Network’s Federal File programme, that the country ‘faced its tightest credit squeeze since the early 1960s’, which would require a release of about AUD500 million from Statutory Reserve Deposits to avoid a serious recession. Whitlam immediately summoned the heads of Treasury and the Reserve Bank to Kirribilli House to demand an explanation. Both emphatically denied Prouse’s claim (The Age, 1974: 1; Reference WhitlamWhitlam, 1985).

The question of abandoning full employment was openly discussed by key figures during this period. For example, a declassified US embassy cable on a briefing provided by Bob Hawke (then both ACTU and ALP President) to the US ambassador Reference GreenMarshal Green (1974a) on 5 July 1974, reveals Hawke’s analysis of the situation:

On question of labor [sic] unrest and ‘fear of unemployment’ Hawke pointed out that full employment was long time national commitment and was not unique goal of labor movement. While people expected low unemployment rate and had come to expect it ever since wartime economic expansion, this was much more dangerous area for Whitlam government than any other. Government planners had for some time unwisely, in his opinion, figured on unemployment as instrument in fight against inflation. He gave estimate that new election would take place within twelve months if rate of inflation continued to increase and if unemployment passed or closely approached two percent.

On 31 July Hawke consulted with Acting Secretary Ingersoll:

On Australian internal situation, Hawke opposed anti-inflationary proposals emanating from Treasury and voiced opinion that, if accepted, they could raise unemployment to between two and three percent which Hawke felt might result in new elections within a year. … In view of Australian history of virtual full employment for last 34 years, Hawke felt that unemployment rate of even two or three percent could prove politically disastrous. (Reference MartensMartens, 1974)

Another despatch reported that Hawke:

rejects idea that unemployment rate, or measures which raise it, are appropriate inflation control instruments, using strong language on July 20 to condemn those in ‘ivory towers’ and in the Treasury who regarded people as ‘pawns on an economic chessboard’. (Harrop, 1974)

After winning their second election in 18 months, the Whitlam cabinet started working on the August 1974 budget, for which the Treasury recommended a ‘…a hard line deflationary package of reduced expenditure and increased taxes across the board’. Treasurer Frank Crean presented the Treasury line to cabinet, arguing for full employment to be temporarily abandoned to curb union wage demands in the face of an inflation emergency (Cabinet Submission 1243, 1974, National Archives of Australia (NAA), 2004)Footnote 11 Crean met with strong opposition from his cabinet colleagues, both on the grounds of Labor principle, and in consideration for the electoral consequences. In any event, Treasury took the decision out of the Cabinet’s hands.

Treasury’s contempt for the right of a democratically elected government to determine the course of economic policy soon revealed itself in a dramatic fashion. According to then Minister for Urban and Regional Development, Tom Uren, Dr Michael Keating, then head of his Ministry’s Economic department, had privately advised him that Treasury was planning a AUD1300 million surplus, which would push unemployment higher than it had been in the previous 30 years. On the morning Treasury presented its budget recommendations to Cabinet, Uren left the cabinet room on the pretext of a call of nature, took the papers to his office downstairs, had staff copy them and asked Keating to brief him on their contents that lunchtime. Although the papers claimed a AUD300 million surplus, Keating found an additional AUD1000 million in net expenditure cuts hidden in the detail. Reference UrenUren (1994: 233–234) then briefed Cairns, and the Cabinet was then informed of the Treasury’s attempted deception.

‘Cabinet rejected most of the Treasury package and Caucus, unable to stomach a policy deliberately designed to create unemployment, threatened to reject most of what was left’ (Reference FreudenbergFreudenberg, 1977: 304). Cabinet ordered Treasury to produce alternative policy options including recommendations aimed at reducing rather than increasing unemployment. In an extraordinary demonstration of its mindset, the Treasury refused and withdrew from most of the process of producing and presenting the budget, which the Cabinet largely developed by itself, aiming at a domestic surplus of AUD23 million. Within weeks, the government received confirmation of the depth of the credit squeeze and tried to reverse it in a November mini-budget, but it was too late to stop unemployment from rising to nearly 5% in the following year (Reference WhitlamWhitlam, 1985: 204–207; Reference WhitwellWhitwell, 1986: 214–216).

Hawke’s prediction of an election within a year is interesting, since having won the May 1974 election, Whitlam’s government was not obliged to face the electorate again until mid-1977. Given that time frame, while Cairns, Cameron and others were staunchly opposed to any departure from full employment, others such as Hayden (who became Treasurer in mid-1975) may have thought they had time to allow the Treasury-induced unemployment to remain high for a couple of years to elicit greater cooperation from the unions, and still bring it down well before the next election. What transpired is that during 1975, two conservative state governments appointed non-Labor people to fill two casual Senate vacancies won by the ALP at previous elections. This gave the Liberal-Country party the ability to defer Senate consideration of budget bills (it was unconstitutional to reject them) and thus deny the Whitlam government the funds to govern. But given these moves occurred during 1975, it is hard to understand the accuracy with which some key political figures, like Hawke, predicted the course of events a year earlier.

