Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-m6dg7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-19T02:07:18.094Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Analysing wages and labour institutions in China: An unfinished transition

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 January 2023

Muriel Périsse
Affiliation:
Université d’Artois, France
Clément Séhier*
Affiliation:
IMT Lille Douai, France
*
Clément Séhier, Faculty of Economics, Management and Enterprise, IMT Lille Douai, 20 Rue Guglielmo Marconi, 59653, Villeneuve d’Ascq, France. Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

The rise of wages in China would seem to indicate that the demographic dividend has reached its end. A more refined approach reveals, however, that the situation of Chinese workers has not really improved: even though real wages are rising, the share of wages in the nation’s wealth has not kept pace. The reason for this is China’s position within global value chains, where the employment relationship is not solely governed by the employer–employee power relationship, but by contractual relations established between ‘lead firms’ and subcontractors. This situation echoes labour institutional economist JR Commons’ concept of ‘competitive menace’ and analyses of the structural imbalance of power in the employer/employee relationship. We argue that despite the Chinese government’s desire for industrial upgrading and its intention to develop internal labour markets, Chinese labour institutions have shown significant resistance to change making it hard to envisage any shift towards a Fordist regime of capital accumulation based on a virtuous cycle of mass production and mass consumption.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The Author(s) 2019

The announcement that wages would be raised in China following the economic crisis of 2008–2009 was seen as good news both for Chinese workers and other developing countries. Given the massive number of employees in China, the nation’s influence on changes in wages at the global level has been significant (International Labour Organization (ILO), 2016a). It is known that a low level of compensation has supported Chinese growth over the last four decades (Reference Xu, Chen and LiXu et al., 2015; Reference ZhangZhang, 2016a). Investments have therefore been encouraged, allowing the country to quickly increase its production capabilities and to take over a major share of the global trade in manufactured goods. The policy of reforms and openness initiated by Deng Xiaoping in 1979 included a new endeavour to internationalise production, which profoundly changed the international division of labour. Within global value chains (GVCs),Footnote 1 multinational corporations (MNCs) searched for new ways to lower production costs, which led to the fragmentation of production systems based on subcontractor relationships. China quickly became a privileged investment destination due to an abundant rural labour force that was relatively uneducated, but motivated and ideologically regulated. The country established its specialisation at the bottom of GVCs by decreasing Chinese labour costs while integrating a massive number of rural people into modern industrial production.

However, the contraction of foreign demand during the 2008–2009 global recession led the Chinese government to reorient its choices for the country’s growth model towards the development of interior markets, a strategy that included a continuous increase in minimum wages (Reference ZhangZhang, 2016b). The purpose of the present study is to demonstrate that the depletion of the reserve of the rural labour force is not the only driver of the evolution of wages in China, but that an effective rebalancing process in favour of employees is much more complex because of a particular power balance between labour and capital. So far, the combination of specific labour institutions and China’s position within GVCs has prevented a fairer distribution of the value added at the national level.

We begin by showing that the Chinese situation illustrates Reference KuznetsKuznets’ (1955) theory, according to which the increase in wages results from the shift towards sectors with greater productivity, thereby mobilising a more skilled labour force. However, the specific labour regime, particularly adapted to China’s integration into GVCs, confined the gains for Chinese employees. This analysis echoes the early Institutional Economics initiated by JR Commons (founder of the Industrial Relations’ tradition) considering the natural trend of capitalism to low wages and wage stagnation when strong labour institutions are missing. In the end, despite the apparent increase in wages, Chinese industrial development rests on a weak redistribution of labour productivity gains to workers. While recent government policies have shown a desire to develop the internal market, the characteristics of Chinese industry prevent, for the moment, any prospect for transition towards a Fordist type of capitalism in the near future. By Fordist, we mean a form of governed capitalism led by labour institutions able to resolve the wage–productivity imbalance, and able to create reasonable economic outcomes for the society, a ‘reasonable capitalism’ as Reference CommonsJR Commons (1934) called it.

A linear wage transition?

Contrary to many developing countries, China has long-term experience with industrial employees. Under the thumb of Maoism, wage systems responded to the need to mobilise the workforce. The notion of sacrifice in the name of national independence was promoted, and this notion enabled the practice of low monetary wages, compensated by benefits in kind (the ‘iron rice bowl’) that depended on the size, prestige and rank of the work unit (danwei 单位) (Reference WalderWalder, 1986). Wage scales were reduced to an extreme degree, and the employee hierarchy was based essentially on seniority (Reference Korzec and HoweKorzec and Howe, 1992). This socialist heritage of poorly paid employees then played an important role in the economic development of contemporary China.

