Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t7czq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T06:13:33.430Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Trade openness, job sectors, and social policy preferences: evidence from China

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 March 2022

Li Zheng*
Affiliation:
School of Government, Yunnan University, Yunnan, China
Ling Zhu
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, University of Houston, Houston, USA
*
*Corresponding author. Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

How does trade openness affect individuals’ social policy preferences in emerging markets? Drawing upon the theories of economic openness, risk, and social policy preference, we examine how trade openness and job sectors jointly shape preferences on social protection in China, the largest emerging market. Using the World Value Survey (WVS) Wave VI and archival macroeconomic indicators in 2012, we find that trade openness is associated with higher demands for government responsibility in social protection. We also find, compared with public-sector employees, private-sector employees exhibit lower levels of support to the role of government in social protection. The public–private divide in policy preferences, nevertheless, diminishes in regions with high levels of trade openness. This research provides new evidence to the risk-model of social policy preferences in the Chinese context. It also highlights the importance of considering the significant differences between public and private-sector employees in their social policy preferences.

Type
Research Note
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the European Political Science Association

1. Introduction

The literature of globalization and social protections highlights the importance of identifying how economic gains and losses determine one's preferences on government-funded social protection (Scheve and Slaughter, Reference Scheve and Slaughter2004; Mayda and Rodrik, Reference Mayda and Rodrik2005; Walter, Reference Walter2010, Reference Walter2017). Other works find sociotropic and cultural factors play important roles in shaping individuals’ policy preferences (Mansfield and Mutz, Reference Mansfield and Mutz2009; Naoi and Kume, Reference Naoi and Kume2011; Lü et al., Reference Lü, Scheve and Slaughter2012). Most of the existing studies, however, are drawn from the empirical context of western industrialized countries (Mares and Carnes, Reference Mares and Carnes2009). Recent studies in developing countries find that economic globalization has led governments to adopt different policy responses such as the expansion of subsidies or public employment (Wibbels and Ahlquist, Reference Wibbels and Ahlquist2011; Rickard, Reference Rickard2012; Nooruddin and Rudra, Reference Nooruddin and Rudra2014). However, we still know much less about whether economic openness affects individuals’ social policy preferences differently in emerging markets. Furthermore, many relevant studies primarily consider the total volume of trade and overlook how imports and exports may affect workers’ labor market risks differently. It also remains unclear whether workers’ occupational characteristics defined by the public–private cleavage will affect their preferences on social protection. In this paper, we fill these gaps in the literature by probing how trade openness and job sectors jointly affect individuals’ preferences on social protection in China.

Drawing upon the “new new trade theory”, we argue that trade openness raises workers’ demand for social protection as more individuals share the heightened economic risks in local labor market. Also, imports and exports affect workers’ labor market risks differently, then translate into distinct demand on social programs. Our analysis suggests that greater imports increase workers’ job volatility and income variability in emerging markets as found in advanced economies (Margalit, Reference Margalit2011; David et al., Reference David, Dorn and Hanson2013; Owen and Johnston, Reference Owen and Johnston2017; Jensen et al., Reference Jensen, Quinn and Weymouth2017). However, greater exports may increase demand on redistribution-related government responsibility but do not necessarily raise the demand on unemployment compensations.

Linking micro-level preference data from World Value Survey (WVS) Wave VI and macroeconomic indicators on trade openness at the sub-national (provincial) level in China, we find evidence that trade openness significantly increases demand on social protection. Although public-sector employees hold more supportive views than private-sector employees regarding the role of government in providing social protection, trade openness is more likely to affect private-sector employees’ social policy preferences than public-sector employees. In Chinese provinces with high levels of trade openness, we observe convergence in social policy preferences between public and private-sector employees. Our research provides new evidence to the risk-model of social policy preferences as China embraces economic globalization and has become the largest emerging market. Showing the significant differences between public and private-sector employees in their social policy preferences, our research sheds lights on the economic foundations of heterogeneous social policy preferences in China.