In November 1974, for example, Governor General Sir John Kerr privately conferred with Rupert Murdoch in the presence of several Murdoch journalists, on the options available to himself, the government and the opposition, should the latter move to block supply in the Senate the following year (Reference MenadueMenadue, 1999: 155). Murdoch provided US Ambassador Marshal Green (1974b) with a wide-ranging assessment of the political situation on 16 November 1974 where he noted:

Australian elections are likely to take place in about one year, sparked by refusal of appropriations in the Senate. All signs point to a Liberal-Country victory, since the economy is in disturbingly bad condition and will probably not improve much of that time…

Murdoch also declared a preference for Hawke as a future ALP leader over Deputy PM Cairns who he considered ‘a puzzling and disturbing figure’ (Green, 1974b). Cairns’s political demise in mid-1975, under siege by the Murdoch press over accusations of ministerial impropriety that he went to his grave denying, made way for Bill Hayden to take over as Treasurer. Hayden’s mildly contractionary 1975 budget ensured unemployment would be slow to fall from the historic high it had by then reached (around 5%). Malcolm Fraser seized his opportunity to block supply, and on 11 November, Sir John Kerr ensured the full electoral backlash for the loss of full employment was visited upon the Whitlam government.

The restoration of chronic labour underutilisation

In the campaign for the 1975 election, both major parties pledged to restore full employment. Fraser and his employment spokesperson (Tony Street) berated Labor for the rise in unemployment, claiming that while they would rely more on the private sector than would Labor, they would also use a public sector job creation programme operated through the states, to restore full employment and prosperity (SMH, 1975: 13). Following his 12 December landslide win, Fraser immediately announced the coalition would ‘fight inflation first’, and only bring down unemployment after inflation was subdued (Reference HughesHughes, 1980). He immediately announced a crackdown on ‘welfare cheats’ (Reference WindschuttleWindschuttle, 1979). At the February 1976 opening of Parliament, Reference KerrKerr’s (1976) opening address declared the new government’s ‘long term objective is to prevent the growth of centralized bureaucratic government domination in Australia’ and that ‘there will be a major redirection of resources away from government toward individuals and private industry’ (p. 6). A large corporate-funded ‘economic education’ campaign was imported from the USA in 1976, extolling the virtues of the free market, the social necessity for businesses to make healthy profits and condemning excessive government involvement in the economy. Millions were spent each year thereafter to sell the message through radio and television advertising, school text books, workplace talks, and on growing and establishing right-wing think tanks (Reference BederBeder, 2005, Reference Beder2006; Reference CareyCarey, 1995).

Fraser embraced a range of agenda management techniques to contain the political damage of pushing up unemployment, as it continued to rise throughout his term in office, blaming Whitlam, the unions and (reprehensibly) the unemployed themselves (Reference HardingHarding, 1985; Reference HughesHughes, 1980). Research undertaken by Professor Reference ArndtHeinz Arndt (1973) on his return from 6 months with the OECD group that produced ‘Inflation the Present Problem’ had suggested that people would be more tolerant of higher unemployment if they believed it was substantially voluntary. Consequently, Fraser and the media barons blamed the work-shy attitudes of the unemployed for their plight (Reference WindschuttleWindschuttle, 1979).

During this period the cash-strapped ALP opposition morphed into a ‘free market’ party under the leadership of Bill Hayden, who succeeded Whitlam in 1977. Campaign costs had risen sharply throughout the 1970s, leaving Labor on the verge of insolvency after fighting four federal campaigns in 5 years (Reference WhitlamWhitlam, 1985). Labor’s survival rested on its ability to make itself more palatable to corporate donors, and so its commitment to the Right to Work was quietly dropped. Hawke entered parliament at the 1980 election and deposed Hayden for the Labour leadership on the day Fraser announced the 1983 election. With unemployment at 10.6%, Hawke promised to create 500,000 jobs: ‘but he did not promise restoration of full employment in his first term; to do so would be dishonest, he said’ (Reference GrattanGrattan, 1983: 1).

Hawke overcame his 1974 aversion to using people as ‘pawns on an economic chessboard’, in introducing the activity test in 1988 that implied people’s willingness to work could be tested without offering them work (Reference CassCass, 1988; Reference HoweHowe, 1991). His Treasurer then presided over a policy-induced recession (1990–1992), pushing the unemployment rate up to 11% (Reference TooheyToohey, 1994),Footnote 12 arguing publicly and privately it was ‘a recession we had to have’.Footnote 13 The labour market rapidly casualised with the intensified competition for jobs, while the fragmentation of permanent full-time work appeared in the persons-based labour-force framework as new jobs being created.

As a million people became unemployed, Commonwealth Employment Service (CES) staff saw little justice in punishing them for breaching their ‘activity agreements’ (Australian National Audit Office (ANAO), 1991), so a public relations firm was engaged to re-engineer its organisational culture. The organisational manual was rigidly codified, and staff were threatened with prosecution for criminal fraud for deviation from guidelines. This inflexibility impaired their effectiveness as job brokers, reflected in a fall in the CES share of advertised vacancies from 41% in 1988 to 19% in 1992 (Committee on Employment Opportunities (CEO), 1993). Keating (and his Minister Peter Baldwin) then commissioned McKinsey and Co. bank downsizing consultant Paul Twomey to design a marketised employment services system, of which ‘contracted case management’ introduced with the 1994 White Paper ‘Working Nation’ was the first implementation stage (Reference CampbellCampbell, 1994; Reference Wearing, Smyth, Cass and SmythWearing and Smyth, 1998; Reference Jose, Quirk and CarlsonJose and Quirk, 2002; Reference QuirkQuirk, 2002; Reference TwomeyTwomey, 1994). This approach linked the employment security of employment service staff to their willingness to cut the incomes of the unemployed. The Howard Government’s Job Network that replaced the CES in 1998 was merely the final implementation stage of Labor’s policy, despite Labour’s confected opposition at the time (Reference Jose, Quirk and CarlsonJose and Quirk, 2002; Reference QuirkQuirk, 2002). The system’s effectiveness was reflected in the breaching-induced poverty epidemic reported by welfare agencies around 2000 (Salvation Army, 2001), yet the ALP appeared to have no qualms about marketised public employment services, or any intention to reverse the policy when it returned to office in 2007.

