Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-m6dg7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-06T10:05:00.702Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Bibliography

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  12 November 2022

Lionel Page
Affiliation:
University of Queensland
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Optimally Irrational
The Good Reasons We Behave the Way We Do
, pp. 281 - 306
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2022

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abbink, Klaus and Harris, Donna (2019) “In-group favouritism and out-group discrimination in naturally occurring groups,” PLoS ONE, Vol. 14, No. 9, p. e0221616.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Adida, Claire L., Laitin, David D. and Valfort, Marie-Anne (2014) “Muslims in France: Identifying a discriminatory equilibrium,” Journal of Population Economics, Vol. 27, No. 4, pp. 10391086.Google Scholar
Agassi, Andre (2010) Open: An Autobiography. HarperCollinsGoogle Scholar
Ainslie, George (1975) “Specious reward: A behavioral theory of impulsiveness and impulse control,” Psychological Bulletin, Vol. 82, No. 4, p. 463.Google Scholar
Akerlof, George A. and Kranton, Rachel (2010) “Identity economics,” The Economists’ Voice, Vol. 7, No. 2.Google Scholar
Alchian, Armen A (1950) “Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 58, No. 3, pp. 211221.Google Scholar
Alexander, Richard D. (1987) The biology of moral systems. Transaction Publishers.Google Scholar
Alger, Ingela and Weibull, Jörgen W. (2013) “Homo moralis–Preference evolution under incomplete information and assortative matching,” Econometrica, Vol. 81, No. 6, pp. 22692302.Google Scholar
Allais, Maurice (1953) “Le comportement de l’homme rationnel devant le risque: Critique des postulats et axiomes de l’école américaine,” Econometrica, pp. 503546.Google Scholar
Allais, Maurice and Hagen, G. M. (1979) Expected utility hypotheses and the Allais paradox. Springer.Google Scholar
Allen, Eric J., Dechow, Patricia M., Pope, Devin G. and Wu, George (2017) “Reference-dependent preferences: Evidence from marathon runners,” Management Science, Vol. 63, No. 6, pp. 16571672.Google Scholar
Allen, M. W. and Jones, T. L., eds. (2016) Violence and warfare among hunter-gatherers. Routledge.Google Scholar
Alt, Franz (1936) “Über die messbarkeit des nutzens,” Zeitschrift für Nation-alökonomie/Journal of Economics, Vol. 7, No. 2, pp. 161169.Google Scholar
Ammer, Christine (2013) The American heritage dictionary of idioms: American English idiomatic expressions & phrases. HMH.Google Scholar
Anand, Paul, Pattanaik, Prasanta and Puppe, Clemens (2009) The handbook of rational and social choice. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Anderson, Ashton and Green, Etan A. (2018) “Personal bests as reference points,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, Vol. 115, No. 8, pp. 17721776.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Anderson, John Robert (1990) The adaptive character of thought. Psychology Press.Google Scholar
Angilletta, Michael J. Jr., Kubitz, Gregory and Wilson, Robbie S. (2019) “Self-deception in nonhuman animals: Weak crayfish escalated aggression as if they were strong,” Behavioral Ecology, Vol. 30, No. 5, pp. 14691476.Google Scholar
Angner, Erik (2019) “We’re all behavioral economists now,” Journal of Economic Methodology, Vol. 26, No. 3, pp. 195207.Google Scholar
Aquinas, T., (1265–1274/2015). Summa theologica. Xist Publishing.Google Scholar
Arendt, Hannah (1963/2006) Eichmann in Jerusalem: A Report on the Banality of Evil. Penguin.Google Scholar
Ariely, Dan and Wertenbroch, Klaus (2002) “Procrastination, deadlines, and performance: Self-control by precommitment,” Psychological Science, Vol. 13, No. 3, pp. 219224.Google Scholar
Aristotle (340 BCE). Nicomachean ethics.Google Scholar
(350 BCE) On the heavens.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. (1951/1963) Social choice and individual values. Yale University Press.Google Scholar
(1972) “Some mathematical models of race discrimination in the labor market,” in Pascal, Anthony, ed., Racial discrimination in economic life. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, pp. 187204.Google Scholar
Ashar, Jayen, Ashmore, Jaiden, Hall, Brad, Harris, Sean, Hengst, Bernhard, Liu, Roger, Mei, Zijie, Pagnucco, Maurice, Roy, Ritwik, Sammut, Claude, Sushkov, Oleg, Teh, Belinda and Tsekouras, Luke (2015) “RoboCup SPL 2014 champion team paper,” in Bianchi, R. A., Akin, H. L., Ramamoorthy, S., and Sugiura, K., eds., RoboCup 2014: Robot World Cup XVIII (Vol. 8992). Springer, pp. 7081.Google Scholar
Aumann, Robert J. (1960) “Acceptable points in games of perfect information,” Pacific Journal of Mathematics, Vol. 10, No. 2, pp. 381417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aumann, Robert J. (1962) “Utility theory without the completeness axiom,” Econometrica, Vol. 30, No. 3, pp. 445462.Google Scholar
Aumann, Robert J. (2019) “A synthesis of behavioural and mainstream economics,” Nature Human Behaviour, Vol. 3, No. 7, pp. 666670.Google Scholar
Axelrod, Robert (1980a) “Effective choice in the prisoner’s dilemma,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 24, No. 1, pp. 325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Axelrod, Robert (1980b) “More effective choice in the prisoner’s dilemma,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 24, No. 3, pp. 379403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Babcock, Linda and Loewenstein, George (1997) “Explaining bargaining impasse: The role of self-serving biases,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 11, No. 1, pp. 109126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bacharach, Michael (1999) “Interactive team reasoning: A contribution to the theory of co-operation,” Research in Economics, Vol. 53, No. 2, pp. 117147.Google Scholar
Bacharach, Michael (2006) Beyond individual choice: Teams and frames in game theory. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Baliga, Sandeep and Ely, Jeffrey C. (2011) “Mnemonomics: The sunk cost fallacy as a memory kludge,” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, Vol. 3, No. 4, pp. 3567.Google Scholar
Balliet, Daniel, Wu, Junhui and De Dreu, Carsten K. W. (2014) “Ingroup favoritism in cooperation: A meta-analysis,” Psychological Bulletin, Vol. 140, No. 6, p. 1556.Google Scholar
Barber, Brad M. and Odean, Terrance (2001) “Boys will be boys: Gender, overconfidence, and common stock investment,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 116, No. 1, pp. 261292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barber, Benjamin S. IV and English, William (2019) “The origin of wealth matters: Equity norms trump equality norms in the ultimatum game with earned endowments,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, Vol. 158, pp. 3343.Google Scholar
Barrett, Justin L (2000) “Exploring the natural foundations of religion,” Trends in Cognitive Sciences, Vol. 4, No. 1, pp. 2934.Google Scholar
Baumard, Nicolas, André, Jean-Baptiste and Sperber, Dan (2013) “A mutualistic approach to morality: The evolution of fairness by partner choice,” Behavioral and Brain Sciences, Vol. 36, No. 1, pp. 5978.Google Scholar
Beaufils, Bruno, Delahaye, Jean-Paul and Mathieu, Philippe (1997) “Our meeting with gradual, a good strategy for the iterated prisoner’s dilemma,” in Proceedings of the Fifth International Workshop on the Synthesis and Simulation of Living Systems. MIT Press, pp. 202209.Google Scholar
Bechara, Antoine, Damasio, Antonio R., Damasio, Hanna, Anderson, Steven W. et al. (1994) “Insensitivity to future consequences following damage to human prefrontal cortex,” Cognition, Vol. 50, pp. 13.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S. (1957) The economics of discrimination. University of Chicago press.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S. (1976) “Altruism, egoism, and genetic fitness: Economics and sociobiology,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 14, No. 3, pp. 817826.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S. (1981) “Altruism in the family and selfishness in the market place,” Economica, Vol. 48, No. 189, pp. 115.Google Scholar
Bénabou, Roland and Tirole, Jean (2002) “Self-confidence and personal motivation,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 117, No. 3, pp. 871915.Google Scholar
Benson, K. E. and Stephens, D. W. (1996) “Interruptions, tradeoffs, and temporal discounting,” American Zoologist, Vol. 36, No. 4, pp. 506517.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bentham, Jeremy (1776) A fragment on government.Google Scholar
Bentham, Jeremy (1825) The rationale of reward: John and H. L. Hunt.Google Scholar
Bentham, Jeremy (1832/1998) “Anarchical fallacies,” Headline Series, No. 318, p. 56.Google Scholar
Berns, G.S., Laibson, D. and Loewenstein, G., 2007. Intertemporal choice–toward an integrative framework. Trends in cognitive sciences, 11(11), pp.482488.Google Scholar
Bhui, Rahul and Xiang, Yang (2021) “A rational account of the repulsion effect.” https://psyarxiv.com/hxjqv/.Google Scholar
Bicchieri, Cristina (2005) The grammar of society: The nature and dynamics of social norms. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Binmore, Ken (1987) “Modeling rational players: Part I,” Economics & Philosophy, Vol. 3, No. 2, pp. 179214.Google Scholar
Binmore, Ken (1988) “Modeling rational players: Part II,” Economics & Philosophy, Vol. 4, No. 1, pp. 955.Google Scholar
Binmore, Ken (1994b) Game theory and the social contract, vol. 1: Playing fair. MIT Press.Google Scholar
Binmore, Ken (2005a) “Economic man—Or straw man?Behavioral and Brain Sciences, Vol. 28, No. 6, pp. 817818.Google Scholar
Binmore, Ken (2005b) Natural justice. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Binmore, Ken (2007) Game theory: A very short introduction. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Binmore, Ken (2008) Rational decisions. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Binmore, Ken (2012) “Kitcher on natural morality,” Analyse & Kritik, Vol. 34, No. 1, pp. 129140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, Kenneth (1994a) Game theory and the social contract, vol. 2: Just playing. MIT Press.Google Scholar
Birger, Jon (2015) Date-Onomics: How dating became a lopsided numbers game. Workman Publishing.Google Scholar
Blanchflower, David G., Van Landeghem, Bert and Oswald, Andrew J. (2009) “Imitative obesity and relative utility,” Journal of the European Economic Association, Vol. 7, Nos. 2–3, pp. 528538.Google Scholar
Bogacz, Rafal, Brown, Eric, Moehlis, Jeff, Holmes, Philip and Cohen, Jonathan D. (2006) “The physics of optimal decision making: A formal analysis of models of performance in two-alternative forced-choice tasks,” Psychological review, Vol. 113, No. 4, p. 700.Google Scholar
Aislinn, Bohren, J., Haggag, Kareem, Imas, Alex and Pope, Devin G. (2019) “Inaccurate statistical discrimination,” Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Bond, Charles F. and DePaulo, Bella M. (2006) “Accuracy of deception judgments,” Personality and Social Psychology Review, Vol. 10, No. 3, pp. 214234.Google Scholar