Indeed, beginning with reforms starting in 1979, an end to egalitarian principles resulted in the introduction of incentive wage schemes (low base salary, supplementation in kind, and a bonus system relying on overtime as the only way to improve one’s wages). This competitive wage relationship, which quickly developed in the coastal provinces, was also combined with the possibility for companies to make profits, leading to an economic transition that was ultimately unfavourable for workers. Indeed, the form adopted for putting the rural labour force to work was initially that of factory wage labour in Township and Village Enterprises or joint ventures in which the social benefits of the danwei were challenged.

According to official Chinese statistics, the real annual wages of urban workers remained low until the mid-1990s (Figure 1), growing at an average annual rate of only 5.9%,Footnote 2 compared with the real growth rate of the Chinese economy which reached an average of 9.9% per year for this period. The growth of real wages accelerated in the period that followed: from 1998 to 2010, it averaged 15.4% annually, compared to average GDP (gross domestic product) annual growth rate of 10.8%. This trend continued from 2010 to 2015, real urban wages growing on average by almost 13% per year, while average GDP growth slowed to 7.6% per year. Reference Li, Li and WuLi et al. (2012) emphasise that Chinese wages in manufacturing industries have increased more quickly than in other emerging Asian countries. Compared to India or Indonesia, the Chinese industrial workforce has quickly caught up in most sectors and for all skill levels.

Figure 1. Real annual wages of Chinese urban workers 1978–2015 (RMB).

Sources: China Statistical Yearbooks, various years, Tables 4–11.

However, the gap between the highly industrialised coastal provinces and inland provinces persists (Figure 2): while wages are improving just as much for export industries as for others, Reference Hering and PoncetHering and Poncet (2009) show that the wage dynamic is influenced by proximity to export markets. This uneven wage dynamic has contributed to reinforcing inequalities, China becoming one of the countries where the Gini index is among the highest, rising from 0.26 in 1978 to 0.46 in 2014 (Reference LiLi, 2016).

Figure 2. Annual average wages of urban workers by region 2004–2015 (RMB).

Sources: China Statistical Yearbooks, various years, Tables 4–16.

Coastal provinces: Beijing, Tianjin, Shanghai, Jiangsu, Zhejiang, Fujian, Shandong, Guangdong, Hebei and Hainan.

Nevertheless, inequalities have been slowly shrinking since 2009, owing to the economic crisis, which had a greater impact on the richest provinces (Reference ZhangZhang 2016b). The strong increase in wages is related to the combination of two long-term phenomena: the quick development of manufacturing industries, and the slowdown in the growth of the working-age population (15-64 years) since the beginning of the 2000s (Reference Das and N’DiayeDas and N’Diaye, 2013).

Wages in China: A Kuznets–Lewis textbook case?

The rise in real wages and in wage inequalities illustrates the theories of Reference KuznetsKuznets (1955) and Reference LewisLewis (1955). According to Kuznets, a rise in income inequalities, especially between cities and the countryside, is a normal step in the industrial transformation of an agricultural society, and is one that accompanies the increase in overall income. The expansion of industrial employment creates income and wage inequalities. This phenomenon is a necessary part of the capital accumulation process, since a greater share of GDP is dedicated to profits. In China, the share of wages in GDP has indeed declined constantly from the end of the 1980s to the mid-2000s, while labour productivity has been growing at an ever-increasing pace (Reference PiovaniPiovani, 2014).

As a country becomes richer, wages in manufacturing industries, though higher than income drawn from agricultural activity, are maintained at a low level due to the movement of agriculture workers entering factories (Reference LewisLewis, 1955). In China, the abundant reserve of rural workers sustained a long decline of the wage share from the 1980s on. However, Lewis indicates that over time, the demand for skilled labour increases alongside industrialisation and in the end exceeds the supply. This leads to an increase in qualified workers’ wages, and to rising inequalities within the industry.

As long as the turning point has not been reached – while growth in labour productivity remains higher than wage growth – industrial sectors become increasingly profitable, encouraging capital accumulation. Then, when the reserve of agricultural workers is used up, industrial wages grow quickly to the detriment of profits and investment. Economic growth can then no longer rely on low labour force costs, and must instead rely on industrial upgrading.