The missing political party

And so, with corporate money and the media barons backing them, the Fraser, Hawke and Keating governments acclimatised the public to mass unemployment. ALP governments actively engaged in transferring a large portion of national output from wages to profits under the Accord processFootnote 14 and used a savage recession to casualise the labour force in the early 1990s, further disempowering the union movement (Reference PuseyPusey, 2003), as they privatised, outsourced and downsized the public sector (Reference Cook, Quirk and MitchellCook et al., 2012). In its most recent period in office, Labor governments pursued budget surpluses as unemployment and labour underutilisation rates rose (Reference BattinBattin, 2017). Whereas the gap between rich and poor narrowed during the period of full employment, it has continued to widen ever since, such that Australia is now considered by Citigroup investment strategists as a ‘plutonomy’ (Citigroup, 2006; Reference GradínGradín, 1999; Oxfam, 2014).

How do we account for Bob Hawke’s role in all this? Although claiming to admire what Curtin and Chifley achieved, and condemning proposals to abandon full employment during an inflation crisis, he then presided over a government that created mass unemployment, punished the unemployed and deliberately casualised the labour force. Perhaps a clue lies in the diplomatic cable traffic of 1974 where Hawke is reported to have had ‘feelers about political realignment’ while dismissing the likelihood of a ‘national unity’ government at that time (Reference BrandBrand, 1974). Of course, the ‘national unity’ message of his first government was dramatically emphasised at the ‘national economic summit’ Hawke convened within a month of leading Labor back to power in March 1983. Business and union leaders sat in the House of Representatives of the Old Parliament House to forge a deal between labor and capital – to bury class antagonisms and agree to increase profits for reinvestment in job creating, productive enterprises, to bring down unemployment and inflation. Unfortunately, the beneficiaries of this largesse used it to excessively acquire shares, companies, property, artworks and other assets, producing the asset price inflation of the late 1980s, prompting the interest rate rises that caused the recession Paul Keating thought ‘we had to have’ (Reference TooheyToohey, 1994).

When governments of ‘national unity’ were previously formed in Australia and the UK during the 1930s economic crisis, prominent Labo(u)r figures became the leaders of conservative governments. In Australia, former Labor Premier of Tasmania and acting Federal Treasurer Joseph Lyons was recruited by Keith Murdoch (Rupert’s father) and a group of Melbourne business and political figures, including Robert Menzies, to lead the rebadged conservative ‘United Australia Party’ (Reference DenningDenning, 1982; Reference JostJost, 1978). Labor leader Ramsay MacDonald took a similar path in Britain. Both were contemptuous of the left-wings of their parties, both were backed by powerful business and media interests and both were condemned as traitors by their respective former parties. Like Hawke, they called for sacrifices in the national interest, reduced the workers’ share of national income and increased the business share. Whereas we see some parallels with Hawke, a key difference is that MacDonald and Lyons left the remains of their Labo(u)r parties in opposition, so they could eventually regroup and return to office as in the case of the Curtin-Chifley government. Hawke retained the Labor franchise as his ‘national unity’ party, thus ensuring the political pendulum had nowhere to swing back to when the electorate tired of the economic repression that Fraser’s, his and subsequent neoliberal governments actively facilitated by preserving high levels of labour underutilisation.

Conclusion

As a blueprint for a major policy innovation, the details (and omissions) of the 1945 White Paper, the development of its various drafts, its political compromises and so forth, are legitimate concerns for modern-day reviewers.Footnote 15 Nevertheless, we should not lose sight of its most important achievement: it played a critical strategic role in convincing Australians that the Commonwealth had the power and responsibility to eliminate all but frictional unemployment. It was this understanding that prevented governments from using unemployment as a political instrument for the next 30 years. We should celebrate this document, and reflect on how profound its core message was: a free and democratic people have a right to work. The contrast between the Australian Labor Party of 73 years ago that successfully fought to establish that right, and its modern namesake that pretends it never happened, is a stark reminder of what Australia’s working people have lost along the way.

Funding

The author(s) received no financial support for the research, authorship and/or publication of this article.

Footnotes

1. An early description of this phenomenon may be found in the preamble to the English Statute of Labourers of 1349 and 1351. This maximum rates award was enacted because the bubonic plague wiped out one-third of the working age population, and the scarcity of labour/relative abundance of jobs, emboldened workers to seek higher wages and better working conditions. The act set wages to the levels they were 4 years before the plague struck, and included penalties for employers who paid above them and for workers who refused offers of work (Reference QuirkQuirk, 2006; Reference Stephenson and MarchamStephenson and Macham, 1937).