Bossaerts, Peter and Murawski, Carsten (2017) “Computational complexity and human decision-making,” Trends in Cognitive Sciences, Vol. 21, No. 12, pp. 917929.Google Scholar
Bourdieu, Pierre and Passeron, Jean-Claude (1977/1990) Reproduction in education, society and culture, vol. 4. Sage.Google Scholar
Bourget, D. and Chalmers, D. J. (2020) “Philosophers on philosophy: The PhilPapers 2020 Survey.” https://philpapers.org/rec/BOUPOP-3.Google Scholar
Bowles, Samuel and Gintis, Herbert (1976/2011) Schooling in capitalist America: Educational reform and the contradictions of economic life. Haymarket Books.Google Scholar
Bowles, Samuel and Gintis, Herbert (2013) A cooperative species: Human reciprocity and its evolution. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Boyer, Pascal (2008) Religion explained. Random House.Google Scholar
Brickman, Philip (1971) “Hedonic relativism and planning the good society,” in Appley, M. H., ed., Adaptation level theory. New York: Academic Press, pp. 287301.Google Scholar
Brosnan, Sarah F., Jones, Owen D., Lambeth, Susan P., Mareno, Mary Catherine, Richardson, Amanda S. and Schapiro, Steven J. (2007) “Endowment effects in chimpanzees,” Current Biology, Vol. 17, No. 19, pp. 17041707.Google Scholar
Brown, Zachariah C., Anicich, Eric M. and Galinsky, Adam D. (2020) “Compensatory conspicuous communication: Low status increases jargon use,” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, Vol. 161, pp. 274290.Google Scholar
Bruni, Luigino and Sugden, Robert (2007) “The road not taken: How psychology was removed from economics, and how it might be brought back,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 117, No. 516, pp. 146173.Google Scholar
Buggle, Johannes C. (2020) “Growing collectivism: Irrigation, group conformity and technological divergence,” Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 25, No. 2, pp. 147193.Google Scholar
Bursztyn, Leonardo, Ferman, Bruno, Fiorin, Stefano, Kanz, Martin and Rao, Gautam (2018) “Status goods: Experimental evidence from platinum credit cards,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 133, No. 3, pp. 15611595.Google Scholar
Buss, David M. (1988) “Love acts: The evolutionary biology of love,” in R. J. Sternberg and M. L. Barnes, eds., Psychology of love. Yale University Press, 100118.Google Scholar
Buss, David M. (2003) The evolution of desire: Strategies of human mating. Basic Books.Google Scholar
Buss, David M. (2006) “The evolution of love,” in Sternberg, Robert J. and Sternberg, Karin, eds., The new psychology of love. Yale University Press, pp. 6586.Google Scholar
Buss, David M. (2019) Evolutionary psychology: The new science of the mind. Routledge.Google Scholar
Camerer, Colin, Babcock, Linda, Loewenstein, George and Thaler, Richard (1997) “Labor supply of New York City cabdrivers: One day at a time,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 112, No. 2, pp. 407441.Google Scholar
Camerer, Colin F. (2011) Behavioral game theory: Experiments in strategic interaction. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Cameron, J. J. and Curry, E. (2020) “Gender roles and date context in hypothetical scripts for a woman and a man on a first date in the twenty-first century.” Sex Roles, Vol. 82, No. 5, pp. 345362.Google Scholar
Caplin, Andrew, Dean, Mark and Leahy, John (2019) “Rational inattention, optimal consideration sets, and stochastic choice,” The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 86, No. 3, pp. 10611094.Google Scholar
Carlin, John (2008) Playing the enemy: Nelson Mandela and the game that made a nation. Penguin.Google Scholar
Carmichael, H. Lorne and MacLeod, W. Bentley (1997) “Gift giving and the evolution of cooperation,” International Economic Review, Vol. 38, No. 3, pp. 485509.Google Scholar
Carmon, Ziv and Ariely, Dan (2000) “Focusing on the forgone: How value can appear so different to buyers and sellers,” Journal of Consumer Research, Vol. 27, No. 3, pp. 360370.Google Scholar
Casey, B. J., Somerville, Leah H., Gotlib, Ian H., Ayduk, Ozlem, Franklin, Nicholas T., Askren, Mary K., Jonides, John, Berman, Marc G., Wilson, Nicole L., Teslovich, Theresa et al. (2011) “Behavioral and neural correlates of delay of gratification 40 years later,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, Vol. 108, No. 36, pp. 1499815003.Google Scholar
Chagnon, Napoleon A. (1988) “Life histories, blood revenge, and warfare in a tribal population,” Science, Vol. 239, No. 4843, pp. 985992.Google Scholar
Charness, Gary and Chen, Yan (2020) “Social identity, group behavior, and teams,” Annual Review of Economics, Vol. 12.Google Scholar
Charness, Gary and Rabin, Matthew (2002) “Understanding social preferences with simple tests,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 117, No. 3, pp. 817869.Google Scholar
Chernoff, Herman (1954) “Rational selection of decision functions,” Econometrica, pp. 422443.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Choi, Jung-Kyoo and Bowles, Samuel (2007) “The coevolution of parochial altruism and war,” Science, Vol. 318, No. 5850, pp. 636640.Google Scholar
Cicero, Marcus Tullius (45 BCE/1869) De finibus bonorum et malorum. Imprensis Librariae Glydendalianae (Frederici Hegel).Google Scholar
Clark, Andrew E. (2016) “Happiness, habits, and high rank,”in Bartolini, S., Bilancini, E., Bruni, L. and Porta, P. L., eds., Policies for happiness. Oxford University Press, p. 62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, Andrew E., Frijters, Paul and Shields, Michael A. (2008) “Relative income, happiness, and utility: An explanation for the Easterlin paradox and other puzzles,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 46, No. 1, pp. 95144.Google Scholar
Clark, Andrew E. and Oswald, Andrew J. (1996) “Satisfaction and comparison income,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 61, No. 3, pp. 359381.Google Scholar
Coase, R. (1995) “Interview with Gary Becker-Consumer behavior.” YouTube video, available at www.youtube.com/watch?v=edOr4RZ7_Ys.Google Scholar
Coate, Stephen and Conlin, Michael (2004) “A group rule-utilitarian approach to voter turnout: Theory and evidence,” American Economic Review, Vol. 94, No. 5, pp. 14761504.Google Scholar
Coates, Ta-Nehisi (2016) “’It’s what we do more than what we say’: Obama on race, identity, and the way forward,” The Atlantic, December, No. 22.Google Scholar
Cohen, Jonathan D., McClure, Samuel M. and Yu, Angela J. (2007) “Should I stay or should I go? How the human brain manages the trade-off between exploitation and exploration,” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, Vol. 362, No. 1481, pp. 933942.Google Scholar
Constantinople, Christine M., Piet, Alex T. and Brody, Carlos D. (2019) “An analysis of decision under risk in rats,” Current Biology, Vol. 29, No. 12, pp. 20662074.Google Scholar
Conte, Anna, Hey, John D. and Moffatt, Peter G. (2011) “Mixture models of choice under risk,” Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 162, No. 1, pp. 7988.Google Scholar
Cooper, W. S. (1989) “How evolutionary biology challenges the classical theory of rational choice,” Biology and Philosophy, Vol. 4, No. 4, pp. 457481.Google Scholar
Cornell, Bradford and Welch, Ivo (1996) “Culture, information, and screening discrimination,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 104, No. 3, pp. 542571.Google Scholar
Cox, James C., Friedman, Daniel and Sadiraj, Vjollca (2008) “Revealed altruism 1,” Econometrica, Vol. 76, No. 1, pp. 3169.Google Scholar
Cross, K. Patricia (1977) “Not can, but will college teaching be improved?New Directions for Higher Education, Vol. 1977, No. 17, pp. 115.Google Scholar
Cubitt, Robin P. and Sugden, Robert (2001) “On money pumps,” Games and Economic Behavior, Vol. 37, No. 1, pp. 121160.Google Scholar
Curtis, Valerie, de Barra, Micheal and Aunger, Robert (2011) “Disgust as an adaptive system for disease avoidance behaviour,” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, Vol. 366, No. 1563, pp. 389401.Google Scholar
Cushman, Fiery (2020) “Rationalization is rational,” Behavioral and Brain Sciences, Vol. 43, pp. 159.Google Scholar
Damasio, Antonio R. (2006) Descartes’ error. Random House.Google Scholar
Darwin, Charles (1859) The origin of species. London: John Murray.Google Scholar
Darwin, Charles (1871/1981) The descent of man, and selection in relation to sex. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Darwin, Charles (1897) The expression of the emotions in man and animals. D. Appleton and Company.Google Scholar
Dasgupta, Partha and Maskin, Eric (2005) “Uncertainty and hyperbolic discounting,” American Economic Review, Vol. 95, No. 4, pp. 12901299.Google Scholar
Davidson, Donald, Charles, John McKinsey, Chenoweth and Suppes, Patrick (1955) “Outlines of a formal theory of value, I,” Philosophy of Science, Vol. 22, No. 2, pp. 140160.Google Scholar
Dawes, Robyn M. and Thaler, Richard H. (1988) “Anomalies: Cooperation,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 2, No. 3, pp. 187197.Google Scholar
Dawkins, Richard (1976) The selfish gene. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Dawkins, Richard (1997) Climbing mount improbable. W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Dawkins, Richard (2008) River out of Eden: A Darwinian view of life. Basic Books.Google Scholar
De Freitas, Julian, Thomas, Kyle, DeScioli, Peter and Pinker, Steven (2019) “Common knowledge, coordination, and strategic mentalizing in human social life,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, Vol. 116, No. 28, pp. 1375113758.Google Scholar
De Vignemont, Frederique and Singer, Tania (2006) “The empathic brain: How, when and why?Trends in Cognitive Sciences, Vol. 10, No. 10, pp. 435441.Google Scholar
de Finetti, Bruno (1931) “Sul significato soggettivo della probabilità,” ńFundamenta Mathematicae, Vol. 17, pp. 298329.Google Scholar
de Condorcet, Jean Antoine Nicolas (1788) Essai sur la constitution et les fonctions des assemblées provinciales.Google Scholar
Debreu, Gerard (1960) “Review of RD Luce, Individual choice behavior: A theoretical analysis,” American Economic Review, Vol. 50, No. 1, pp. 186188.Google Scholar
Dekel, Eddie and Siniscalchi, Marciano (2015) “Epistemic game theory,” in Young, H. P. and Zamir, S., eds., Handbook of game theory with economic applications, vol. 4. Elsevier, pp. 619702.Google Scholar
Della Vigna, Stefano and Malmendier, Ulrike (2006) “Paying not to go to the gym,” American Economic Review, Vol. 96, No. 3, pp. 694719.Google Scholar
Dennett, Daniel (1996) Darwin’s dangerous idea: Evolution and the meaning of life. Simon and Schuster.Google Scholar
Dennett, Daniel Clement (1987) The intentional stance. MIT Press.Google Scholar
Descamps, Ambroise, Massoni, Sebastien, Page, Lionel et al. (2019) “Learning to hesitate,” Technical report.Google Scholar
Dobzhansky, Theodosius (1973) “Nothing in biology makes sense except in the light of evolution,” The American Biology Teacher, Vol. 35, No. 3, pp. 125129.Google Scholar
Doleac, Jennifer L. and Stein, Luke C. D. (2013) “The visible hand: Race and online market outcomes,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 123, No. 572, pp. F469F492.Google Scholar