The acceleration of wage growth since 2003–2004, combined with the sporadic appearance of rural migrant worker shortages in coastal export provinces, could indicate that the Lewis process has begun (Reference CaiCai, 2018; Reference Das and N’DiayeDas and N’Diaye, 2013; Reference Zhang, Shao and DongZhang et al., 2018), thereby contributing to the convergence of rural and urban wages (Reference Cai and DuCai and Du, 2011). On the other hand, other studies argue that China is far from having used up its demographic dividend, claiming that shortages of low-skilled workforce are real but localised. Rural residents are more inclined to find employment close to home. Spatial disparities are declining as firms from coastal provinces transfer capital and technology inland, where labour productivity is catching up (Reference Lemoine, Poncet and ÜnalLemoine et al., 2015). As emphasised by Reference Knight, Deng and LiKnight et al. (2011), while the minimum wage policy has been generally well implemented since 2004, the response of labour-intensive industries in the coastal provinces has been an increase in the number of hours worked, thereby limiting this policy’s benefits. The development policy for the Western provinces (the Western Development Plan launched in 2001 – 西部大开发) and Central provinces (Rise of Central China Plan, adopted in 2004 – 中部崛起计划) also reinforced the scarcity of low-skilled workers in coastal provinces (Reference Zhu and PicklesZhu and Pickles, 2014).

According to the Migrant Workers Monitoring Survey Report (National Bureau of Statistics of China (NBS), 2016), local migrations have begun to supersede long-distance migrations since 2010. The trend reversal is sustained by the faster growth pace of local migrations vis-à-vis long-distance ones since 2010: in 2016, the migrant worker population fell by 0.3% in the coastal regions and grew by 5.3% in the western provinces. Rural migrants can more easily find jobs in their locality, thanks to the economic development of inland provinces (Reference Gao, Yan and DuGao et al., 2018).

The current situation is thus more complex than the mere depletion of the available rural workforce. Labour shortages in the most industrialised areas of coastal provinces are combined with a persistent rural workforce surplus (approximately 110m workers) ready to accept very low wages, but no longer attracted by the low benefits of migration (Reference SongSong, 2017).

These analyses are based, however, on a view of the labour market that ascribes the determining role in the evolution of wages to the relative scarcity of labour. Yet Kuznets emphasised that economic growth cannot benefit employees as long as they are kept in an unfavourable power relationship: only institutional innovations, such as public intervention in favour of a minimum wage or employee collective bargaining, can encourage a move from ‘industrial upgrading’ to ‘social upgrading’,Footnote 3 which would contribute to reducing income inequalities. While China fits well into the growth pattern related to demographic transition, the institutions that have kept workers’ bargaining power at a low level have equally played a role.

This situation echoes the works of early Institutional Economists like Reference CommonsJR Commons (1934) for whom wage stagnation and rising inequalities are a natural trend for capitalism. The employment relationship is indeed an unbalanced institutional structure which creates a structural inequality of bargaining powers, preventing wage-earners from benefitting from productivity gains (Reference KaufmanKaufman, 2018). Consequently, wages are not only regulated by the laws of supply and demand as proponents of the Lewis turning point imagine, but are above all the result of power asymmetries between employers and workers.

Industrial development that does not benefit workers

In China, the increase in real wages is constantly outpaced by labour productivity gains: Reference Li, Li and WuLi et al. (2012) argue that the growth of labour productivity between 1978 and 1997 outpaced the growth of real wages, resulting in a relative decrease in labour costs. This trend has persisted since then (Figure 3). While labour productivity kept on improving, wages lagged behind, especially in the inland provinces manufacturing industries (Reference Cui and LuCui and Lu, 2018), in relation to industrial relocations.

Figure 3. Labour productivity and average labour compensation in China, 2000–2013 (100 = 2000 base year).

Source: ILO (2016b: Figure 6).

The intensification of work is reflected in the ongoing drop in the share of labour income in GDP – confirming the weak bargaining power of labour (Figure 4) – at least until the 2008–2009 crisis. A regular rise in minimum wages was then decided by the central government when a minimum wage policy was mobilised to reverse the trend. But the continuation of this policy is now questioned (Reference Li, Kanbur and LinLi et al., 2018). In China, the level of minimum wages, usually the bottom-line in labour-intensive industries such as garment and electronics, is set locally.Footnote 4 It is therefore subject to inter-regional competition, as the objectives of attracting investments and industrial development prevail for local governments. This situation leads to a ‘race to the bottom’ in local labour standards and weak law enforcement, endorsed by local authorities (Reference Friedman and LeeFriedman and Lee, 2010). For instance, the annual increase in mingongs’ (internal migrant workers’) wages has dropped from 21% in 2011 to only 7.4% in 2016 and 6.4% in 2017 (NBS, 2016, 2017).