2. Trade openness, economic risks, and social policy preferences

In this section, we discuss individual workers’ social protection preferences in emerging markets by drawing distributional implications from the “new new trade theory” in the labor markets. We conceptualize individuals’ labor market risks as two major dimensions: job security and income volatility. According to the “new new trade theory”, trading firms are larger and more competitive than their domestic counterparts, because only more productive firms can afford the costs of international trade while less productive firms have to focus on the domestic market or exit (Melitz, Reference Melitz2003). Exporting firms that are more productive and larger, therefore tend to gain increasing profits from the economies of scale and technology-oriented innovation, which result in higher returns to their workers (Atkin et al., Reference Atkin, Khandelwal and Osman2017). To the contrary, domestic firms and their workers face intensified competition from foreign companies (Kim and Osgood, Reference Kim and Osgood2019). Relevant trade studies find that trade is associated with rising inequality in developing countries and emerging markets (Goldberg and Pavcnik, Reference Goldberg and Pavcnik2007; Verhoogen, Reference Verhoogen2008).

New study based on the “new new trade theory” underscores that in regions that have a high-level of trade openness, domestic workers might share similar labor market risks due to job competition (Palmtag et al., Reference Palmtag, Rommel and Walter2020). As such, individuals are more likely to support the expansion of social protection when trade openness is high. Inspired by the non-material explanations of trade-relevant policies (Mansfield and Mutz, Reference Mansfield and Mutz2009; Lü et al., Reference Lü, Scheve and Slaughter2012), we acknowledge that individuals’ feelings and preferences about the economic risks might also depend on how well the other people in their surroundings feel. The overall trade exposure in the community or local area has a crucial influence on how individuals perceive the economic risks. As trade openness increases, domestic workers in the same region share the heightened economic risks and therefore form the collective sentiment for higher social protections.

We further recognize different mechanisms by which exports and imports affect individuals’ economic risk and demand on social protections. Export-intensive areas benefit workers within the exporting sectors, and the income gap between exporters and domestic firms will raise domestic workers’ demand on distribution-related social programs. Then individuals who reside in export-intensive areas tend to demand a higher level of government-funded social protection while they are not sensitive to unemployment risks because the expansion of exports creates new jobs. Import-intensive areas, on the contrary, will provide fewer job opportunities to local workers (David et al., Reference David, Dorn and Hanson2013). In a developed open economy, a high level of imports is often associated with the outsourcing of domestic jobs (Margalit, Reference Margalit2011; David et al., Reference David, Dorn and Hanson2013; Owen and Johnston, Reference Owen and Johnston2017). In emerging markets, labor market shocks from imports are also likely to produce demand on generous unemployment compensations and other social safety net programs, since one who had experienced labor market worries are also very likely to experience shocks of other social domains such as family, health, and wealth (Hacker et al., Reference Hacker, Rehm and Schlesinger2013; Zhu and Lipsmeyer, Reference Zhu and Lipsmeyer2015).

H1a: Individuals who reside in places with a higher level of trade openness will be more likely to demand social protection than those living in places with a lower level of trade openness.

H1b: Individuals who reside in places with a higher level of export will be more likely to demand government responsibility in redistribution-related social protection than those living in places with a lower level of export.

H1c: Individuals who reside in places with a higher level of import will be more likely to demand unemployment protection than those living in places with a lower level of import.