Donihue, Colin M., Kowaleski, Alex M., Losos, Jonathan B., Algar, Adam C., Baeckens, Simon, Buchkowski, Robert W., Fabre, Anne-Claire, Frank, Hannah K., Geneva, Anthony J., Reynolds, R. Graham et al. (2020) “Hurricane effects on neotropical lizards span geographic and phylogenetic scales,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, Vol. 117, No. 19, pp. 1042910434.Google Scholar
Douglas, Karen M. and Leite, Ana C. (2017) “Suspicion in the workplace: Organizational conspiracy theories and work-related outcomes,” British Journal of Psychology, Vol. 108, No. 3, pp. 486506.Google Scholar
Drayton, Lindsey A., Brosnan, Sarah F., Carrigan, Jodi and Stoinski, Tara S. (2013) “Endowment effects in gorillas (Gorilla gorilla),” Journal of Comparative Psychology, Vol. 127, No. 4, p. 365.Google Scholar
Dressler, Joshua (1982) “Rethinking heat of passion: A defense in search of a rationale,” J. Crim. L. & Criminology, Vol. 73, p. 421.Google Scholar
Dubra, Juan, Maccheroni, Fabio and Ok, Efe A. (2004) “Expected utility theory without the completeness axiom,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 115, No. 1, pp. 118133.Google Scholar
Dufwenberg, Martin and Kirchsteiger, Georg (2004) “A theory of sequential reciprocity,” Games and Economic Behavior, Vol. 47, No. 2, pp. 268298.Google Scholar
Dunbar, Robin I. M. (2004) “Gossip in evolutionary perspective,” Review of General Psychology, Vol. 8, No. 2, pp. 100110.Google Scholar
Eagleman, David (2011) Incognito: The secret lives of the brain. Pantheon Books.Google Scholar
Easterlin, Richard A. (1974) “Does economic growth improve the human lot? Some empirical evidence,” in David, P. A. and Reder, M. W., eds., Nations and households in economic growth: Essays in honor of Moses Abramovitz. Elsevier, pp. 89125.Google Scholar
Edgeworth, Francis Ysidro (1881) Mathematical psychics: An essay on the application of mathematics to the moral sciences. Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Edwards, Ward (1954) “The theory of decision making,” Psychological Bulletin, Vol. 51, No. 4, p. 380.Google Scholar
Ely, Jeffrey C. (2011) “Kludged,” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, Vol. 3, No. 3, pp. 210231.Google Scholar
Engelmann, Jan M. and Tomasello, Michael (2019) “Children’s sense of fairness as equal respect,” Trends in Cognitive Sciences, Vol. 23, No. 6, pp. 454463.Google Scholar
Engler, Yola, Kerschbamer, Rudolf and Page, Lionel (2018) “Why did he do that? Using counterfactuals to study the effect of intentions in extensive form games,” Experimental Economics, Vol. 21, No. 1, pp. 126.Google Scholar
Enke, Benjamin and Graeber, Thomas (2019) “Cognitive uncertainty,” National Bureau of Economic Research, No. 26518.Google Scholar
Epley, Nicholas and Whitchurch, Erin (2008) “Mirror, mirror on the wall: Enhancement in self-recognition,” Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, Vol. 34, No. 9, pp. 11591170.Google Scholar
Epper, Thomas and Fehr-Duda, Helga (2012) “The missing link: Unifying risk taking and time discounting,” University of Zurich Department of Economics Working Paper, No. 96.Google Scholar
Erev, Ido, Wallsten, Thomas S. and Budescu, David V. (1994) “Simultaneous over and underconfidence: The role of error in judgment processes,” Psychological Review, Vol. 101, No. 3, p. 519.Google Scholar
Ericson, Keith Marzilli and Laibson, David (2018) “Intertemporal choice,” Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Erikson, Erik H. (1968) Identity: Youth and crisis. W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Eysenck, Hans J. (1985) Decline and fall of the Freudian empire. Pelican.Google Scholar
Falk, Armin, Fehr, Ernst and Fischbacher, Urs (2003) “On the nature of fair behavior,” Economic Inquiry, Vol. 41, No. 1, pp. 2026.Google Scholar
Fardouly, Jasmine, Diedrichs, Phillippa C., Vartanian, Lenny R. and Halliwell, Emma (2015) “Social comparisons on social media: The impact of Facebook on young women’s body image concerns and mood,” Body Image, Vol. 13, pp. 3845.Google Scholar
Feddersen, Timothy J. (2004) “Rational choice theory and the paradox of not voting,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 18, No. 1, pp. 99112.Google Scholar
Feddersen, Timothy and Sandroni, Alvaro (2006) “A theory of participation in elections,” American Economic Review, Vol. 96, No. 4, pp. 12711282.Google Scholar
Feltovich, Nick, Harbaugh, Richmond and To, Ted (2002) “Too cool for school? Signalling and countersignalling,” RAND Journal of Economics, pp. 630649.Google Scholar
Fessler, Daniel M. T., Eng, Serena J. and Navarrete, C. David (2005) “Elevated disgust sensitivity in the first trimester of pregnancy: Evidence supporting the compensatory prophylaxis hypothesis,” Evolution and Human Behavior, Vol. 26, No. 4, pp. 344351.Google Scholar
Fink, Philip W., Foo, Patrick S., and Warren, William H. (2009) “Catching fly balls in virtual reality: A critical test of the outfielder problem,” Journal of Vision, Vol. 9, No. 13, pp. 18.Google Scholar
Fischbacher, Urs and Gachter, Simon (2010) “Social preferences, beliefs, and the dynamics of free riding in public goods experiments,” American Economic Review, Vol. 100, No. 1, pp. 541556.Google Scholar
Fishburn, Peter C. and LaValle, Irving H. (1988) “Context-dependent choice with nonlinear and nontransitive preferences,” Econometrica, pp. 12211239.Google Scholar
Fishburn, Peter and Wakker, Peter (1995) “The invention of the independence condition for preferences,” Management Science, Vol. 41, No. 7, pp. 11301144.Google Scholar
Fiske, Alan Page and Tetlock, Philip E. (1997) “Taboo trade-offs: Reactions to transactions that transgress the spheres of justice,” Political Psychology, Vol. 18, No. 2, pp. 255297.Google Scholar
Fiske, Susan T. (2015) “Intergroup biases: A focus on stereotype content,” Current Opinion in Behavioral Sciences, Vol. 3, pp. 4550.Google Scholar
Fiske, Susan T. and Taylor, Shelley E. (1991) Social Cognition. McGraw-Hill Book Company.Google Scholar
Flood, Merrill M. (1958) “Some experimental games,” Management Science, Vol. 5, No. 1, pp. 526.Google Scholar
Fourcade, Marion, Ollion, Etienne and Algan, Yann (2015) “The superiority of economists,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 29, No. 1, pp. 89114.Google Scholar
Frank, Robert H. (1985) Choosing the right pond: Human behavior and the quest for status. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Frank, Robert H. (1987) “Shrewdly irrational,” Sociological Forum, Vol. 2, pp. 2141.Google Scholar
Frank, Robert H. (1988) Passions within reason: The strategic role of the emotions. W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Frank, Robert H., Gilovich, Thomas and Regan, Dennis T. (1993) “The evolution of one-shot cooperation: An experiment,” Ethology and Sociobiology, Vol. 14, No. 4, pp. 247256.Google Scholar
Frederick, Shane (2005) “Cognitive reflection and decision making,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 19, No. 4, pp. 2542.Google Scholar
Frederick, Shane, Loewenstein, George and O’Donoghue, Ted (2002) “Time discounting and time preference: A critical review,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 40, No. 2, pp. 351401.Google Scholar
Freud, Sigmund (1916–1917/1977) Introductory lectures on psychoanalysis, translated by J. Strachey. W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Friedman, James W. (2000) “A guided tour of the Folk Theorem,” in Norman, George and The, Jean Francois Thisse eds., Market structure and competition policy. Cambridge University Press, pp. 5169.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton (1953) Essays in positive economics. University of Chicago press.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton and Savage, Leonard J. (1948) “The utility analysis of choices involving risk,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 56, No. 4, pp. 279304.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton and Savage, Leonard J. (1952) “The expectedutility hypothesis and the measurability of utility,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 60, No. 6, pp. 463474.Google Scholar
Frymer-Kensky, Tikva (1980) “Tit for tat: The principle of equal retribution in Near Eastern and Biblical law,” The Biblical Archaeologist, Vol. 43, No. 4, pp. 230234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, Drew, Strack, Philipp and Strzalecki, Tomasz (2017) “Stochastic choice and optimal sequential sampling.” https://arxiv.org/abs/1505.03342.Google Scholar
Gabaix, Xavier and Laibson, David (2017) “Myopia and discounting,” Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Gabriel, Marsha T., Critelli, Joseph W., and Ee, Jullana S. (1994) “Narcissistic illusions in self-evaluations of intelligence and attractiveness,” Journal of Personality, Vol. 62, No. 1, pp. 143155.Google Scholar
Gambetta, Diego (2011) Codes of the underworld: How criminals communicate. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Gandolfi, Anna Sachko (2002/2018) Economics as an evolutionary science: From utility to fitness. Routledge.Google Scholar
Gelman, Andrew and Yao, Yuling (2020) “Holes in Bayesian statistics,” arXivpreprintarXiv:2002.06467.Google Scholar
Georgescu-Roegen, Nicholas (1936) “The pure theory of consumers behavior,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 50, No. 4, pp. 545593.Google Scholar
Gershman, Samuel J. and Bhui, Rahul (2020) “Rationally inattentive intertemporal choice,” Nature Communications, Vol. 11, No. 1, pp. 18.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, Gerd (2000) Adaptive thinking: Rationality in the real world. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, Gerd (2007) Gut feelings: The intelligence of the unconscious. Penguin.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, Gerd (2018) “The bias bias in behavioral economics,” Review of Behavioral Economics, Vol. 5, Nos. 3–4, pp. 303336.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, Gerd and Brighton, Henry (2009) “Homo heuristicus: Why biased minds make better inferences,” Topics in Cognitive Science, Vol. 1, No. 1, pp. 107143.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, Gerd and Goldstein, Daniel G. (1996) “Reasoning the fast and frugal way: Models of bounded rationality,” Psychological Review, Vol. 103, No. 4, p. 650.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, Gerd and Hoffrage, Ulrich (1995) “How to improve Bayesian reasoning without instruction: Frequency formats,” Psychological Review, Vol. 102, No. 4, p. 684.Google Scholar
Gilboa, Itzhak (2009) Theory of decision under uncertainty. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gilboa, Itzhak, Postlewaite, Andrew and Schmeidler, David (2009) “Is it always rational to satisfy Savage’s axioms?,” Economics & Philosophy, Vol. 25, No. 3, pp. 285296.Google Scholar
Gilliver, K. M. (2004) Caesar’s Gallic Wars 58–50 BC. Routledge.Google Scholar
Gilovich, Thomas and Griffin, Dale (2002) “Introduction-heuristics and biases: Then and now,” in Gilovich, T., Griffin, D. and Kahneman, D., eds., Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment. Cambridge University Press, pp. 118.Google Scholar