Figure 4. China’s Labour Share in GDP (%), 1978–2015.

Source: Reference Cui, Meng and LuCui et al. (2018: 1237).

Total bill of employees in urban units.

However, as Reference Xu, Chen and LiXu et al. (2015) demonstrate, workers have always been rewarded less than half of their marginal product, even recently. This is especially true in the private sector, despite the intensive restructuring of the public sector that started in 1992. Labour is indeed subject to capitalist structural constraints, which undermine workers’ bargaining power and prevent labour from getting a larger share of the value added. Consequently, real wages have suffered due to new strategies: increasing the number of working hours for the same wage, the generalisation of a new type of informal labour (temporary workers and interns) after the adoption of the 2007 Labour Contract Law, and relocation of factories to inland provinces where wages are lower. Finally, massive investments promoting automation of labour-intensive industries are making China the largest installer of robots.

The strategy of maintaining low wages is now complemented by the objective of industrial upgrading in Coastal provinces, as illustrated by the ‘Made in China 2025’ plan and massive investments in new technologies (Reference FabreFabre, 2018). The result has been relocations towards inland provinces and outside China, as the decline in China’s processing trade during the last decade indicates (Reference Chen, Zhu and ChenChen et al., 2018): the aim is endogenous development and the growth of a domestic market in which MNCs can find their new interest. Therefore, the capitalist logic of keeping wages under the level of their marginal product as depicted by early Institutional Economics can still shed light on the Chinese case (Reference KaufmanKaufman, 2018). Despite a large number of jobs created, many have also been destroyed and employees are still subject to an unfavourable power relationship, since Chinese companies and MNCs capture a rent – that is, an income not related to a productive contribution – a well-established characteristic of GVCs.

Industrial specialisation dependent on GVCs

China’s industrial specialisation relies on artificially low wages particularly attractive for Western brands: its economic opening at the beginning of the 1980s coincided with the new offshoring strategies of Western MNCs, in the wake of financialisation and the search for an increased return on equity leading to outsourcing. Since then, the fragmentation of production process within GVCs has been part of a system of economic power relations that gives Chinese firms no other choice but to accept or reject the conditions concerning prices, deadlines and volumes established by Western buyers that own a brand or advanced technology. These ‘lead firms’ have the power to subcontract operations requiring low-skilled labour in low-wage countries (Reference Gimet, Guilhon and RouxGimet et al., 2015).Footnote 5 The pressure on wages is thus non-negotiable for subcontracting factories, and its corollary is a decline in employee bargaining power (Reference BarrientosBarrientos, 2013; Reference HayterHayter, 2004). The complex fragmentation of the production system forces workers from different countries to compete on similar tasks (Reference Nathan and SarkarNathan and Sarkar, 2011).

The mechanism for extracting a rent (i.e. a persistent gap between labour compensation and productivity due to weak countervailing institutional corrections (Reference CommonsCommons, 1909, Reference Commons1934) is based on the ability of lead firms to impose their conditions to suppliers and manage the contractual relation only through authority. The system is indeed globally organised to reinforce the power of lead firms over subcontractors: while the former externalises low value-added tasks, the latter is constantly under the threat of losing orders if its competitiveness deteriorates (Reference Barrientos, Mayer and PosthumaBarrientos et al., 2011b; Reference Gereffi, Humphrey and SturgeonGereffi et al., 2005).

In this unbalanced contractual relationship, conditions of employment and wages become residual variables, as JR Commons understood a century ago. The subcontractor may potentially increase its margins by adopting a more efficient production process, but only until its competitors adjust their own technology. It is thus almost impossible to establish a ‘sustainable price’ which would allow suppliers to pay decent wages and comply with labour law: globalised capitalism always shifts unreasonable costs onto workers, at the price of the workers’ economic insecurity (Reference CommonsCommons, 1909).