Individuals’ occupational characteristics, such as their job sectors, may color how trade openness shapes social policy preferences. We argue that private-sector employees have distinct social policy preferences in emerging markets. First, social protection program is a dual-system by design and uses different schemes for public and private-sector employees (Mares and Carnes, Reference Mares and Carnes2009). For example, the Chinese government utilizes its fiscal capacities to fund the public sectors while privatizing social programs for the private sectors (Huang, Reference Huang2019). Second, as private-sector employees do not have access to publicly-funded social programs, they have to cope with their economic risks by relying on social insurance provided by their employers or out-of-pocket resources (Frazier, Reference Frazier2011, Reference Frazier2015; Chen and Hamori, Reference Chen and Hamori2013; Holland, Reference Holland2018; Jiang et al., Reference Jiang, Qian and Wen2018). As such, private-sector employees are less likely to demand government-funded social protection than public-sector employees, because they do not directly benefit from these government-funded programs. However, trade openness amplifies the gap in economic risks between public employees and private employees. A high level of trade openness increases the economic risks of those who hold private-sector jobs, while public-sector employees are not affected by trade and receive generous publicly-funded social protections (Mares and Carnes, Reference Mares and Carnes2009; Nooruddin and Rudra, Reference Nooruddin and Rudra2014). As the local economy is more exposed to international competition, individuals who work in private sectors are facing heightened economic risks. Therefore, we expect that the rising economic risks caused by trade openness will motivate private workers to desire greater social protection.

H2: Private-sector employees are less likely to demand social protection than public-sector employees.

H3: Private employees will be more likely to demand publicly funded social protection than their counterparts in public sectors when the level of trade openness is high.

3. Research design and data

China, as the largest merging market, offers an ideal case to examine the link between economic openness and preferences on social protection preferences. Chinese economic growth in recent years relied on economic openness, where private companies account for the majority of its exports (Naughton and Tsai., Reference Naughton and Tsai2015). Also, a socialist welfare tradition raises the question of whether trade openness changes Chinese citizens’ social policy preferences.

We draw data on Chinese workers’ social policy preferences from the China Module of the WVS Wave 6. Using the GPS-assisted area sampling method (Landry and Shen, Reference Landry and Shen2005), the survey produces a nationally representative sample of adults between the ages of 18 and 75, who reside in Mainland China (Hong Kong and Macao are not included) in 2012. Forty counties were chosen as primary survey units by stratified PPS (Probabilities Proportional to Size) out of 2855 counties in China. The resulting data include respondents from 21 provinces and threedirect-administrated municipalities. We merge the individual-level survey data with archival macroeconomic indicators at the provincial level. Provincial-level data on foreign trade, foreign direct investment (FDI), service industry ratio, unemployment rate, and province-level Gross Domestic Product (GDP) are drawn from the National Bureau of Statistics of China (NBSC) and Chinese Provincial Statistical Yearbooks.

Two survey items from the WVS measure Chinese citizens’ social protection preferences. The first dependent variable measures individuals’ responses to the question: “Do you agree or disagree with the government, or people should take more responsibility to ensure that everyone is provided for living?” Responses are coded from 1 to 10, with “10” referring to a strongly supportive attitude toward the role of government in providing social protection, and “1” referring to the opinion that people should care for their basic needs for living. The second dependent variable also has a 1–10 ordinal scale, measuring whether the government should provide unemployment benefits to citizens. Higher values on this scale indicate the government should provide higher unemployment subsidies.Footnote 1 We attribute individuals’ preferences of social protection to economic vulnerability induced by trade openness and job sector. First, we use rade volume as the percent of GDP at province level in 2012 to measure the overall level of trade openness. Figure A2 in Appendix shows the geographic variation of trade openness across 24 provincial units in China. The mean of variable-trade openness is 34 percent, with a range from 3.8 to 144 percent. Because we conceptualize different effects of exports and imports, we provide exports over GDP and imports over GDP. The second independent variable is a dichotomous variable measuring survey respondents’ job sectors based on whether one works in public or private sector, coding “1” for private-sector employees and “0” for employees in governmental and public sectors. In the Chinese economy, private firms dominate export-oriented sectors that produce manufacturing goods. While some SOEs involve in foreign trade, the majority of them concentrate on strategic sectors, such as banks and energy industries, and therefore are sheltered from external economic shocks.Footnote 2 Because we nest individual-level preference data within provincial-level economic indicators, we estimate several multi-level models for the two policy preference variables. Specifically, we use the generalized linear latent and mixed models (Rabe-Hesketh and Skrondal, Reference Rabe-Hesketh and Skrondal2012). For each of our empirical models, we recognize the two-level hierarchical data structure, and include random intercepts by provinces to deal with intra-class heterogeneity. We choose the multilevel-model approach over the method using clustered standard errors to more explicitly account for the hierarchical bias (Abadie et al., Reference Abadie, Athey, Imbens and Wooldridge2017).Footnote 3