Gilovich, Thomas, Vallone, Robert and Tversky, Amos (1985) “The hot hand in basketball: On the misperception of random sequences,” Cognitive Psychology, Vol. 17, No. 3, pp. 295314.Google Scholar
Gintis, Herbert (2007) “A framework for the unification of the behavioral sciences,” Behavioral and Brain Sciences, Vol. 30, No. 1, pp. 116.Google Scholar
Glimcher, Paul W. (2011) Foundations of neuroeconomic analysis. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Goethals, George R. and Darley, John M. (1977) “Social comparison theory: An attributional approach,” in Suls, J. M. and Miller, R. L., eds., Social comparison processes: Theoretical and empirical perspectives. Hemisphere, pp. 259278.Google Scholar
Goffman, Erving (1959) The presentation of self in everyday life. Anchor Books.Google Scholar
Goffman, Erving (1971) Relations in public. Basic Books.Google Scholar
Gold, Joshua I. and Shadlen, Michael N. (2002) “Banburismus and the brain: Decoding the relationship between sensory stimuli, decisions, and reward,” Neuron, Vol. 36, No. 2, pp. 299308.Google Scholar
Goodman, Nelson (1965) Fact, fiction, and forecast. Bobbs-Merrill.Google Scholar
Gould, Stephen Jay and Lewontin, Richard C. (1979) “The spandrels of San Marco and the Panglossian paradigm: A critique of the adaptationist programme,” Proceedings of the Royal Society of London. Series B. Biological Sciences, Vol. 205, No. 1161, pp. 581598.Google Scholar
Green, Brett and Zwiebel, Jeffrey (2018) “The hot-hand fallacy: Cognitive mistakes or equilibrium adjustments? Evidence from major league baseball,” Management Science, Vol. 64, No. 11, pp. 53155348.Google Scholar
Green, Elliott (2021) “The politics of ethnic identity in sub-Saharan Africa,” Comparative Political Studies, Vol. 54, No. 7, pp. 11971226.Google Scholar
Green, Leonard and Myerson, Joel (1996) “Exponential versus hyperbolic discounting of delayed outcomes: Risk and waiting time,” American Zoologist, Vol. 36, No. 4, pp. 496505.Google Scholar
Grether, David M. and Plott, Charles R. (1979) “Economic theory of choice and the preference reversal phenomenon,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 69, No. 4, pp. 623638.Google Scholar
Grotius, Hugo (1625) De jure belli ac pacis. French National Library.Google Scholar
Guay, Brian and Johnston, Christopher (2021) “Ideological asymmetries and the determinants of politically motivated reasoning,” American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 66, No. 2, pp. 285301.Google Scholar
Gurdal, Mehmet Y., Miller, Joshua B. and Rustichini, Aldo (2013) “Why blame?Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 121, No. 6, pp. 12051247.Google Scholar
Güth, Werner, Schmittberger, Rolf and Schwarze, Bernd (1982) “An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, Vol. 3, No. 4, pp. 367388.Google Scholar
Haidt, Jonathan (2006) The happiness hypothesis: Putting ancient wisdom and philosophy to the test of modern science. Random House.Google Scholar
Haldeman, Harry R. and DiMona, Joseph (1978) The ends of power. Dell Publishing Company.Google Scholar
Halevy, Yoram (2008) “Strotz meets Allais: Diminishing impatience and the certainty effect,” American Economic Review, Vol. 98, No. 3, pp. 11451162.Google Scholar
Halevy, Yoram (2015) “Time consistency: Stationarity and time invariance,” Econometrica, Vol. 83, No. 1, pp. 335352.Google Scholar
Hamilton, William D. (1963) “The evolution of altruistic behavior,” The American Naturalist, Vol. 97, No. 896, pp. 354356.Google Scholar
Hamilton, William D. (1964) “The genetical evolution of social behaviour. II,” Journal of Theoretical Biology, Vol. 7, No. 1, pp. 1752.Google Scholar
Hamlin, Robert P. (2017) ““The gaze heuristic:” Biography of an adaptively rational decision process,” Topics in Cognitive Science, Vol. 9, No. 2, pp. 264288.Google Scholar
Hammerstein, Peter and Hagen, Edward H. (2005) “The second wave of evolutionary economics in biology,” Trends in Ecology & Evolution, Vol. 20, No. 11, pp. 604609.Google Scholar
Handa, Jagdish (1977) “Risk, probabilities, and a new theory of cardinal utility,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 85, No. 1, pp. 97122.Google Scholar
Harbaugh, Richmond and To, Theodore (2020) “False modesty: When disclosing good news looks bad,” Journal of Mathematical Economics, Vol. 87, pp. 4355.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. (1982) “Rule utilitarianism, rights, obligations and the theory of rational behavior,” in Papers in game theory. Springer, pp. 235253.Google Scholar
Haselton, Martie G., Bryant, Gregory A., Wilke, Andreas, Frederick, David A., Galperin, Andrew, Frankenhuis, Willem E. and Moore, Tyler (2009) “Adaptive rationality: An evolutionary perspective on cognitive bias,” Social Cognition, Vol. 27, No. 5, pp. 733763.Google Scholar
Haselton, Martie G. and Buss, David M. (2000) “Error management theory: A new perspective on biases in cross-sex mind reading,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, Vol. 78, No. 1, p. 81.Google Scholar
Haslam, S. Alexander, Reicher, Stephen D. and Platow, Michael J. (2010) The new psychology of leadership: Identity, influence and power. Psychology Press.Google Scholar
Hayden, Benjamin Y. (2016) “Time discounting and time preference in animals: A critical review,” Psychonomic Bulletin & Review, Vol. 23, No. 1, pp. 3953.Google Scholar
Heath, Chip, Larrick, Richard P. and Wu, George (1999) “Goals as reference points,” Cognitive Psychology, Vol. 38, No. 1, pp. 79109.Google Scholar
Heifetz, Aviad, Shannon, Chris and Spiegel, Yossi (2007a) “What to maximize if you must,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 133, No. 1, pp. 3157.Google Scholar
Heifetz, Aviad, Shannon, Chris and Spiegel, Yossi (2007b) “The dynamic evolution of preferences,” Economic Theory, Vol. 32, No. 2, pp. 251286.Google Scholar
Helvétius, Claude Adrien (1758) De l’esprit. Durand.Google Scholar
Henrich, Joseph (2004) “Cultural group selection, coevolutionary processes and large-scale cooperation,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, Vol. 53, No. 1, pp. 335.Google Scholar
Henrich, Joseph, Boyd, Robert, Bowles, Samuel, Camerer, Colin, Fehr, Ernst, Gintis, Herbert, McElreath, Richard, Alvard, Michael, Barr, Abigail, Ensminger, Jean et al. (2005) “‘Economic man’ in cross-cultural perspective: Behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies,” Behavioral and Brain Sciences, Vol. 28, No. 6, pp. 795815.Google Scholar
Herold, Florian and Netzer, Nick (2010) “Probability weighting as evolutionary second-best,” Technical report, working paper.Google Scholar
Hertwig, Ralph and Gigerenzer, Gerd (1999) “The ‘conjunction fallacy’ revisited: How intelligent inferences look like reasoning errors,” Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, Vol. 12, No. 4, pp. 275305.Google Scholar
Hilton, Denis J (1995) “The social context of reasoning: Conversational inference and rational judgment,” Psychological Bulletin, Vol. 118, No. 2, p. 248.Google Scholar
Hintze, Arend, Olson, Randal S, Adami, Christoph and Hertwig, Ralph (2015) “Risk sensitivity as an evolutionary adaptation,” Scientific Reports, Vol. 5, p. 8242.Google Scholar
Hirshleifer, David and Welch, Ivo (2002) “An economic approach to the psychology of change: Amnesia, inertia, and impulsiveness,” Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, Vol. 11, No. 3, pp. 379421.Google Scholar
Hirshleifer, Jack (1977) “Economics from a biological viewpoint,” The Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 20, No. 1, pp. 152.Google Scholar
Hirshleifer, Jack (1985) “The expanding domain of economics,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 75, No. 6, pp. 5368.Google Scholar
Hirshleifer, Jack (1987) “On the emotions as guarantors of threats and promises,” in J. E. Dupré, ed., The latest on the best: Essays on evolution and optimality. MIT Press, pp. 30726.Google Scholar
Ho, Benjamin (2021) Why Trust Matters: An Economist’s Guide to the Ties That Bind Us. Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Hobbes, Thomas (1651) Leviathan.Google Scholar
Hoffman, Elizabeth, McCabe, Kevin, Shachat, Keith and Smith, Vernon (1994) “Preferences, property rights, and anonymity in bargaining games,” Games and Economic Behavior, Vol. 7, No. 3, pp. 346380.Google Scholar
Hoffman, Elizabeth, McCabe, Kevin and Smith, Vernon L (1996) “Social distance and other-regarding behavior in dictator games,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 86, No. 3, pp. 653660.Google Scholar
Hoffman, Moshe, Hilbe, Christian and Nowak, Martin A. (2018) “The signal-burying game can explain why we obscure positive traits and good deeds,” Nature Human Behaviour, Vol. 2, No. 6, p. 397.Google Scholar
Hoffman, Moshe, Yoeli, Erez and Nowak, Martin A. (2015) “Cooperate without looking: Why we care what people think and not just what they do,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, Vol. 112, No. 6, pp. 17271732.Google Scholar
Hofstadter, Douglas R. (1983) “The prisoner’s dilemma computer tournaments and the evolution of cooperation,” Scientific American, Vol. 248, No. 5, pp. 1420.Google Scholar
Hornsey, Matthew J. and Esposo, Sarah (2009) “Resistance to group criticism and recommendations for change: Lessons from the intergroup sensitivity effect,” Social and Personality Psychology Compass, Vol. 3, No. 3, pp. 275291.Google Scholar
Huber, Joel, Payne, John W. and Puto, Christopher (1982) “Adding asymmetrically dominated alternatives: Violations of regularity and the similarity hypothesis,” Journal of Consumer Research, Vol. 9, No. 1, pp. 9098.Google Scholar
Hume, David (1739/2003) A treatise of human nature. Courier Corporation.Google Scholar
Hutcheson, Francis (1725) Inquiry into the original of our ideas of beauty and virtue.Google Scholar
Huttegger, Simon M. and Zollman, Kevin J. S. (2012) “Evolution, dynamics, and rationality: The limits of ESS methodology,” in Okasha, Samir and Binmore, Ken, eds., Evolution and rationality. Cambridge University Press, pp. 6783.Google Scholar
Iredale, Wendy and Vugt, Mark van (2012) “Altruism as showing off: A signalling perspective on promoting green behaviour and acts of kindness,” in Roberts, Craig, ed., Applied evolutionary psychology. Oxford University Press, pp. 173185.Google Scholar
Jean, Roger V. (2009) Phyllotaxis: A systemic study in plant morphogenesis. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Jevons, William Stanley (1879) The theory of political economy. Macmillan and Company.Google Scholar
Johnson, Dominic and Bering, Jesse (2006) “Hand of God, mind of man: Punishment and cognition in the evolution of cooperation,” Evolutionary Psychology, Vol. 4, No. 1, pp. 219233.Google Scholar
Johnson, Dominic D. P. and Fowler, James H. (2011) “The evolution of overconfidence,” Nature, Vol. 477, No. 7364, p. 317.Google Scholar
Jones, Adam G. and Ratterman, Nicholas L. (2009) “Mate choice and sexual selection: What have we learned since Darwin?,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, Vol. 106, Supplement No. 1, pp. 1000110008.Google Scholar
Jones, Owen D. (2000) “Time-shifted rationality and the law of law’s leverage: Behavioral economics meets behavioral biology,” Northwestern University Law Review, Vol. 95, p. 1141.Google Scholar