The prospect of industrial upgrading, through the development of services and/or products with higher value-added and specialisation in more sophisticated tasks, is often seen as an opportunity to improve workers’ lot (Reference Zhu and PicklesZhu and Pickles, 2014). Based on this objective, policies to increase the cost of labour adopted by the central Chinese authorities – through minimum wage policies and more stringent labour legislation – become tenable. Yet concretely, the beneficial effects of industrial upgrading on workers’ lives have for the time being been held back by industrial strategies that generally remain fixed on minimising labour costs. The development of more sophisticated technological production has not resulted in the development of internal labour markets within enterprises or in the improvement of the employment relationship for skilled workers. Rather, strategies involving automation, reconfiguration of production systems, or lean management are leading to a reduction in the labour force and a refusal to improve wages and working conditions, or to relocations to South-East Asian countries. The production model based on exploitation of a low-cost labour force is thus very resilient (Reference ButolloButollo, 2015; Reference Lüthje and ButolloLüthje and Butollo, 2017). In that sense Reference AlmeidaAlmeida (2009) shows that China is the only example in East Asia’s middle-income countries where the openness to foreign investments and the adoption of recent technologies did not increase the demand for skilled labour. Stronger integration in international markets is associated with a greater specialisation in relatively low-skilled intensive productions, similar to low-income countries like Vietnam and Cambodia.

Even if the Chinese manufacturing system has been able to create more value-added goods for exports since the mid-2000s, these improvements remain limited, even in the tech-intensive industry. Within GVCs, China has so far not been able to attract higher value-added productions (Reference WenWen, 2018), and even in IT and electronics, remains specialised in tasks relying on low-skilled and low-paid workforce in most of its manufacturing industries. Despite important productivity gains, Chinese firms’ integration into GVCs did not materialise in improved wages or quality of employment. Compensation conditions continue to depend both on the local labour market and the requirements of foreign buyers.

The GVC analysis reveals that in addition to controlling the segments creating most of the value, lead firms can impose their control on the distribution of that value at each step along the chain. Reference Gimet, Guilhon and RouxGimet et al. (2015) indicate that the fragmentation of production leads to a decline in wages over the long term, even more so when MNCs’ strategies force producers at the bottom of the chain to specialise in narrower segments, which hampers their ability to upgrade their production and increase their share of value-added. In other words, contrary to what was being heralded by economic growth theory, integration of Chinese firms in GCVs does not lead to social progress as long as it is based on MNCs organising competition within their suppliers’ network, which leads to a race to the bottom.

The return of the sweating system

This result has already been analysed by Reference CommonsJR Commons (1909), in his article ‘American Shoemakers’ as the logical and inevitable product of a ‘competitive menace’. The employer’s greater bargaining power on the labour market, which leads to an imbalance of bargaining power within the market (Reference KaufmanKaufman, 2010: 437), has every chance of being reflected in an imperfectly competitive wage. This would be less than a competitive wage, especially since the labour supply is not flexible (i.e. workers need to work and do not withdraw from the labour market) (Reference KaufmanKaufman, 2010). The ‘sweating system’ refers to a situation in which labour compensation is aligned with what the marginal worker is forced to accept (possibly a subcontracted worker and/or a migrant worker). This process by which the worker is no longer able to earn wages that match his or her productivity results from changes in the structures of production organised according to the dissociation of the wage from the series of prices negotiated between the various market intermediaries on a large scale. When MNCs decided to externalise their production by making use of an increasingly large set of suppliers, they simply deployed this sweating system on a global scale (Reference McIntyre, Ramstad, Champlin and KoedlerMcIntyre and Ramstad, 2004).

In the analysis proposed by Reference CommonsCommons (1909), the decision to use subcontractors rather than direct hiring – that is, the preference for subcontracted work in small workshops specialised in one segment of the production process, and even for home workers – comes from market expansion. The direct relationship of the client with the producer, which ensures the wage/sales price link, is replaced by a series of intermediaries, which introduces a series of market transactions that separates the determination of the sales price for goods from the wage of the person that produced them. JR Commons contends that the control of information (especially concerning the difference between regular and overtime hours, and therefore the exact compensation to be paid) by the ‘merchant capitalists’ (the MNCs or their contractors) throughout the process is essential for this system to develop, while allowing the capitalists to make a profit without hiring a single person. This evolution did not escape Reference Marx and FowkesMarx (2015 [1887]), for whom the sweating system was related to piece-work pay. He added that ‘the exploitation of the labourer by capital is here effected through the exploitation of the labourer by the labourer’ (p. 391): the foreman responsible for bargaining the price with the buyer holds the responsibility to set the wages.

This dissociation between wage bargaining and price is reflected in the disconnection between wages and labour productivity, thus allowing growth in wages to be kept under the level of growth in productivity. This series of bargaining between intermediaries creates a ‘transactional gap’ between workers and the entity that captures the results of their labour force (Reference McIntyre, Ramstad, Champlin and KoedlerMcIntyre and Ramstad, 2004). Within GVCs, this transactional gap is even greater since the lead firms do not own the factories and therefore do not have a direct employment relationship with the workers responsible for the production tasks. In the cascade of subcontractors and ‘subletting labour’ (as designated by Reference Marx and FowkesMarx, 2015 [1887]) that characterises China’s integration into GVCs, competitive menace has become the norm of employment, at least for workers in export industries: they are in general not aware of the legislation on overtime work, nor of most of the existing labour laws.