4. Empirical findings

Table A2 in the Appendix presents findings based on two multi-level regressions. Model 1 is for the dependent variable that measures attitudes regarding the role of government in supporting basic living standards. Model 2 is for the dependent variable specifically measuring demand on government-funded unemployment compensation. In both models, we observe that variable Trade (as percent of GDP) is positive and significantly associated with supporting greater role of government. Both models show consistent evidence supporting H1a that individuals living in provinces (or directly-administrated municipalities) with higher levels of trade openness are more likely to demand greater role of government in the social protection. The left-hand panel in Figure 1 shows the estimated odds ratios of variable “Trade”, which are 1.018 and 1.025, in Model 1 and Model 2, respectively. These two odds ratios suggest a 1 percent increase in trade openness will lead to an increase in the probability of demanding government responsibility in providing one's living by 1.8 percent and an increase in the probability of supporting government-funded unemployment protection by 2.5 percent. The substantive effect size of foreign trade on individual social protection could be very large across different provinces, given the extensive range of foreign trade across Chinese provinces (from 4 to 144 percent).

Fig. 1. Odds ratio coefficients and 95 percent confidence intervals, based on full models in Table A2.

Table A2-Model 1 also confirms Hypothesis 2 that private-sector employees are less likely than public-sector employees to demand greater government responsibility in providing for one's living ($b = -0.329$, $p< 0.05$). The corresponding odds ratio is approximately 0.70. This odds ratio indicates that individuals from private sectors will be less likely to demand government responsibility in economic welfare than their counterparts in the public sector by a probability of 30 percent. This finding is substantively significant in support of our theory that workers in private sectors strongly disfavor the expansion of government's role in social protection.

Key findings in Table A2 remain robust in two robustness checks. First, since our empirical sample includes 24 different sub-national units, it might be possible that some provinces with a very high level of trade openness would bias the empirical estimation. It is also possible that some unobserved province-specific factors could affect individuals’ labor market risks. In our Statistical Appendix, we re-estimate our models by adding provincial fixed effects. This robustness check confirms the empirical results reported in the main manuscript (Table A9). The fixed-effects specification produces slightly larger coefficient sizes for our two key explanatory variable. The coefficients for trade openness in two models increase from 0.019 to 0.103 (government responsibility) and 0.022 to 0.329 (unemployment subsidies) while private-sector employees show a lower coefficient at $-0.377$ from $-0.329$.

Second, we posit that foreign trade affects individuals’ labor market risks as a form of an external economic shock. Therefore, we replace the level of foreign trade by an annual change measure. Using the yearly difference between 2011 and 2012 over the total trade volume in 2012, we probe whether the change ratio of trade significantly affect one's social policy preferences. We provide these tests in the supplementary materials (Table A12). This robustness check further confirms our theory that trade openness treated as an economic shock does drive individuals’ demand on government responsibility in social protection. In addition, considering the lagged effect of trade on individuals’ labor market effects, we find that using trade data in 2011 produces highly consistent results in the supplementary materials (Table A12).