Jussim, Lee, Cain, Thomas R., Crawford, Jarret T., Harber, Kent and Cohen, Florette (2009) “The unbearable accuracy of stereotypes,” in Handbook of Prejudice, Stereotyping, and Discrimination, Vol. 199, p. 227.Google Scholar
Kagel, John H., Green, Leonard and Caraco, Thomas (1986) “When foragers discount the future: Constraint or adaptation?,” Animal Behaviour, Vol. 34, pp. 271283.Google Scholar
Kahan, Dan M., Peters, Ellen, Dawson, Erica and Slovic, Paul (2013) “Motivated numeracy and enlightened self-government,” Behavioural Public Policy, Vol. 1, pp. 5486.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel (2003) “A perspective on judgment and choice: Mapping bounded rationality,” American Psychologist, Vol. 58, No. 9, p. 697.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel (2011) Thinking, fast and slow. Macmillan.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, Knetsch, Jack L. and Thaler, Richard (1986) “Fairness as a constraint on profit seeking: Entitlements in the market,” The American Economic Review, pp. 728741.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos (1979) “Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk,” Econometrica, Vol. 47, No. 2, pp. 263292.Google Scholar
Kamenica, Emir (2008) “Contextual inference in markets: On the informational content of product lines,” American Economic Review, Vol. 98, No. 5, pp. 21272149.Google Scholar
Kaplan, Hillard S., Lancaster, Jane B., Johnson, Sara E. and Bock, John A. (1995) “Does observed fertility maximize fitness among New Mexican men?,” Human Nature, Vol. 6, No. 4, pp. 325360.Google Scholar
Karlan, Dean and McConnell, Margaret A. (2014) “Hey look at me: The effect of giving circles on giving,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, Vol. 106, pp. 402412.Google Scholar
Karni, Edi and Vierø, Marie-Louise (2017) “Awareness of unawareness: A theory of decision making in the face of ignorance,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 168, pp. 301328.Google Scholar
Keeley, Lawrence H., 1996. War before civilization. OUP USA.Google Scholar
Keren, Gideon and Roelofsma, Peter (1995) “Immediacy and certainty in intertemporal choice,” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, Vol. 63, No. 3, pp. 287297.Google Scholar
Knight, Frank H. (1921) Risk, uncertainty and profit. Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Knill, David C. and Pouget, Alexandre (2004) “The Bayesian brain: The role of uncertainty in neural coding and computation,” Trends in Neurosciences, Vol. 27, No. 12, pp. 712719.Google Scholar
Kolmogorov, Andrĕı Nikolaevich and Bharucha-Reid, Albert T. (1933/2018) Foundations of the theory of probability, 2nd English edition. Courier Dover Publications.Google Scholar
Koopmans, Tjalling C. (1960) “Stationary ordinal utility and impatience,” Econometrica, pp. 287309.Google Scholar
Köszegi, Botond and Rabin, Matthew (2006) “A model of reference-dependent preferences,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 121, No. 4, pp. 11331165.Google Scholar
Krasnova, Hanna, Wenninger, Helena, Widjaja, Thomas and Buxmann, Peter (2013) “Envy on Facebook: A hidden threat to users’ life satisfaction?”, in Proceedings of the 11th International Conference on Wirtschaftsinformatik (WI2013), Universität Leipzig, Germany, 27 February–3 January 2013.Google Scholar
Kuhn, Thomas S. (1962/2012) The structure of scientific revolutions. University of Chicago press.Google Scholar
Kühne, Thomas (2011) “The pleasure of terror: Belonging through genocide,” in Pleasure and power in Nazi Germany. Springer, pp. 234255.Google Scholar
Kunda, Ziva (1987) “Motivated inference: Self-serving generation and evaluation of causal theories,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, Vol. 53, No. 4, p. 636.Google Scholar
Laibson, David (1997) “Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 112, No. 2, pp. 443478.Google Scholar
Lakshminaryanan, Venkat, Chen, M. Keith and Santos, Laurie R. (2008) “Endowment effect in capuchin monkeys,” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, Vol. 363, No. 1511, pp. 38373844.Google Scholar
Laplace, Pierre-Simon (1814) Essai philosophique sur les probabilités. Paris: Mme Ve Courcier.Google Scholar
Laughlin, Simon (1981) “A simple coding procedure enhances a neuron’s information capacity,” Zeitschrift für Naturforschung C, Vol. 36, Nos. 9–10, pp. 910912.Google Scholar
Lazear, Edward P. (2000) “Economic imperialism,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 115, No. 1, pp. 99146.Google Scholar
Lendon, Jon E. (2005) Soldiers and ghosts: A history of battle in classical antiquity. Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Levine, David K. (1998) “Modeling altruism and spitefulness in experiments,” Review of Economic Dynamics, Vol. 1, No. 3, pp. 593622.Google Scholar
Levitt, Steven D. and Dubner, Stephen J. (2005) Freakonomics. William Morrow.Google Scholar
Li, Shengwu and Yu, Ning Neil (2018) “Context-dependent choice as explained by foraging theory,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 175, pp. 159177.Google Scholar
Lichtenstein, Sarah and Slovic, Paul (1971) “Reversals of preference between bids and choices in gambling decisions,” Journal of Experimental Psychology, Vol. 89, No. 1, p. 46.Google Scholar
Lichtenstein, Sarah and Slovic, Paul (2006) The construction of preference. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lieder, Falk and Griffiths, Thomas L. (2020) “Resource-rational analysis: Understanding human cognition as the optimal use of limited computational resources,” Behavioral and Brain Sciences, Vol. 43.Google Scholar
Lieder, Falk, Griffiths, Thomas L. and Hsu, Ming (2018) “Overrepresentation of extreme events in decision making reflects rational use of cognitive resources,” Psychological Review, Vol. 125, No. 1, p. 1.Google Scholar
Locke, John (1689) An essay concerning human understanding.Google Scholar
Loomes, Graham and Sugden, Robert (1982) “Regret theory: An alternative theory of rational choice under uncertainty,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 92, No. 368, pp. 805824.Google Scholar
Loury, Glenn C. (1994) “Self-censorship in public discourse: A theory of ‘political correctness’ and related phenomena,” Rationality and Society, Vol. 6, No. 4, pp. 428461.Google Scholar
Luce, R. Duncan (1958) Individual choice behavior: A theoretical analysis. John Wiley.Google Scholar
Luce, R. Duncan and Raiffa, Howard (1957) Games and decisions. John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Luce, R. Duncan et al. (1986) Response times: Their role in inferring elementary mental organization. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
MacCrimmon, Kenneth R. (1968) “Descriptive and normative implications of the decision-theory postulates,” in Risk and uncertainty. Springer, pp. 332.Google Scholar
Malmendier, Ulrike and Tate, Geoffrey (2005) “Does overconfidence affect corporate investment? CEO overconfidence measures revisited,” European Financial Management, Vol. 11, No. 5, pp. 649659.Google Scholar
Mann, Michael (1986) The sources of social power, vol. 1: A history of power from the beginning to AD 1760. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Marcus, Gary (2009) Kluge: The haphazard evolution of the human mind. Houghton Mifflin Harcourt.Google Scholar
Markowitz, Harry (1952) “The utility of wealth,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 60, No. 2, pp. 151158.Google Scholar
Marschak, Jacob (1950) “Rational behavior, uncertain prospects, and measurable utility,” Econometrica, pp. 111141.Google Scholar
Mas-Colell, Andreu, Whinston, Michael Dennis, Green, Jerry R. et al. (1995) Microeconomic theory, vol. 1. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Mauss, Marcel (1990) The gift: The form and reason for exchange in archaic societies. Routledge.Google Scholar
Mayberry, John P. (1970) “Structural requirements for abstract-mode models of passenger transportation,” in Quandt, R. E., ed., The demand for travel: Theory and measurement.Google Scholar
Maynard Smith, John (1982) Evolution and the theory of games. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
McBeath, Michael K., Shaffer, Dennis M and Kaiser, Mary K. (1995) “How baseball outfielders determine where to run to catch fly balls,” Science, Vol. 268, No. 5210, pp. 569573.Google Scholar
McClennen, Edward (2009) “The Normative Status of the Independence Principle,” in Anand, Paul, Pattanaik, Prasanta and Puppe, Clemens, eds., The handbook of rational and social choice. Oxford University Press, pp. 140155.Google Scholar
McFadden, Daniel (1973) “Conditional logit analysis of qualitative choice behavior,” in P. Zarembka, ed., Frontiers in econometrics. New York: Academic Press, pp. 105142.Google Scholar
McFadden, Daniel (2001) “Economic choices,” American Economic Review, Vol. 91, No. 3, pp. 351378.Google Scholar
McLean, Iain (1995) “Independence of irrelevant alternatives before Arrow,” Mathematical Social Sciences, Vol. 30, No. 2, pp. 107126.Google Scholar
McNamara, John M. and Houston, Alasdair I. (1987) “Starvation and predation as factors limiting population size,” Ecology, Vol. 68, No. 5, pp. 15151519.Google Scholar
Meijaard, Jaap P., Papadopoulos, Jim M., Ruina, Andy and Schwab, Arend L. (2007) “Linearized dynamics equations for the balance and steer of a bicycle: A benchmark and review,” Proceedings of the Royal Society A: Mathematical, Physical and Engineering Sciences, Vol. 463, No. 2084, pp. 19551982.Google Scholar
Mellers, Barbara, Hertwig, Ralph and Kahneman, Daniel (2001) “Do frequency representations eliminate conjunction effects? An exercise in adversarial collaboration,” Psychological Science, Vol. 12, No. 4, pp. 269275.Google Scholar
Mély, David A., Linsley, Drew and Serre, Thomas (2018) “Complementary surrounds explain diverse contextual phenomena across visual modalities,” Psychological Review, Vol. 125, No. 5, p. 769.Google Scholar
Mercier, Hugo and Sperber, Dan (2011) “Why do humans reason? Arguments for an argumentative theory,” Behavioral and Brain Sciences, Vol. 34, No. 2, pp. 5774.Google Scholar
Mertens, Jean-Francois and Zamir, Shmuel (1985) “Formulation of Bayesian analysis for games with incomplete information,” International Journal of Game Theory, Vol. 14, No. 1, pp. 129.Google Scholar
Metz, J. A. J., Mylius, S. D. and Diekmann, O. (2008) “When does evolution optimize?,” Evolutionary Ecology Research, Vol. 10, pp. 629654.Google Scholar
Michell, Joel (1993) “The origins of the representational theory of measurement: Helmholtz, Hölder, and Russell,” Studies in History and Philosophy of Science Part A, Vol. 24, No. 2, pp. 185206.Google Scholar
Milkman, Katherine L., Rogers, Todd and Bazerman, Max H. (2009) “Highbrow films gather dust: Time-inconsistent preferences and online DVD rentals,” Management Science, Vol. 55, No. 6, pp. 10471059.Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart (1836) “On the definition of political economy; and on the method of investigation proper to it.”Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart (1861) Utilitarianism.Google Scholar
Miller, Joshua B. and Sanjurjo, Adam (2014) A cold shower for the hot hand fallacy (No. 518). IGIER working paper.Google Scholar