2. The Centre of Full Employment and Equity (CofFEE) at the University of Newcastle, NSW, advocates the elimination of unemployment with a ‘Job Guarantee’, whereby the Commonwealth provides a pool of minimum wage jobs to people who would otherwise be unemployed, entailing work of benefit to the community or the environment, designed to inculcate skills in demand in the local economy. See: Reference Cook, Mitchell and QuirkCook et al., 2008; Reference MitchellMitchell, 1998; Reference Mitchell and MuyskenMitchell and Muysken, 2008; Reference Mitchell, Quirk and WrightsonMitchell and Quirk, 2005; Reference Mitchell, Watts and CarlsonMitchell and Watts, 2003; Reference Mitchell, Wray and CarlsonMitchell and Wray, 2004; Reference MoslerMosler, [1997] 1998; Reference Quirk, Allen and AndresenQuirk et al., 2006; Reference WrayWray, 1997.

3. The term ‘right to work’ was later appropriated, predominantly in the USA, as a denunciation of the ‘closed shop’ where employment is conditional on joining a trade union. It is seldom explained that the closed shop was adopted as a countermeasure to the victimisation and blacklisting of unionists in workplaces (Reference OlsonOlson, 1971).

4. This is despite the inclusion of the Right to Work in both the 1948 Universal Declaration of Human Rights (article 23) and the United Nations Covenant on Economic Social and Cultural Rights (article 6; Reference Nevile, Kriesler, Harcourt, Kriesler and HaleviNevile and Kriesler, 2016).

5. Entitled ‘A Bill to promote work through public authorities for unemployed people. 7 Edw VII, c3’.

6. Where a court had ruled British trade unions could not fund political activities, such as wages for Labour politicians.

7. President Harry S. Truman explained to a New Hampshire audience on 16 October 1952 that when he and other senators introduced the ‘Full Employment Bill’ of 1945 to ‘establish a national policy of full employment, and set up the machinery to carry out that policy’ the ‘National Association of Manufacturers and the other big business organizations rolled out their propaganda machines’ to scuttle the policy. ‘They brought up all kinds of arguments as to why full employment was a bad idea. They said people would lose their initiative if they could count on having full employment… One distinguished witness said it was good for business to have a ‘floating pool of unemployed’. ‘… The NAM flooded the country with propaganda leaflets against the full employment bill. They saw that these leaflets got into the hands of schoolteachers, editors, radio commentators and everybody else in a position to influence public opinion’. ‘One reactionary group, calling themselves the Committee for Constitutional Government – which specializes in calling progressive legislation communistic – put that label on the idea of full employment, too. And this refrain was picked up by other big business opponents of the bill. That same committee’s literature also attacked the goal of full employment as – quote –“sentimental humanitarianism”’. These opponents ‘succeeded in getting the act watered down. The title had been changed from the Full Employment Act of 1946 to just the Employment Act of 1946. And the right-to-a-job idea had been killed and the rest of the provisions had been changed accordingly. ‘The Republicans in the House of Representatives voted almost 2 to 1 against the full Employment Act of 1946 (Reference TrumanTruman, 1952).

8. President Roosevelt declared the ‘Four Freedoms’, of speech and religion, from want, and from fear, in a speech to Congress on 6 January 1941.

9. The Menzies government was returned with less than 50% of the two-party preferred vote at both the 1954 and 1961 elections (Reference BarberBarber, 2011).

10. This is now thought to have been deliberately engineered by US Secretary of State and National Security Advisor, Henry Kissinger. Oil market insider Reference EngdahlWalter Engdahl (2004) suggests that Kissinger’s oil industry patrons benefitted enormously, because unprofitable oil fields were made profitable. At the same time, this strategy restored value to the recently floated and devalued US dollar, because the global oil market is denominated in US dollars, so increasing the price of oil increased demand for US currency. US columnist Reference AndersonJack Anderson (1979) made similar accusations at the time.

11. (Cabinet Submission 1243, 1974: 2): A number of things must be present before inflation can be reversed. They include a slacker demand situation, a shock to inflationary expectations and, for a time, reduced employment opportunities. I set aside the popular cure theories we read about in the daily press; they have not worked anywhere else and they will not work here. So it is not really a choice between widely varying methods of checking inflation but a choice between whether or not we are going to seriously tackle it at all; doing so must inevitably entail some consequences in terms of employment opportunities, profits and growth. There is another viewpoint that over-full employment must be maintained all of the time. I understand that viewpoint. But inflation of the order we are experiencing, let alone of the order in prospect, is so socially and economically destructive and divisive in its implications that we must ask ourselves whether for a time we should not have a different priority.

12. The initial error in tightening monetary policy too far was inexcusable, but the dogmatic refusal of Treasury and the Reserve Bank to contemplate any form of economic stimulus in 1990 and 1991 was perverse. … A Royal Commission should have been held into this massively destructive series of misjudgements, which are still destroying the working lives of hundreds of thousands, and costing the Australian people tens of billions of dollars. (Reference Langmore and QuigginLangmore and Quiggin, 1994: 74)

13. ‘According to the PM [Keating] the countries that are going to “make it”, that are going to emerge “at the top of the pack”, are those with some degree of unemployment during the transition period between the first phase of economic restructuring (Australia in the 1980s) and the second stage, which will follow in the mid-1990s. He got rather carried away with the notion of unemployment in this phase of restructuring – “international”, “necessary” and “inevitable”. “It is the unemployment we had to have”’ (Reference BlewettBlewett, 1999: 153).