In Table A3, we present two additional models by decomposing the total trade into two parts: exports over local GDP and imports over local GDP. Consistent with our theoretical expectation, Model 3 and Model 4 support Hypothesis1b and Hypothesis1c by providing more nuanced tests on how exports affect individuals’ social protection preferences differently from imports. Specifically, we find that residents who live in a province with greater exports tend to demand a higher level of government intervention and unemployment subsidies. However, exports’ effect on unemployment subsidies does not reach statistical significance because export sectors could bring about more new jobs for local people that absorb many workers from declining domestic firms. In contrast, imports increase an individual's support for unemployment subsidies and the role of government in distribution. Figure 2 visualizes the odds ratio coefficients derived from Table A3. Figure 2 shows the odds ratios for export in model 3 is 1.02, which means a one-unit increase in the export will lead to an increase in the probability of demanding the role of government by 2 percent. The odds ratios for imports in Model 3 and Model 4 are 1.01 and 1.04, respectively. Imports’ effect on one's support for job-related subsidies (4 percent) is higher than the demand for income-related social protection (1 percent). Moreover, the empirical findings of private-sector employees on social protection preferences are consistent with Models 1 and 2 in Table A2.

Fig. 2. Odds ratio coefficients and 95 percent confidence intervals, based on full models in Table A3.

A quick review of the control variables in Tables A2 and A3 shows expected relationships. Provincial-level unemployment rate is positively associated with demand on the role of government in social protection and unemployment compensation across four models. In the Chinese context, we do not find evidence that FDI and individuals’ skill assets significantly affect their social policy preferences.Footnote 4 While previous studies in the context of advanced economies find the service sector is positively associated with demand on government-funded social protection (Iversen and Cusack, Reference Iversen and Cusack2000), we find in the Chinese context, the expansion of service sector is associated with decreases in support for government responsibility in social protection. Female workers are more likely to demand unemployment-related benefits than the role of government in social protection. This finding suggests that women are motivated by sociotropic factors such as family-related job security (Mansfield et al., Reference Mansfield, Mutz and Silver2015). Last but not least, individuals’ perceptions on income inequality significantly affect their social protection preferences. Those who endorse egalitarian values are more likely to support a higher level of social protections.

To test Hypothesis 3 regarding the joint effect of trade openness and private-sector jobs, we present two models in Table A4. Trade openness and workers’ job sectors are significant predictors of individuals’ social protection preferences, as shown in Table A4. In Model 5, we find some evidence that trade openness moderates the effect of private-sector jobs. Private-sector employees exhibit lower levels of support to the role of government in social protection, but the public–private divide in policy preferences diminishes as trade openness increases. Figures 3 and 4 further illustrate the interactive effects.Footnote 5 Figure 3 shows the marginal effects of private employees across the full range of the trade openness variable. We find that the marginal effect of private-sector jobs is negative and statistically significant in provinces with low trade openness (i.e., total trade volume accounting for less than 30 percent of provincial GPD). As trade openness increases, the marginal effect becomes not distinguishable from zero, meaning that in Chinese provinces with high levels of trade openness, there is a convergence of policy preferences between public and private-sector employees. Figure 4 demonstrates the marginal effects of trade openness on the support for government-funded protection between two job sectors. It shows that trade openness has positive marginal effects on demand for public-funded social protection across both job sectors.

Fig. 3. Marginal effect of supporting government responsibility by occupation sector among individuals as province-level trade varies.

Fig. 4. Marginal effect of supporting government responsibility by trade openness as occupation sector among individuals varies.

5. Concluding discussions

In this paper, we provide a risk model to emphasize how trade openness and job sectors jointly shape social policy preferences in the largest emerging market. Despite the fact that China has long been a socialist country, Chinese workers are now exposed to different labor market risks. The empirical results show that trade openness and job sectors breed into more heterogeneous preferences in the social policy area among Chinese citizens.

This paper contributes new insights about social policy preferences in open emerging markets. Our paper identifies who is helped, hurt, and sheltered in one largest emerging market, by drawing upon insights from the “new new trade theory”. We theorize and present that individuals from export-intensive and import-intensive areas face rising labor market risks and therefore demand higher social protection in China. This study also provides new evidence in the context of emerging markets, that trade does increase workers’ demands for greater social protection, but more saliently among those in private sectors. This finding diverges from the argument that globalization exposure does not increase workers’ demand for job-related protections when they mainly rely on insurance (Lim and Burgoon, Reference Lim and Burgoon2018). Based on a risk model of social protection, our paper finds that trade-induced economic risks motivate private-sector workers to demand higher protections, although they have limited accesses to public-funded social protections (Frazier, Reference Frazier2011; Holland, Reference Holland2018; Huang, Reference Huang2019).