Miller, Joshua B. and Sanjurjo, Adam (2018) “Surprised by the hot hand fallacy? A truth in the law of small numbers,” Econometrica, Vol. 86, No. 6, pp. 20192047.Google Scholar
Mischel, Walter and Ebbesen, Ebbe B. (1970) “Attention in delay of gratification,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, Vol. 16, No. 2, p. 329.Google Scholar
Mischel, Walter, Ebbesen, Ebbe B. and Zeiss, Antonette Raskoff (1972) “Cognitive and attentional mechanisms in delay of gratification,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, Vol. 21, No. 2, p. 204.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Kevin J. (2020) Innate: How the wiring of our brains shapes who we are. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Mobbs, Dean, Trimmer, Pete C., Blumstein, Daniel T. and Dayan, Peter (2018) “Foraging for foundations in decision neuroscience: Insights from ethology,” Nature Reviews Neuroscience, Vol. 19, No. 7, pp. 419427.Google Scholar
Modelling Animal Decisions Group, Fawcett, Tim W., Fallenstein, Benja, Higginson, Andrew D., Houston, Alasdair I., Mallpress, Dave E. W., Trimmer, Pete C. and McNamara, John M. (2014) “The evolution of decision rules in complex environments,” Trends in Cognitive Sciences, Vol. 18, No. 3, pp. 153161.Google Scholar
Monger, G. (2004) Marriage customs of the world: From henna to honeymoons. Abcclio.Google Scholar
Montague, Read (2006) Why choose this book? How we make decisions. E. P. Dutton.Google Scholar
Morris, Stephen (2001) “Political correctness,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 109, No. 2, pp. 231265.Google Scholar
Moscati, Ivan (2016) “Retrospectives: How economists came to accept expected utility theory: The case of Samuelson and Savage,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 30, No. 2, pp. 219236.Google Scholar
Moscati, Ivan (2018) Measuring utility: From the marginal revolution to behavioral economics. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Mosteller, Frederick and Nogee, Philip (1951) “An experimental measurement of utility,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 59, No. 5, pp. 371404.Google Scholar
Mullen, Brian and Hu, Litze (1989) “Perceptions of ingroup and outgroup variability: A meta-analytic integration,” Basic and Applied Social Psychology, Vol. 10, No. 3, pp. 233252.Google Scholar
Naimark, Norman M. (2017) Genocide: A world history. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Nash, John F. (1950) “The bargaining problem,” Econometrica, Vol. 18, No. 2, pp. 155162.Google Scholar
Nesse, R. M. (2001) “The smoke detector principle: Natural selection and the regulation of defensive responses,” Annals of the New York Academy of Sciences, Vol. 935, pp. 7585.Google Scholar
Netzer, Nick (2009) “Evolution of time preferences and attitudes toward risk,” American Economic Review, Vol. 99, No. 3, pp. 937955.Google Scholar
Neuberg, Steven L., Kenrick, Douglas T. and Schaller, Mark (2011) “Human threat management systems: Self-protection and disease avoidance,” Neuroscience & Biobehavioral Reviews, Vol. 35, No. 4, pp. 10421051.Google Scholar
Newton, Isaac (1687/1999) The Principia: Mathematical principles of natural philosophy. University of California Press.Google Scholar
Nielsen, K. and Rehbeck, J., 2022. When Choices are mistakes. American Economic Review, 112(7), pp. 223768.Google Scholar
Nietzsche, Friedrich Wilhelm (1882/2001) The gay science. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Nisbett, Richard E. and Cohen, Dov (1996) Culture of honor: The psychology of violence in the south. Westview Press.Google Scholar
Norenzayan, Ara and Shariff, Azim F. (2008) “The origin and evolution of religious prosociality,” Science, Vol. 322, No. 5898, pp. 5862.Google Scholar
Nowak, Martin and Sigmund, Karl (1993) “A strategy of win-stay, lose-shift that outperforms tit-for-tat in the Prisoner’s Dilemma game,” Nature, Vol. 364, No. 6432, p. 56.Google Scholar
Nowak, Martin A. and Sigmund, Karl (2005) “Evolution of indirect reciprocity,” Nature, Vol. 437, No. 7063, pp. 12911298.Google Scholar
Nozick, Robert (1974) Anarchy, state, and utopia. Basic Books.Google Scholar
O’Donoghue, Ted and Sprenger, Charles (2018) “Reference-dependent preferences,” in Ericson, K. M., Laibson, D., Bernheim, B. D. and Stefano, D., eds., Handbook of behavioral economics: Foundations and applications, Vol. 1, p. 1.Google Scholar
Oesch, Daniel (2008) “Explaining workers’ support for right-wing populist parties in Western Europe: Evidence from Austria, Belgium, France, Norway, and Switzerland,” International Political Science Review, Vol. 29, No. 3, pp. 349373.Google Scholar
Okabe, Takuya (2015) “Biophysical optimality of the golden angle in phyllotaxis,” Scientific Reports, Vol. 5, p. 15358.Google Scholar
Okabe, Takuya, Ishida, Atsushi and Yoshimura, Jin (2019) “The unified rule of phyllotaxis explaining both spiral and non-spiral arrangements,” Journal of the Royal Society Interface, Vol. 16, No. 151, pp. 17.Google Scholar
Okasha, Samir (2018) Agents and goals in evolution. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Okasha, Samir and Binmore, Ken (2012) Evolution and rationality: Decisions, cooperation and strategic behaviour. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Olberg, R. M., Worthington, A. H., and Venator, K. R. (2000) “Prey pursuit and interception in dragonflies,” Journal of Comparative Physiology A, Vol. 186, No. 2, pp. 155162.Google Scholar
Oliver, J. Eric and Wood, Thomas (2014) “Medical conspiracy theories and health behaviors in the United States,” JAMA Internal Medicine, Vol. 174, No. 5, pp. 817818.Google Scholar
Orr, H. Allen (2009) “Fitness and its role in evolutionary genetics,” Nature Reviews Genetics, Vol. 10, No. 8, pp. 531539.Google Scholar
Osborne, Martin J. and Rubinstein, Ariel (1994) A course in game theory. MIT Press.Google Scholar
Page, Lionel (2020) “The ethics of social choices and the role of economists in a pandemic,” Journal of Behavioral Economics for Policy, Vol. 4, No. 8, pp. 1722.Google Scholar
Parekh, Bhikhu (2016) Bentham’s political thought. Routledge.Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo (1906/2014) Manual of political economy: A critical and variorum edition. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Persky, Joseph (1995) “The ethology of homo economicus,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 9, No. 2, pp. 221231.Google Scholar
Phelps, Edmund S. (1972) “The statistical theory of racism and sexism,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 62, No. 4, pp. 659661.Google Scholar
Phillips, Lawrence D. and von Winterfeldt, Detlof (2007) “5 reflections on the contributions of Ward Edwards to decision analysis and behavioral research,” in Edwards, Ward, Miles, Ralph F. Jr., von Winterfeldt, Detlof, eds., Advances in decision analysis: From foundations to applications. Cambridge University Press, p. 71.Google Scholar
Pinker, Steven (2011a) The better angels of our nature: The decline of violence in history and its causes. Penguin UK.Google Scholar
Pinker, Steven (2011b) “Representations and decision rules in the theory of self-deception,” Behavioral and Brain Sciences, Vol. 34, No. 1, pp. 3537.Google Scholar
Pinker, Steven (2021) Rationality: What it is, why it seems scarce, why it matters. Penguin UK.Google Scholar
Pinker, Steven, Nowak, Martin A., and Lee, James J. (2008) “The logic of indirect speech,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, Vol. 105, No. 3, pp. 833838.Google Scholar
Planck, Max (1950) Scientific autobiography and other papers. Williams and Northgate.Google Scholar
Plato (375 BC) The Republic.Google Scholar
(490–420 BCE) Protagoras.Google Scholar
Poddiakov, Alexander N. (2013) “Catching a a flying ball: Is that really that easy? A contributionv to the critique of G. Gigerenzer’s approach,” in Egorov, A. G. and Selivanov, V. V., eds., Psychologia Kognitivnykh Processov: Materialy. Smolensk: Smolensk State University, pp. 8386.Google Scholar
Poon, Kai-Tak and Wong, Wing-Yan (2018) “Stuck on the train of ruminative thoughts: The effect of aggressive fantasy on subjective well-being,” Journal of Interpersonal Violence, Vol. 36, Nos. 11–12, pp. NP6390NP6410.Google Scholar
Popper, Karl (1945/2005) The logic of scientific discovery. Routledge.Google Scholar
Popper, Karl (1948) Objective knowledge: An evolutionary approach. Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Poundstone, William (1993) Prisoner’s Dilemma: John von Neumann, game theory and the puzzle of the bomb. Anchor.Google Scholar
Preston, Malcolm G. and Baratta, Philip (1948) “An experimental study of the auction-value of an uncertain outcome,” The American Journal of Psychology, Vol. 61, No. 2, pp. 183193.Google Scholar
Pribram, Karl (1983) A history of economic reasoning. Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Price, Michael Holton and Jones, James Holland (2020) “Fitness-maximizers employ pessimistic probability weighting for decisions under risk,” Evolutionary Human Sciences, Vol. 2, pp. 132.Google Scholar
Prusinkiewicz, Przemyslaw and Lindenmayer, Aristid (2012) The algorithmic beauty of plants. Springer Science + Business Media.Google Scholar
Quiggin, John (1982) “A theory of anticipated utility,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, Vol. 3, No. 4, pp. 323343.Google Scholar
Quine, Willard V. (1969) “Natural kinds,” in Rescher, Nicholas, ed., Essays in honor of Carl G. Hempel. Springer, pp. 523.Google Scholar
Rabin, Matthew (1993) “Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 83, No. 5, pp. 12811302.Google Scholar
Radner, Roy and Marschak, Jacob (1954) “Note on some proposed decision criteria,” in Thrall, R. M., Coombs, C. H. and Davis, R. L., eds., Decision process. Wiley.Google Scholar
Ramsey, Frank Plumpton (1928) “A mathematical theory of saving,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 38, No. 152, pp. 543559.Google Scholar
Ransford, H. Chris (2015) “The 8 most complex object in the known universe,” in The far horizons of time. Sciendo Migration, pp. 3235.Google Scholar
Rawls, John (1971) A theory of justice. Belknap.Google Scholar
Ray, Paramesh (1973) “Independence of irrelevant alternatives,” Econometrica, pp. 987991.Google Scholar
Rayo, Luis and Becker, Gary S. (2007) “Evolutionary efficiency and happiness,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 115, No. 2, pp. 302337.Google Scholar
Redelmeier, Donald A. and Tversky, Amos (1992) “On the framing of multiple prospects,” Psychological Science, Vol. 3, No. 3, pp. 191193.Google Scholar
Ridley, J. N. (1982) “Packing efficiency in sunflower heads,” Mathematical Biosciences, Vol. 58, No. 1, pp. 129139.Google Scholar
Rieskamp, Jörg, Busemeyer, Jerome R. and Mellers, Barbara A. (2006) “Extending the bounds of rationality: Evidence and theories of preferential choice,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 44, No. 3, pp. 631661.Google Scholar
Robbins, Lionel (2007) An essay on the nature and significance of economic science. Ludwig von Mises Institute.Google Scholar
Robinson, Joan (1953) “The production function and the theory of capital,” The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 21, No. 2, pp. 81106.Google Scholar