A situation of competitive menace, the race to the bottom emerges when the labour market becomes entirely dependent on contractual relations (not competitive relations; Reference Nathan and SarkarNathan and Sarkar, 2011) that are formed outside the market, in transactions between the various suppliers along the value chain. This leads Reference Lakhani, Kuruvulla and AvgarLakhani et al. (2013) to consider the coexistence within GVCs of several employment relationship configurations that result from buyer/subcontractor relations going from the market to the chain of command depending on the degree of complexity of the tasks to accomplish, the possibility that they can be codified and the capacities of subcontractors: it is the interconnections within and between the firms involved in a GVC that configure the employment relationships in each segment.

It is thus not because the worker does not enter into a direct employment relationship with the lead firm that he or she can escape from the specific aspects of the labour contract; instead, the subordinate relationship here is lost in the series of commercial transactions conducted at a global scale; it is especially the case given that his or her direct employer must be able to ensure the flexibility required by the buyers. This leads to the cohabitation of two types of workforce: one is permanent, legally employed and benefits from social legislation; the other is casual, temporary and often not declared, which always provides the required flexibility (Reference Barrientos, Gereffi and RossiBarrientos et al., 2011a). One of the characteristics of GVCs is thus to create or strengthen the segmentation of the labour market. This trend is confirmed by the split between industrial and social upgrading in the Chinese industry (Reference ButolloButollo, 2015).

This phenomenon of unfair competition is based not only on the fact that the employee bargains without power on the market, but also that it is combined with an imbalance of bargaining power ‘before the market’ (Reference KaufmanKaufman, 2010: 437) due to the unequal distribution of property rights that benefit the employer. Workers find themselves in a situation of ‘institutional exploitation’ in which the pay discrepancy between capital and labour reaches a level no longer considered as ‘reasonable’ according to Commons’ definition: the difference between a wage and the minimum job conditions considered by society as reasonable – that is, for which a consensus is negotiated at a specific time – and the real level of wages that results from biased rules of the competitive game. Yet the possibility for institutional exploitation is made easier due to the globalised (transactional gap) and fragmented (strengthening the imbalance of powers) nature of production networks (Reference Rossi, Luinstra and PicklesRossi et al., 2014). China currently fits in such an ‘unreasonable’ situation of asymmetrical powers due to the persistence of specific labour institutions endorsed by the state.

Labour institutions favouring integration within GVCs

Within GVCs, the employment relationship is thus no longer modelled solely according to a labour contract between an employer and his or her employees but is also based on inter-firm arrangements at a transnational scale (Reference Lakhani, Kuruvulla and AvgarLakhani et al., 2013). The prevalent labour institutions in China have shown themselves to be highly compatible with lead firms’ strategies. Following Reference CommonsJR Commons (1934), institutions are the formal or informal, artificial (i.e. human-made) rules that govern the economic activities. Under the capitalist system, institutions enable accumulation and transactions, and here more specifically, the labour contract.

Labour law that legitimises institutional discrimination against rural migrants

The Chinese labour law developed as part of the reforms to the socialist system was not designed to apply to migrant workers (mingong 民工). Indeed, the household registration system (hukou) contributes to providing subcontractors of lead firms with an opportunity to access a labour force at a much lower cost, as these workers are deprived of basic social and civil rights in the cities. Even if the original hukou implemented in the 1950s was not designed to this end – but rather to prevent rural migrations towards cities – its persistence during the transition process to capitalism has been a major driver in the fragmentation of the Chinese workforce (Reference ChenChen, 2019). This case illustrates Commons’ theory of institutional evolutionism. Often compared to a ‘floating population’, migrant workers make up the vast reservoir of a workforce that can be exploited at will in workshops or on construction sites (Reference SolingerSolinger, 1999). Employers can thus benefit from the semi-clandestine situation of the mingong and employ them without labour contracts, with the active support of local authorities and the official trade-unions, which were in charge with supplying workforce to the joint ventures in the 1980s. This role further benefitted the nascent private sector all along the reforms process.