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/psrm.2022.10. To obtain replication material for this article, please visit: https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/I8SPKO

Footnotes

1 Figure A1 in Appendix provides more information about more respondents’ preferences on government responsibility in social protection and unemployment subsidies.

2 We present detailed descriptions about control variables and relevant robustness checks in the Statistical Appendix. Worth to note, all the Tables are provided in the Statistical Appendix.

3 In the Statistical Appendix, we provide additional models using clustered standard errors as the robustness check (Tables A7 and A8). The alternative model specification produce similar substantive results. Where we also present more detailed discussions about the multilevel model we adopt.

4 We find skilled workers are less likely to demand government-funded social protection, using the fixed-effects specification shown in the Statistical Appendix, Table A9.

5 We use the interflex package in STATA to generate visualizations of the conditional marginal effects of trade openness and private-sector jobs(Hainmueller et al., Reference Hainmueller, Mummolo and Xu2019). The visuals are produced using bootstrap standard errors with 1500 replications, which mitigates the potential bias because of the small number of clusters (provinces) in our sample.

References

Abadie, A, Athey, S, Imbens, GW and Wooldridge, J (2017) When Should You Adjust Standard Errors for Clustering? Technical Report National Bureau of Economic Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkin, D, Khandelwal, AK and Osman, A (2017) Exporting and firm performance: evidence from a randomized experiment. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 132, 551615.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, G and Hamori, S (2013) Formal and informal employment and income differentials in urban China. Journal of International Development 25, 9871004.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
David, H, Dorn, D and Hanson, GH (2013) The China syndrome: local labor market effects of import competition in the United States. American Economic Review 103, 21212168.Google Scholar
Frazier, MW (2011) Welfare policy pathways among large uneven developers. In Scott Kennedy (ed.), Beyond the Middle Kingdom: Comparative Perspectives on China's Capitalist Transformation. Stanford University Press, pp. 89–112.Google Scholar
Frazier, MW (2015) The evolution of a welfare state under China's state capitalism. In Barry Naughton and Kellee S. Tsai (eds), State Capitalism, Institutional Adaption and the Chinese Miracle. Cambridge University Press, pp. 223–239.Google Scholar
Goldberg, PK and Pavcnik, N (2007) Distributional effects of globalization in developing countries. Journal of Economic Literature 45, 3982.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hacker, JS, Rehm, P and Schlesinger, M (2013) Insecure American: economic experiences, financial worries and policy attitudes. The Perspectives of Politics 11, 2349.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hainmueller, J, Mummolo, J and Xu, Y (2019) How much should we trust estimates from multiplicative interaction models? Simple tools to improve empirical practice. Political Analysis 27, 163192.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holland, AC (2018) Diminished Expectations: Redistributive Preferences in Truncated Welfare States. World Politics 70, 555594.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huang, X (2019) Social cleavages and preferences for government redistribution in contemporary China. Studies in Comparative International Development 54, 415450.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iversen, T and Cusack, TR (2000) The causes of welfare state expansion: deindustrialization or globalization?. World Politics 52, 313349.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jensen, JB, Quinn, DP and Weymouth, S (2017) Winners and losers in international trade: the effects on US presidential voting. International Organization 71, 423457.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jiang, J, Qian, J and Wen, Z (2018) Social protection for the informal sector in urban China: institutional constraints and self-selection behaviour. Journal of Social Policy 47, 335357.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, IS and Osgood, I (2019) Firms in trade and trade politics. Annual Review of Political Science 22, 399417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Landry, PF and Shen, M (2005) Reaching migrants in survey research: the use of the global positioning system to reduce coverage bias in China. Political Analysis 13, 122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lim, S and Burgoon, B (2018) Globalization and support for unemployment spending in Asia: do Asian citizens want to embed liberalism?. Socio-Economic Review 135.Google Scholar