Robson, Arthur and Samuelson, Larry (2011) “The evolution of decision and experienced utilities,” Theoretical Economics, Vol. 6, No. 3, pp. 311339.Google Scholar
Robson, Arthur J. (2001) “The biological basis of economic behavior,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 39, No. 1, pp. 1133.Google Scholar
Robson, Arthur J. and Samuelson, Larry (2007) “The evolution of intertemporal preferences,” American Economic Review, Vol. 97, No. 2, pp. 496500.Google Scholar
Robson, Arthur J. and Samuelson, Larry (2009) “The evolution of time preference with aggregate uncertainty,” American Economic Review, Vol. 99, No. 5, pp. 19251953.Google Scholar
Robson, A. J., Whitehead, L. A. and Robalino, N. (2018) Adaptive hedonic utility. Working paper.Google Scholar
Roller, Steve (2012) “Let’s write a swimming pool,” American Writers and Artists Inc., www.awai.com/2012/02/lets-write-a-swimming-pool/.Google Scholar
Rose, Arnold M. (1957) “A study of irrational judgments,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 65, No. 5, pp. 394402.Google Scholar
Ross, Michael and Sicoly, Fiore (1979) “Egocentric biases in availability and attribution,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, Vol. 37, No. 3, p. 322.Google Scholar
Rousseau, Jean-Jacques (1755/1999) Discourse on the origin of inequality. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Roymans, Nico (2017) “A Roman massacre in the far north: Caesar’s annihilation of the Tencteri and Usipetes in the Dutch river area,” in Fernández-Götz, M. and Roymans, N., eds., Conflict archaeology: Materialities of collective violence from prehistory to Late Antiquity. Routledge, pp. 167181.Google Scholar
Rubin, Paul H. and Paul, Chris W. (1979) “An evolutionary model of taste for risk,” Economic Inquiry, Vol. 17, No. 4, pp. 585596.Google Scholar
Rubinstein, Ariel (1989) “The Electronic Mail Game: Strategic Behavior under ‘almost common knowledge’,” The American Economic Review Vol. 79, No. 3, pp. 385391.Google Scholar
Saleh, Mohamed (2018) “On the road to heaven: Taxation, conversions, and the Coptic-Muslim socioeconomic gap in medieval Egypt,” The Journal of Economic History, Vol. 78, No. 2, pp. 394434.Google Scholar
Sally, David (2005) “Can I say ‘bobobo’ and mean ‘There’s no such thing as cheap talk’?Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, Vol. 57, No. 3, pp. 245266.Google Scholar
Samuels, Richard, Stich, Stephen and Bishop, Michael (2002) “Ending the rationality wars: How to make disputes about human rationality disappear,” in Elio, Renee, ed., Common sense, reasoning and rationality. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Larry (2004) “Information-based relative consumption effects,” Econometrica, Vol. 72, No. 1, pp. 93118.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Larry and Swinkels, Jeroen M. (2006) “Information, evolution and utility,” Theoretical Economics, Vol. 1, No. 1, pp. 119142.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A (1937) “A. note on measurement of utility,” The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 4, No. 2, pp. 155161.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A (1950) “Probability and the attempts to measure utility,” Economic Review (Japanese), Vol. 1, No. 3, pp. 167173.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A (1952) “Probability, utility, and the independence axiom,” Econometrica, Vol. 20, No. 4, pp. 670678.Google Scholar
Savage, L. J. (1954). The foundations of statistics. Wiley.Google Scholar
Savage, Leonard J. (1951) “The theory of statistical decision,” Journal of the American Statistical Association, Vol. 46, No. 253, pp. 5567.Google Scholar
Savage, Leonard J. (1972) The foundations of statistics. Courier Corporation.Google Scholar
Sayer, Andrew (1997) “Essentialism, social constructionism, and beyond,” The Sociological Review, Vol. 45, No. 3, pp. 453487.Google Scholar
Schauer, Frederick and Zeckhauser, Richard J. (2007) “Paltering,” SSRN working paper, http://ssrn.com/abstract=832634.Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. (1960/1980) The strategy of conflict. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Schipper, Burkhard C. (2014) “Unawareness: A gentle introduction to both the literature and the special issue,” Mathematical Social Sciences, Vol. 70, pp. 19.Google Scholar
Schkade, David A. and Kahneman, Daniel (1998) “Does living in California make people happy? A focusing illusion in judgments of life satisfaction,” Psychological Science, Vol. 9, No. 5, pp. 340346.Google Scholar
Schmeidler, David (1989) “Subjective probability and expected utility without additivity,” Econometrica, pp. 571587.Google Scholar
Schroeder, Juliana, Caruso, Eugene M. and Epley, Nicholas (2016) “Many hands make overlooked work: Over-claiming of responsibility increases with group size,” Journal of Experimental Psychology: Applied, Vol. 22, No. 2, p. 238.Google Scholar
Schultz, Wolfram (2007) “Behavioral dopamine signals,” Trends in Neurosciences, Vol. 30, No. 5, pp. 203210.Google Scholar
Schwardmann, Peter and Van der Weele, Joel (2019) “Deception and self-deception,” Nature Human Behaviour, Vol. 3, No. 10, pp. 10551061.Google Scholar
Schwarz, Norbert, Strack, Fritz, Hilton, Denis and Naderer, Gabi (1991) “Base rates, representativeness, and the logic of conversation: The contextual relevance of ‘irrelevant’ information,” Social Cognition, Vol. 9, No. 1, pp. 6784.Google Scholar
Seabright, Paul (2010) The company of strangers: A natural history of economic life, revised edition. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Sell, Aaron, Tooby, John and Cosmides, Leda (2009) “Formidability and the logic of human anger,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, Vol. 106, No. 35, pp. 1507315078.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya (1993) “Internal consistency of choice,” Econometrica, Vol. 61, No. 3, pp. 495521.Google Scholar
Shackle, G. L. S. (1941) “A means of promoting investment,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 51, Nos. 202–203, pp. 249260.Google Scholar
Shaffer, Dennis M., Krauchunas, Scott M., Marianna Eddy and Michael K. McBeathGoogle Scholar
Shaffer, Dennis M., Krauchunas, Scott M. (2004) “How dogs navigate to catch Frisbees,” Psychological Science, Vol. 15, No. 7, pp. 437441.Google Scholar
Sharot, Tali, Velasquez, Cristina M. and Dolan, Raymond J. (2010) “Do decisions shape preference? Evidence from blind choice,” Psychological Science, Vol. 21, No. 9, pp. 12311235.Google Scholar
Shayo, Moses (2009) “A model of social identity with an application to political economy: Nation, class, and redistribution,” American Political Science Review, Vol. 103, No. 2, pp. 147174.Google Scholar
Shayo, Moses (2020) “Social identity and economic policy,” Annual Review of Economics, Vol. 12, pp. 355389.Google Scholar
Shoda, Yuichi, Mischel, Walter and Peake, Philip K. (1990) “Predicting adolescent cognitive and self-regulatory competencies from preschool delay of gratification: Identifying diagnostic conditions.,” Developmental Psychology, Vol. 26, No. 6, p. 978.Google Scholar
Shubik, Martin (1959) Strategy and market structure: Competition, oligopoly, and the theory of games. Wiley.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. (1957) Administrative behavior: A study of decision-making processes in administrative organization. Macmillan.Google Scholar
Singer, Tania, Seymour, Ben, O’Doherty, John, Kaube, Holger, Dolan, Raymond J. and Frith, Chris D. (2004) “Empathy for pain involves the affective but not sensory components of pain,” Science, Vol. 303, No. 5661, pp. 11571162.Google Scholar
Skyrms, Brian (2001) “The stag hunt,” in Proceedings and Addresses of the American Philosophical Association, Vol. 75, pp. 3141. JSTOR.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam (1759/2010) The theory of moral sentiments. Penguin.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam (1776/2019) The wealth of nations. Courier Dover Publications.Google Scholar
Smith, Megan K., Trivers, Robert and von Hippel, William (2017) “Self-deception facilitates interpersonal persuasion,” Journal of Economic Psychology, Vol. 63, pp. 93101.Google Scholar
Solda, Alice, Ke, Changxia, von Hippel, Bill and Page, Lionel (2020) “Absolute vs. relative success: Why overconfidence is an inefficient equilibrium.” Mimeo.Google Scholar
Solda, Alice, Ke, Changxia, Page, Lionel and Bill von Hippel (2019) “Strategically delusional,” working paper, GATE Lyon Saint-Etienne.Google Scholar
Solnick, Sara J. and Hemenway, David (1998) “Is more always better? A survey on positional concerns,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, Vol. 37, No. 3, pp. 373383.Google Scholar
Soman, Dilip (2015) The last mile: Creating social and economic value from behavioral insights. University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Sozou, Peter D. (1998) “On hyperbolic discounting and uncertain hazard rates,” Proceedings of the Royal Society of London. Series B: Biological Sciences, Vol. 265, No. 1409, pp. 20152020.Google Scholar
Sozou, Peter D. and Seymour, Robert M. (2005) “Costly but worthless gifts facilitate courtship,” Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, Vol. 272, No. 1575, pp. 18771884.Google Scholar
Spencer, Herbert (1864) The principles of biology. Appleton.Google Scholar
Sperber, Dan (1994) “The modularity of thought and the epidemiology of representations,” in Tooby, J., Leslie, A. M., Sperber, D., Caramazza, A., Hillis, A. E., Leek, E. C., Miozzo, M. and Cosmides, L., eds., Mapping the mind: Domain specificity in cognition and culture. Cambridge University Press, pp. 3967.Google Scholar
Spiegler, Rani (2019) “Behavioral economics and the atheoretical style,” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, Vol. 11, No. 2, pp.173194.Google Scholar
Spinoza, Benedict (1670/1958) The political works, ed. and trans. Wernham, A. G.. Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Stanford, P. Kyle (2018) “The difference between ice cream and Nazis: Moral externalization and the evolution of human cooperation,” Behavioral and Brain Sciences, Vol. 41, pp. 149.Google Scholar
Stanovich, Keith E. and West, Richard F. (2000) “Individual differences in reasoning: Implications for the rationality debate?,” Behavioral and Brain Sciences, Vol. 23, No. 5, pp. 645665.Google Scholar
Steiner, Jakub and Stewart, Colin (2016) “Perceiving prospects properly,” American Economic Review, Vol. 106, No. 7, pp. 16011631.Google Scholar
Stewart-Williams, Steve (2018) The ape that understood the universe: How the mind and culture evolve. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Stigler, George (1981) “Economics or ethics?,” in McMurrin, Sterling M., ed., The Tanner lectures on human values, Vol. 2. University of Utah Press, pp. 143191.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J. and Becker, Gary S. (1977) “De gustibus non est disputandum,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 67, No. 2, pp. 7690.Google Scholar
Straub, Paul G. and Murnighan, J. Keith (1995) “An experimental investigation of ultimatum games: Information, fairness, expectations, and lowest acceptable offers,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, Vol. 27, No. 3, pp. 345364.Google Scholar