To be more specific, the introduction of the labour contract in 1986 led to the cohabitation of two types of contract: the hetong zhigong (合同职工), which was intended for employees of public companies (zhigong 职工) who later benefitted from protections in the labour law adopted in 1994, and the old temporary contract (hetong gong 合同工), which was intended for the mingong, and which provided almost no guarantees. The dual nature of the labour market explicitly placed the mingong into an informal wage relationship. This arrangement was a windfall for employers in the coastal provinces. It allowed them, in complicity with local authorities (including the official trade-unions local branches), to adopt a varied implementation of the labour law. They were thus able to enjoy the full benefit of an available and willing workforce, in order to create a competitive advantage that other countries, including in Southeast Asia, have had trouble sustaining.

New forms of labour fragmentation supported by local governments

At the national level, labour legislation has been strengthened based on a well-calculated strategy to raise the cost of labour. These policies aimed at moving migrant workers into an economically secure status (Reference PérissePérisse, 2017) and at fostering industrial upgrading in inland and western provinces.Footnote 6 However, companies integrated within GVCs find in local governments an ally to circumvent these regulations and to maintain low production costs, as illustrated by the new production complexes developed by Foxconn in the last decade in central and western provinces.

The Taiwanese company Foxconn Technology became, in the 2000s, the world’s main supplier of electronic devices, now assembling smartphones and laptops for the largest brands, such as Apple and Samsung. It developed in the city of Shenzhen (Guangdong province) a specific production model relying on massive use of low-cost labour, and a ‘neo-Taylorist’ work organisation (Reference Lüthje and ButolloLüthje and Butollo, 2017). Facing rising labour costs and the development of strikes in the wake of the 2008–2009 crisis, Foxconn started negotiating with several other municipalities to establish new production sites. Local governments in the cities of Zhengzhou (Henan) and Chengdu (Sichuan) provided numerous benefits to the company, such as free recruitment offices, transportation services to the factories, cuts in corporate and value-added taxes, and partial funding of the manufacturing complexes (Reference BarbozaBarboza, 2016; Reference Chan, Pun and SeldenChan et al., 2015).

More fundamentally, the Sichuan and Henan provincial governments supported and organised the large-scale recruitment of interns in vocational schools. Top-level officials now assign targets that lower administrative levels must complete to ensure that thousands of student workers are brought on the production lines (Reference Chan, Pun and SeldenChan et al., 2015). While such preferential treatment by local governments to capital is not new, it has thus supported, in the last few years, the development of a new form of labour fragmentation.

In China, as elsewhere, globalised production is driving the development of new forms of subcontracted bonded labour (Reference BarrientosBarrientos, 2013; Reference LüthjeLüthje, 2014a). The production model based on low labour costs is difficult to overcome, and the Chinese labour institutions enable the sweating system to become more sophisticated, thus increasing economic insecurity for non-permanent workers (Reference LüthjeLüthje, 2014b; Reference PérissePérisse, 2017): the mingongs’ labour contract coverage has dropped since the 2008–2009 crisis, and in 2016 sat at 35.1%. The fragmented Chinese labour market can therefore be understood as a systemic combination of the GVCs’ logic and the specific rules driving the labour force to industrial work, with a strong role for the state in defining those rules.

A ‘Chinese-style’ industrial relations system

The inability to improve workers’ compensation at the same pace as productivity is a source of social conflict. A recent study has found that wealth distribution has become the main concern of Chinese workers, as more than 80% of collective action between 2015 and 2017 demanded the payment of wages in arrears and wage increases (China Labour Bulletin, 2018). However, the ambivalent position of the All-China Federation of Trade Unions (ACFTU) prevents the emergence of explicit regulations on wages involving workers’ representatives. Preoccupied with controlling the negative effects of accelerated industrialisation, the Chinese authorities tightened their grip on the official trade union after the Tiananmen Square massacre in 1989. Besides controlling workers, the ACFTU was explicitly granted by the Communist Party the role of maintaining ‘social stability’ (Reference Clarke and PringleClarke and Pringle, 2009). Since then, the ACFTU has become a quasi-governmental organisation in charge of representing workers within the state (i.e. to provide feedback on labour problems from the grassroots as a base for new labour regulations) and to manage labour conflicts swiftly. Its action is twofold.