14. For specifically the case of Australia, see Reference Mitchell and FaziMitchell and Fazi (2017) and Reference StanfordStanford (2017), both demonstrating declining wages shares and real unit labour costs and rising profit shares throughout Labor’s term of office, more markedly under Hawke than Keating. Also: Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS, 2017). Reference StockhammerStockhammer (2012) includes Australia in a global analysis of declining wages shares.

References

Ahamed, L (2009) Lords of Finance: The Bankers Who Broke the World. New York: Penguin.Google Scholar
Anderson, J (1979) Kissinger-Rockefeller tie linked to oil price increase. Deseret News, 31 May, p. 4.Google Scholar
Arndt, HW (1973) Inflation: new policy prescriptions. The Australian Economic Review 6: 4148.Google Scholar
Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) (2017) Australian National Accounts: National Income, Expenditure and Product (Table 7. ABS Catalogue no. 5206.0). Canberra, ACT, Australia: ABS.Google Scholar
Australian National Audit Office (ANAO) (1991) Auditor General Report No 10, 1991, Administration of the Work Test for Unemployment Benefit. Canberra, ACT, Australia: Australian National Audit Office.Google Scholar
Barber, S (2011) Federal Election Results 1901–2010. Research paper no. 6, 2011–12 (Statistics and Mapping Section, Department of Parliamentary Services). Canberra, ACT, Australia: Parliament of Australia.Google Scholar
Battin, T (2017) Labouring under neoliberalism: the Australian Labor government’s ideological constraint, 2007–2013. The Economic and Labour Relations Review 28(1): 146163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beder, S (2005) The role of ‘economic education’ in achieving capitalist hegemony. In: Hegemony: Explorations into consensus, coercion and culture workshop, University of Wollongong, Wollongong, NSW, Australia, 14–15 February.Google Scholar
Beder, S (2006) Free Market Missionaries: The Corporate Manipulation of Community Values. London: Earthscan.Google Scholar
Black, D (2001) Friendship Is a Sheltering Tree: John Curtin’s Letters 1907 to 1945. Perth, WA, Australia: John Curtin Prime Ministerial Library.Google Scholar
Blanc, L (1848) The Organization of Labour. London, UK: M Mason.Google Scholar
Blewett, N (1999) A Cabinet Diary: A Personal Record of the First Keating Government. Kent Town, SA, Australia: Wakefield Press.Google Scholar
Bramston, T (2011) Looking for the Light on the Hill: Modern Labor’s Challenges. Brunswick, VIC, Australia: Scribe.Google Scholar
Brand, R (1974) Trade Union Leader unsure that Australian Government can satisfy worker demands: interview of Robert Hawke by US embassy official Labatt, 12/11/1974, US Embassy Cable, Public Library of US Diplomacy. Available at: https://www.wikileaks.org/plusd/cables/1974MELBOU01311_b.html (accessed 26 April 2018).Google Scholar
Brown, KD (1971) Labour and Unemployment 1900–1914. Newton Abbot: David Chester.Google Scholar
Burnett, J (1994) Idle Hands: The Experience of Unemployment, 1790–1990. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, I (1994) Working Nation: a critical assessment of recent public policy on unemployment in Australia. In: IWPLMS conference, Strasbourg, July.Google Scholar
Carey, A (1995) Taking the Risk Out of Democracy. Sydney, NSW, Australia: UNSW Press.Google Scholar
Cass, B (1988) Income support for the unemployed in Australia: Towards a more active system. Social Security Review, Issues paper no. 4. Canberra, ACT, Australia: Australian Government Publishing Service.Google Scholar
Cathcart, M (1988) Defending the National Tuckshop. Melbourne, VIC, Australia: McPhee Gribble.Google Scholar
Chifley, B (1949) National election speech, delivered at Canberra, ACT, 14 November. Available at: http://electionspeeches.moadoph.gov.au/speeches/1949-ben-chifley (accessed 24 April 2018).Google Scholar
Citigroup (2006) Equity strategy report: revisiting plutonomy – the rich getting richer. Citigroup. Available at: http://www.sourcewatch.org/index.php?title=Plutonomy (accessed 20 April 2018).Google Scholar
Committee on Employment Opportunities (CEO) (1993) Restoring Full Employment: A Discussion Paper. Canberra, ACT, Australia: Government Publishing Service.Google Scholar
Commonwealth of Australia (CoA) (1945) Full employment in Australia. Parliamentary Paper no. 11.Google Scholar
Cook, B, Mitchell, W, Quirk, V, et al . (2008) Creating Effective Local Labour Markets: A New Framework for Regional Employment Policy. Newcastle, NSW, Australia: Centre of Full Employment and Equity.Google Scholar
Cook, B, Quirk, V, Mitchell, W (2012) The Impact on Community Services of Staff and Service Reductions, Privatisation and Outsourcing of Public Services in the Australian States: Report Prepared for the Community and Public-sector Union (SPSF Group). Newcastle, NSW, Australia: Centre of Full Employment and Equity.Google Scholar
Coombs, HC (1958) Conditions of Monetary Policy in Australia: RC Mills Memorial Lecture Delivered 29/4/1958. Sydney, NSW, Australia: University of Sydney.Google Scholar