Strotz, Robert Henry (1955) “Myopia and inconsistency in dynamic utility maximization,” The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 23, No. 3, pp. 165180.Google Scholar
Sugden, Robert (1985) “Why be consistent? A critical analysis of consistency requirements in choice theory,” Economica, Vol. 52, No. 206, pp. 167183.Google Scholar
Sugden, Robert (1991) “Rational choice: A survey of contributions from economics and philosophy,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 101, No. 407, pp. 751785.Google Scholar
Sugden, Robert (2003) “The logic of team reasoning,” Philosophical Explorations, Vol. 6, No. 3, pp. 165181.Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. and Vermeule, Adrian (2009) “Conspiracy theories: Causes and cures,” Journal of Political Philosophy, Vol. 17, No. 2, pp. 202227.Google Scholar
Svenson, Ola (1981) “Are we all less risky and more skillful than our fellow drivers?Acta psychologica, Vol. 47, No. 2, pp. 143148.Google Scholar
Sznycer, Daniel and Lukaszewski, Aaron W. (2019) “The emotion–valuation constellation: Multiple emotions are governed by a common grammar of social valuation,” Evolution and Human Behavior, Vol. 40, No. 4, pp. 395404.Google Scholar
Tajfel, Henri (1970) “Experiments in intergroup discrimination,” Scientific American, Vol. 223, No. 5, pp. 96103.Google Scholar
Tajfel, Henri (1974) “Social identity and intergroup behaviour,” Information (International Social Science Council), Vol. 13, No. 2, pp. 6593.Google Scholar
Tajfel, Henri, Turner, John C., Austin, William G. and Worchel, Stephen (2004) “An integrative theory of intergroup conflict,” in Hatch, M. J. and Schultz, M., eds., Oxford. Organizational identity: A reader. Oxford University Press, p. 65.Google Scholar
Tanner-Smith, E. E., Wilson, S. J. and Lipsey, M. W. (2013) “Risk factors and crime,” in The Oxford handbook of criminological theory. Oxford University Press, pp. 89111.Google Scholar
Taylor, Shelley E. and Brown, Jonathon D. (1988) “Illusion and well-being: A social psychological perspective on mental health,” Psychological Bulletin, Vol. 103, No. 2, p. 193.Google Scholar
Tenenbaum, Joshua B., Griffiths, Thomas L. et al. (2001) “The rational basis of representativeness,” in Proceedings of the 23rd annual conference of the Cognitive Science Society. Erlbaum, pp. 10361041.Google Scholar
Teoh, Siew Hong and Hwang, Chuan Yang (1991) “Nondisclosure and adverse disclosure as signals of firm value,” The Review of Financial Studies, Vol. 4, No. 2, pp. 283313.Google Scholar
Thaler, Richard H. (2015) Misbehaving: The making of behavioral economics. W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Thaler, Richard H. (2016) “Behavioral economics: Past, present, and future,” American Economic Review, Vol. 106, No. 7, pp. 15771600.Google Scholar
Tooby, John and Cosmides, Leda (1990) “The past explains the present: Emotional adaptations and the structure of ancestral environments,” Ethology and Sociobiology, Vol. 11, Nos. 4–5, pp. 375424.Google Scholar
Train, Kenneth E. (2009) Discrete choice methods with simulation. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Trivers, R. L. (1976) “Foreword,” in R. Dawkins, The selfish gene. Oxford University Press, pp. xiv–xx.Google Scholar
Trivers, Robert (1972) “Parental investment and sexual selection,” in Sexual Selection and the descent of man. Aldine de Gruyter, pp. 136179.Google Scholar
Trivers, Robert L. (1971) “The evolution of reciprocal altruism,” The Quarterly Review of Biology, Vol. 46, No. 1, pp. 3557.Google Scholar
Tung, Ka-Kit (2007) Topics in mathematical modeling. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Turmunkh, Uyanga, van den Assem, Martijn J. and Van Dolder, Dennie (2019) “Malleable lies: Communication and cooperation in a high stakes TV game show,” Management Science, Vol. 65, No. 10, pp. 47954812.Google Scholar
Turner, John C. (1996) “Henri Tajfel: An introduction,” in Robinson, W. P. and Tajfel, H., H., eds., Social groups and identities: Developing the legacy of Henri Tajfel. Psychology Press, p. 23.Google Scholar
Tversky, A. and Kahneman, D. (1982) “Judgments of and by representativeness (No. TR-3),” in Kahneman, D., Slovic, P. and Tversky, A., eds., Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Tversky, Amos (1969) “Intransitivity of preferences,” Psychological Review, Vol. 76, No. 1, p. 31.Google Scholar
Tversky, Amos and Kahneman, Daniel (1974) “Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases,” Science, Vol. 185, No. 4157, pp. 11241131.Google Scholar
Tversky, Amos and Kahneman, Daniel (1992) “Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, Vol. 5, No. 4, pp. 297323.Google Scholar
Tversky, Amos and Simonson, Itamar (1993) “Context-dependent preferences,” Management Science, Vol. 39, No. 10, pp. 11791189.Google Scholar
Van den Steen, Eric (2004) “Rational overoptimism (and other biases),” American Economic Review, Vol. 94, No. 4, pp. 11411151.Google Scholar
van Prooijen, Jan-Willem and van Vugt, Mark (2018) “Conspiracy theories: Evolved functions and psychological mechanisms,” Perspectives on Psychological Science, Vol. 13, No. 6, pp. 770788.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein (1899/2017) The theory of the leisure class. Routledge.Google Scholar
von Böhm-Bawerk, Eugen (1891) The positive theory of capital. G. E. Stechert.Google Scholar
von Hippel, William (2018) The social leap. HarperCollins.Google Scholar
von Hippel, William, Baker, Ernest, Wilson, Robbie, Brin, Loic and Page, Lionel (2016) “Detecting deceptive behaviour after the fact,” British Journal of Social Psychology, Vol. 55, No. 2, pp. 195205.Google Scholar
Von Hippel, William and Trivers, Robert (2011) “The evolution and psychology of self-deception,” Behavioral and Brain Sciences, Vol. 34, No. 1, p. 1.Google Scholar
von Neumann, John and Morgenstern, Oskar (1944) Theory of games and economic behavior. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Vorzimmer, Peter (1969) “Darwin, Malthus, and the theory of natural selection,” Journal of the History of Ideas, Vol. 30, No. 4, pp. 527542.Google Scholar
Wakker, Peter P. (1989) Additive representations of preferences: A new foundation of decision analysis, Vol. 4. Springer Science + Business Media.Google Scholar
Wakker, Peter P. (2010) Prospect theory: For risk and ambiguity: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Wald, Abraham (1945) “Sequential tests of statistical hypotheses,” The Annals of Mathematical Statistics, Vol. 16, No. 2, pp. 117186.Google Scholar
Wald, Abraham and Wolfowitz, Jacob (1948) “Optimum character of the sequential probability ratio test,” The Annals of Mathematical Statistics, Vol. 19, No. 3, pp. 326339.Google Scholar
Watts, Tyler W., Duncan, Greg J. and Quan, Haonan (2018) “Revisiting the marshmallow test: A conceptual replication investigating links between early delay of gratification and later outcomes,” Psychological Science, Vol. 29, No. 7, pp. 11591177.Google Scholar
Webb, Ryan (2018) “The (neural) dynamics of stochastic choice,” Management Science, Vol. 65, No. 1, pp. 230255.Google Scholar
Weber, Max (1915/1953) The religion of China. Confucianism and Taoism. Free Press.Google Scholar
Weinstein, Neil D. (1980) “Unrealistic optimism about future life events,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, Vol. 39, No. 5, p. 806.Google Scholar
Weiss, Yair, Simoncelli, Eero P. and Adelson, Edward H. (2002) “Motion illusions as optimal percepts,” Nature Neuroscience, Vol. 5, No. 6, pp. 598604.Google Scholar
Wernerfelt, Birger (1995) “A rational reconstruction of the compromise effect: Using market data to infer utilities,” Journal of Consumer Research, Vol. 21, No. 4, pp. 627633.Google Scholar
White, Matthew (2011) The great big book of horrible things. Norton.Google Scholar
Wilcox, Nathaniel T. (2008) “Stochastic models for binary discrete choice under risk: A critical primer and econometric comparison,” in Risk aversion in experiments, pp. 197292, Emerald Group.Google Scholar
Wilson, David Sloan and Sober, Elliott (1994) “Reintroducing group selection to the human behavioral sciences,” Behavioral and Brain Sciences, Vol. 17, No. 4, pp. 585607.Google Scholar
Winter, Eyal (2014) Feeling smart: Why our emotions are more rational than we think. PublicAffairs.Google Scholar
Woodford, Michael (2012a) “Inattentive valuation and reference-dependent choice.” Report, Columbia Academic Commons, https://academiccommons.columbia.edu/doi/10.7916/D8VD6XVK.Google Scholar
Woodford, Michael (2012b) “Prospect theory as efficient perceptual distortion,” American Economic Review, Vol. 102, No. 3, pp. 4146.Google Scholar
World Health Organization (2018) Global status report on road safety 2015. World Health Organization.Google Scholar
Yaari, M. E. (1985) “On the role of ‘Dutch books’ in the theory of choice under risk.” Nancy L. Schwartz Memorial Lecture, J. L. Kellogg Graduate School of Management, Northwestern University.Google Scholar
Yaari, Menahem E. (1987) “The dual theory of choice under risk,” Econometrica, pp. 95115.Google Scholar
Yamagishi, Toshio, Horita, Yutaka, Mifune, Nobuhiro, Hashimoto, Hirofumi, Li, Yang, Shinada, Mizuho, Miura, Arisa, Inukai, Keigo, Takagishi, Haruto and Simunovic, Dora (2012) “Rejection of unfair offers in the ultimatum game is no evidence of strong reciprocity,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, Vol. 109, No. 50, pp. 2036420368.Google Scholar
Yamagishi, Toshio and Mifune, Nobuhiro (2016) “Parochial altruism: Does it explain modern human group psychology?,” Current Opinion in Psychology, Vol. 7, pp. 3943.Google Scholar
Yzerbyt, Vincent (2016) “Intergroup stereotyping,” Current Opinion in Psychology, Vol. 11, pp. 9095.Google Scholar
Zahavi, Amotz (1975) “Mate selection: A selection for a handicap,” Journal of Theoretical Biology, Vol. 53, No. 1, pp. 205214.Google Scholar
Zietsch, Brendan P., Kuja-Halkola, Ralf, Walum, Hasse and Verweij, Karin J. H. (2014) “Perfect genetic correlation between number of offspring and grandoffspring in an industrialized human population,” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, Vol. 111, No. 3, pp. 10321036.Google Scholar
Zimring, Franklin E. and Hawkins, Gordon (1999) Crime is not the problem: Lethal violence in America. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Zizzo, Daniel John and Oswald, Andrew J. (2001) “Are people willing to pay to reduce others’ incomes?,” Annales d’Economie et de Statistique, Nos. 63–64, pp. 3965.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Bibliography
  • Lionel Page, University of Queensland
  • Book: Optimally Irrational
  • Online publication: 12 November 2022
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009209175.021
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Bibliography
  • Lionel Page, University of Queensland
  • Book: Optimally Irrational
  • Online publication: 12 November 2022
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009209175.021
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Bibliography
  • Lionel Page, University of Queensland
  • Book: Optimally Irrational
  • Online publication: 12 November 2022
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009209175.021
Available formats
×