, X, Scheve, K and Slaughter, MJ (2012) Inequity aversion and the international distribution of trade protection. American Journal of Political Science 56, 638654.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mansfield, ED and Mutz, DC (2009) Support for free trade: self-interest, sociotropic politics, and out-group anxiety. International Organization 63, 425457.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mansfield, ED, Mutz, DC and Silver, LR (2015) Men, women, trade, and free markets. International Studies Quarterly 59, 303315.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mares, I and Carnes, ME (2009) Social policy in developing countries. Annual Review of Political Science 12, 93113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Margalit, Y (2011) Costly jobs: trade-related layoffs, government compensation, and voting in US elections. American Political Science Review 105, 166188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayda, AM and Rodrik, D (2005) Why are some people (and countries) more protectionist than others?. European Economic Review 49, 13931430.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Melitz, MJ (2003) The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71, 16951725.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Naoi, M and Kume, I (2011) Explaining mass support for agricultural protectionism: evidence from a survey experiment during the global recession. International Organization 65, 771795.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Naughton, B and Tsai, KS (2015) State Capitalism, Institutional Adaptation, and the Chinese Miracle. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nooruddin, I and Rudra, N (2014) Are developing countries really defying the embedded liberalism compact?. World Politics 66, 603640.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Owen, E and Johnston, NP (2017) Occupation and the political economy of trade: job routineness, offshorability, and protectionist sentiment. International Organization 71, 665699.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palmtag, T, Rommel, T and Walter, S (2020) International trade and public protest: evidence from Russian regions. International Studies Quarterly 64, 939955.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rabe-Hesketh, S and Skrondal, A (2012) Multilevel and Longitudinal Modeling Using Stata. College Station, Texas, USA: STATA press.Google Scholar
Rickard, SJ (2012) Welfare versus subsidies: governmental spending decisions in an era of globalization. The Journal of Politics 74, 11711183.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scheve, K and Slaughter, MJ (2004) Economic insecurity and the globalization of production. American Journal of Political Science 48, 662674.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Verhoogen, EA (2008) Trade, quality upgrading, and wage inequality in the Mexican manufacturing sector. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 123, 489530.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walter, S (2010) Globalization and the welfare state: testing the microfoundations of the compensation hypothesis. International Studies Quarterly 54, 403426.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walter, S (2017) Globalization and the demand-side of politics: how globalization shapes labor market risk perceptions and policy preferences. Political Science Research and Methods 5, 5580.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wibbels, E and Ahlquist, JS (2011) Development, trade, and social insurance. International Studies Quarterly 55, 125149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhu, L and Lipsmeyer, C (2015) Policy feedback and economic risk: the influence of privatization on social policy preferences. Journal of European Public Policy 22, 14891511.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Fig. 1. Odds ratio coefficients and 95 percent confidence intervals, based on full models in Table A2.

Figure 1

Fig. 2. Odds ratio coefficients and 95 percent confidence intervals, based on full models in Table A3.

Figure 2

Fig. 3. Marginal effect of supporting government responsibility by occupation sector among individuals as province-level trade varies.

Figure 3

Fig. 4. Marginal effect of supporting government responsibility by trade openness as occupation sector among individuals varies.

Supplementary material: PDF

Zheng and Zhu supplementary material

Zheng and Zhu supplementary material 1

Download Zheng and Zhu supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 1.3 MB
Supplementary material: File

Zheng and Zhu supplementary material

Zheng and Zhu supplementary material 2

Download Zheng and Zhu supplementary material(File)
File 42.2 KB
Supplementary material: Link

Zheng and Zhu Dataset

Link