Curtin, J (1942) Address to the 1942 Constitutional Convention (Records of the Commonwealth of Australia, 00110/51). In: Digest of decisions and announcements and important speeches by the Prime Minister. No. 46, John Curtin Parliamentary Library, Perth, WA, Australia, 12 November–6 December.Google Scholar
Denning, W (1982) Caucus Crisis: The Rise and Fall of the Scullin Government. Sydney, NSW, Australia: Hale & Iremonger.Google Scholar
Engdahl, W (2004) A Century of War: Anglo American Oil Politics and the New World Order. London: Pluto Press.Google Scholar
Evatt, HV (1942) Post-War Reconstruction: A Case for Greater Commonwealth Powers. Canberra, ACT, Australia: Australian Commonwealth Government Printer.Google Scholar
Fitzgerald, R (1994) Red Ted: The Life of EG Theodore. Brisbane, QLD, Australia: University of Queensland Press.Google Scholar
Forde, F (1971) Interview with Mel Pratt. Canberra, ACT, Australia: National Library of Australia.Google Scholar
Freudenberg, G (1977) A Certain Grandeur. Melbourne, ACT, Australia: Sun Books.Google Scholar
Gillard, J (2010) Chifley Memorial Light on the Hill speech, Bathurst Panthers Club, 18 September. Available at: http://australianpolitics.com/2010/09/18/gillard-light-on-the-hill-speech.html (accessed 20 June 2018).Google Scholar
Gradín, C (1999) Polarization and inequality: an international comparison. Essays on Polarization Measurement. Available at: https://www.researchgate.net/profile/Carlos_Gradin2/publication/265080587_POLARIZATION_AND_INEQUALITY_AN_INTERNATIONAL_COMPARISON/links/56ac8e7008ae43a3980c4dd6.pdf (accessed 20 June 2018).Google Scholar
Grattan, M (1983) Hawke pledges tax cuts on lower middle incomes. The Age, 11 February, p. 1.Google Scholar
Green, M (1974a) Ambassadors conversation with Robert Hawke. US Embassy Cable, Public Library of US Diplomacy, 11 July. Available at: https://www.wikileaks.org/plusd/cables/1974MELBOU00808_b.html (accessed 20 June 2018).Google Scholar
Green M (1974b) Australian economic and political situation: views of Rupert Murdock, Managing Director of News Ltd. and Associated Companies (US Embassy Cable, Public Library of US Diplomacy), 16 November. Available at: http://www.wikileaks.org/plusd/cables/1974CANBER07509_b.html (accessed 20 June 2018).Google Scholar
Griffen-Foley, B (2003) Party Games – Australian Politics and the Media from War to Dismissal. Melbourne, VIC, Australia: Text Publishing.Google Scholar
Harding, A (1985) Unemployment policy: a case study in agenda management. Australian Journal of Public Administration 44(3): 224246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harrop (1974) Continuing debate on GOA economic policy (US Embassy Cable, Public Library of US Diplomacy), 23 July. Available at: https://www.wikileaks.org/plusd/cables/1974CANBER04740_b.html (accessed 20 June 2018).Google Scholar
Howe, B (1991) Social Security (Job Search and Newstart) Bill Reprint. Canberra, ACT, Australia: Australian Government Publishing Service.Google Scholar
Hughes, B (1980) Exit Full Employment: Economic Policy in the Stone Age. Melbourne, VIC, Australia: Angus & Robertson.Google Scholar
Jose, J, Quirk, V (2002) Re-engineering and managerialism: the tabula rasa approach to policy and administration. In: Carlson, E (ed.) The Path to Full Employment, Proceedings of the 4th Path to Full Employment Conference and 9th National Conference on Unemployment. Newcastle, NSW, Australia: University of Newcastle, pp. 90101.Google Scholar
Jost, J (1978) Menzies: the man and the myth. The National Times, 7 May, p. 27.Google Scholar
Kalecki, M (1943) Political aspects of full employment. The Political Quarterly 14(4): 322330.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kerr, J (1976) Address at the Opening of Parliament by his Excellency the Governor General Sir John Kerr. Canberra, ACT, Australia: Australian Parliament House (Hansard).Google Scholar
Keynes, JM (1936) The General Theory of Employment Interest and Money. London: MacMillan.Google Scholar
Korpi, W (1991) Political and economic explanations of unemployment: a cross sectional and long -term analysis. British Journal of Political Science 21(3): 315348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Korpi, W (2002) The Great Trough in Unemployment: A Long Term View of Unemployment, Inflation, Strikes and the Profit / Wage Ratio. Stockholm: Swedish Institute for Social Research, Stockholm University.Google Scholar
Langmore, J, Quiggin, J (1994) Work for All: Full Employment in the Nineties. Melbourne, VIC, Australia: Melbourne University Press.Google Scholar
Leigh, A (2014) Billionaires and Battlers: The Story of Inequality in Australia. Melbourne, VIC, Australia: Redback.Google Scholar
Lynch, P (1972) Economic Security. Canberra, ACT, Australia: Department of Labour and National Service.Google Scholar
McIntyre, S (2015) Australia’s Boldest Experiment: War and Reconstruction in the 1940S. Sydney, NSW, Australia: New South Publishing.Google Scholar
McKay, DC (1965) The National Workshops: A Study in the French Revolution of 1848. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
McLean, I (1975) Keir Hardy. New York: St. Martin’s Press.Google Scholar
Maiden, T (1971) The tough business leader. Australian Financial Review, 15 April, p. 1.Google Scholar
Martens, R (1974) Robert Hawke call on Acting Secretary Ingersoll (US Embassy Cable, Public Library of US Diplomacy), 26 July. Available at: https://www.wikileaks.org/plusd/cables/1974STATE166138_b.html (accessed 20 June 2018).Google Scholar
Menadue, J (1999) Things You Learn along the Way. Melbourne, VIC, Australia: David Lovell Publishing.Google Scholar
Menzies, RG (1943) Commonwealth Parliamentary Debates (7 October 1943, CLXXVI: 248). Canberra, ACT, Australia: Commonwealth of Australia.Google Scholar
Mitchell, WF (1998) The Buffer stock model and the NAIRU: the path to full employment. Journal of Economic Issues 32(2): 547555.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, WF, Fazi, T (2017) Reclaiming the State: A Progressive Vision of Sovereignty for a Post-Neoliberal World. London: Pluto Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, WF, Muysken, J (2008) Full Employment Abandoned: Shifting Sands and Policy Failures. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, WF, Quirk, V (2005) Skills shortages in Australia: concepts and reality. In: Wrightson, G (ed.) Creating a Culture of Full Employment (Proceedings of the 7th path to full employment conference and 12th National Conference on Unemployment). Newcastle, NSW, Australia: University of Newcastle, pp. 307323.Google Scholar
Mitchell, WF, Watts, M (2003) In defence of the Job Guarantee. In: Carlson, E (ed.) The Full Employment Imperative (Proceedings of the 5th Path to Full Employment Conference and 10th National Conference on Unemployment). Newcastle, NSW, Australia: University of Newcastle, pp. 183196.Google Scholar
Mitchell, WF, Wray, LR (2004) Full employment through a Job Guarantee: a response to the critics. In: Carlson, E (ed.) A Future That Works: Economics, Employment and the Environment (Proceedings of the 6th Path to Full Employment Conference and the 11th National Conference on Unemployment). Newcastle, NSW, Australia: University of Newcastle, pp. 2136.Google Scholar
Moore, A (1989) The Secret Army and the Premier: Conservative Paramilitary Organisations in New South Wales, 1930–32. Sydney, NSW, Australia: UNSW Press.Google Scholar
Mosler, WB ([1997] 1998) Full employment and price stability. Journal of Post-Keynesian Economics 20(2): 167182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
National Archives of Australia (NAA) (2004) Submission 1243, ‘Economic Situation and Prospects’ [A5915, 1243] (1974 Cabinet records – selected documents). Canberra, ACT, Australia: NAA.Google Scholar
Nevile, JW (2015) The 1945 White Paper, full employment in Australia: a triumph for heterodox economics. In: 2015 society of heterodox economists conference, 8 December, University of New South Wales, Sydney, NSW, Australia.Google Scholar
Nevile, JW, Kriesler, P (2016) Full employment, a neglected, but indispensable and feasible human right. In: Harcourt, GC, Kriesler, P, Halevi, J, et al . (eds) Post-Keynesian Essays from Down Under Volume III: Essays on Ethics, Social Justice and Economics. London: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 209218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, M (1971) The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) (1970) Inflation the Present Problem. Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
OXFAM (2014) Working for the few: political capture and economic inequality. OXFAM Briefing Paper, January. Oxford: OXFAM.Google Scholar
Pusey, M (2003) The Experience of Middle Australia. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Quirk, V (2002) Why the Job Network Is Not Working: Submission DR068, Independent Review of Job Network. Canberra, ACT, Australia: Productivity Commission.Google Scholar
Quirk, V (2004) The problem of a full employment economy . Coffee Working paper no 04-02. Centre of Full Employment and Equity CofFEE, University of Newcastle. Available at: http://e1.newcastle.edu.au/coffee/pubs/wp/2004/04–02.pdf (accessed 9 November 2018).Google Scholar
Quirk, V (2006) Lessons from the English Poor Laws. Newcastle, NSW, Australia: APSA.Google Scholar
Quirk, V (2007) The job guarantee of 1848 (The challenge to restore full employment: incorporating the 9th Path to Full Employment Conference and 14th National Conference on Unemployment. Proceedings: Refereed Papers), Newcastle, NSW, Australia. Available at: http://e1.newcastle.edu.au/coffee/pubs/wp/2007/07–14.pdf (accessed 9 November 2018).Google Scholar
Quirk, V (2008) Britain and the right to work: 1886–1912. International Journal of Environment, Workplace and Employment 3(3–4): 266284.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quirk, V (2009) The Queensland Unemployed Workers Bill of 1919. In: Labour underutilisation, unemployment and underemployment incorporating the 11th path to full employment conference and 16th national conference on unemployment: proceedings refereed papers), University of Newcastle, Newcastle, NSW, Australia, 3–4 December. Available at: http://e1.newcastle.edu.au/coffee/pubs/wp/2010/10-01.pdf (accessed 9 November 2018).Google Scholar
Quirk, V (2010) London’s silken cords and the depression we had to have. In: The aftermath of the crisis: Incorporating the 12th path to full employment conference and 17th national conference on unemployment. proceedings: refereed papers, Newcastle, NSW, Australia, 2–3 December.Google Scholar
Quirk, V, Allen, E, Andresen, T, et al . (2006) The job guarantee in practice. Working paper no 06-15, Centre of Full Employment and Equity. Callaghan, NSW, Australia: University of Newcastle.Google Scholar
Rowse, T (2000) Full employment and the discipline of labour. The Drawing Board 1(1): 113.Google Scholar
Salvation Army (2001) Stepping into the Breach: A Report on Centrelink Breaching and Emergency Relief. Melbourne, VIC, Australia: The Salvation Army Australia Southern Territory.Google Scholar
Schedvin, B (1971) EG Theodore and the London Pastoral Lobby. Politics 6(1): 2641.Google Scholar
Schmidt, M (1984) The politics of unemployment: rates of unemployment and labour market Policy. West European Politics 7(3): 524.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Senior, NW (1973) Journals Kept in France and Italy from 1848 to 1852. New York: Da Capo Press.Google Scholar
Stanford, J (2017) Briefing Note: Labour Share of Australian GDP Hits All-Time Record Low (Centre for the Future of Work). Canberra, ACT, Australia: The Australia Institute. Available at: https://d3n8a8pro7vhmx.cloudfront.net/theausinstitute/pages/1500/attachments/original/1497298286/Labour_Share_Hits_Record_Low.pdf?1497298286 (accessed 20 June 2018).Google Scholar
Stephenson, C, Marcham, FC (eds) (1937) Sources of English Constitutional History. London: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Stockhammer, E (2012) Why Have Wage Shares Fallen? A Panel Analysis of the Determinants of Functional Income Distribution: For the International Labour Organization (ILO) Project ‘New Perspectives on Wages and Economic Growth’. Geneva: International Labour Office, Conditions of Work and Employment Branch.Google Scholar
Sydney Morning Herald (SMH) (1949) New trends of thought in incentive system, 7 May, p. 2.Google Scholar
Sydney Morning Herald (SMH) (1975) Five point plan on jobless, 5 December, p. 13.Google Scholar
The Age (1971) Budget aim is to hit jobs, 19 August, p. 3.Google Scholar
The Age (1974) Bank man warns of credit squeeze, 27 May, p. 1.Google Scholar
The Argus (1949a) PM spurns policy of 8pc unemployment, 10 February, p. 6.Google Scholar
The Argus (1949b) Unemployment, 16 September, p. 5.Google Scholar
The Argus (1951) No work talk ‘nonsense’, 21 December, p. 5.Google Scholar
The Canberra Times (1946) Emphatic mandate given to Chifley Government, 30 September, p. 1.Google Scholar
The Canberra Times (1949) Approval of national works granted, 19 August, p. 4.Google Scholar
The Canberra Times (1951) Censure on Budget: ‘plan for recession’, 3 October, p. 1.Google Scholar
The Times, London (1943) Planning full employment, 23 January: 5.Google Scholar
Theodore, EG (1919) The Unemployment Problem – Proposed Solution by the Labour Government of Queensland. The Text of the Bill and the Speech Delivered in the Legislative Assembly, on 2 September, 1919, by the Treasurer and Secretary for Public Works (Hon. E.G. Theodore), in Explanation of the Scheme. Brisbane, QLD, Australia: Government of Queensland.Google Scholar
Theodore, EG (1924) Address in Reply, Speech by the Premier, E.G. Theodore, MLA, 5 August 1924. Brisbane, QLD, Australia: Government Printer.Google Scholar
Theodore, EG (1932) Letter to Curtin, October 14 1932, Diary of a Labour Man, John Curtin Prime Ministerial Library. Available at: http://john.curtin.edu.au/diary/index.html (accessed 20 June 2018).Google Scholar
Toohey, B (1994) Tumbling Dice: The Story of Modern Economic Policy. Port Melbourne, VIC, Australia: William Heinemann.Google Scholar
Truman, HS (1952) Address at the Armory in Manchester, New Hampshire, 16 October. Avail-able at: https://www.presidency.ucsb.edu/documents/address-the-armory-manchester-new-hampshire (accessed 8 November 2018).Google Scholar
Tsokhas, K (1984) A Class Apart? Businessmen and Australian Politics 1960–1980. Melbourne, VIC, Australia: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Twomey, P (1994) From Client to Customer: Re-engineering the Delivery of Employment Services. Canberra, ACT, Australia: Report Commissioned for Department of Social Services.Google Scholar
Uren, T (1994) Straight Left. Sydney, NSW, Australia: Random House.Google Scholar
Wearing, M, Smyth, P (1998) Working Nation and beyond as market bureaucracy: the introduction of competition policy in case management. In: Cass, BM, Smyth, P (eds) Contesting the Australian Way: States, Markets and Civil Society. Melbourne, VIC, Australia: Cambridge University Press pp. 228240.Google Scholar
Weller, P, Cutt, J (1976) Treasury Control in Australia. Sydney, NSW, Australia: Ian Novak Publishing.Google Scholar
Whitlam, EG (1985) The Whitlam Government 1972–1975. Melbourne, VIC, Australia: Penguin.Google Scholar
Whitwell, G (1986) The Treasury Line. Sydney, NSW, Australia: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Windschuttle, K (1979) Unemployment: A Social and Political Analysis of the Economic Crisis in Australia. Ringwood, VIC, Australia: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Wray, LR (1997) Government of the last resort: full employment without inflation. Working paper 213. New York: Jerome Levy Economics Institute.Google Scholar