Instead of the ACFTU being a counterweight to employers, workers are prohibited by the law from defending their own interests: the trade union seeks to maintain competitive wages, a major concern for municipalities responsible for local development. On the other hand, the ACFTU must limit any social troubles by incorporating the new working class into urban society, especially by making migrant workers theoretically eligible for labour rights. The power imbalance in the wage relationship nonetheless persists due to the inability of the trade union to truly defend the rights of the mingong within factories. According to Reference SongSong (2017), the presence of the ACFTU in companies does not have a positive effect on wages.Footnote 7 The lack of legitimate workers’ representatives contributes to the high level of conflicts in China. The ACFTU may provide individual legal assistance to workers, but never helps them to organise collective action, thus indirectly fostering spontaneous and often violent labour conflicts. Here is another example of institutional evolutionism: as an official part of the local Communist Party organisations, the ACFTU contributes to the economic goals of local authorities, which typically implies siding with employers in case of labour conflict and preventing any emergence of a trade-union alternative. The ACFTU is indeed given by the law the monopoly of representation of the Chinese workers (Reference Clarke and PringleClarke and Pringle, 2009).

It is therefore in the field of conflict management institutions that the official Chinese trade union has been creative, as demonstrated by its ‘cuts and pastes’ from labour relations institutions advocated by the ILO (Reference LeeLee, 2009). For the government, these so-called social dialogue institutions may somehow contain conflict escalation; however, employers who retain exclusive rights in defining employment conditions see no point in genuine negotiations. The wage policy is viewed as being the sole privilege of the employer and is often kept secret so that employees cannot grasp the mechanisms of wage negotiations (Reference Chan and SiuChan and Siu, 2010). A lack of negotiations on social benefits is also widespread, and there is an almost total lack of seniority-based promotion, and of job classification system within factories (Reference Lüthje, Luo and ZhangLüthje et al., 2013). On the other hand, entrepreneurs are suffering from this restrictive view of labour relations, which fosters experienced and skilled workers’ turnover and accentuates competition among firms to retain them. These labour problems are considered by Commons as a natural situation as long as the labour relation is only managed through authority. The process of collective bargaining therefore appears as the only way to avoid destructive conflicts in the capitalist system – what he calls ‘reasonable capitalism’. However, in China, the question of autonomous representation of workers remains out of sight despite rising discontent.Footnote 8

The rise in strikes since the 2008–2009 crisis has so far only produced limited new regulation in the matter of social dialogue (Reference Hui and ChanHui and Chan, 2016). Consequently, even the wages of skilled urban workers have stagnated: the 0.9% rise in wages for white-collar workers in 2017 only benefits a minority of ‘senior managers’, while inequalities are increasing between workers in big cities and ‘clerical workers’ in medium cities (China Labour Bulletin, 2017). Overall, Chinese labour institutions ensure the maximum individualisation of the employment relationship, thus upholding of a competitive menace on workers by lead firms and their Chinese suppliers (Reference KaufmanKaufman, 2010).

Low-wage trap versus Chinese-style Fordism?

The 2008–2009 crisis sounded the alarm and accelerated the transition towards a new economic policy to reorient the growth regime. Since then, Chinese leaders have been seeking to move away from being a low-cost supplier in order to benefit from a better educated and healthier workforce, increase the value-added of production, re-balance distribution in favour of wages and develop domestic demand in order to no longer have to depend on fluctuations in global demand (Reference ZhangZhang, 2016a). This goal still seems very distant as indicated by the decrease in the share of consumption in GDP, which despite a slow rise since 2007 (from 35% to 39% in 2016) remains one of the lowest in the world. However, the share of wages in household income is high in China, the highest in emerging or developing countries (ILO, 2014).

The recovery plan of 2010 has also generated contradictions: it served to develop infrastructure, particularly in underfunded regions, which improved opening-up. But it relied on an increase in investments rather than in household consumption and fuelled overcapacity in heavy industry. Furthermore, local authorities still have the ability to dilute national guidelines by prioritising ‘visible’ and effective economic results in the short term, which has led to a trend to limit as much as possible the effects on wages of pro-labour regulations, especially the 2007 Labour Contract Law.

Chinese growth has therefore relied on companies (all categories combined) extracting high levels of productivity for low wages even during the most recent period (Reference PiovaniPiovani, 2014; Reference Xu, Chen and LiXu et al., 2015). In the long run, this type of growth regime may turn against accumulation itself. Indeed, the effectiveness of this ‘competitive’ type of capitalism (Reference Boyer, Boyer, Uemura and IsogaiBoyer, 2011) is ultimately reflected in over-investment: while low wages create insufficient opportunities to develop domestic demand, the profitability of the capital invested is in constant decline (in 2017, investments still represent 45% of GDP). The tacit compromise between Chinese workers and the Communist Party could in the end not be profitable for anyone, as the competition between municipalities to attract investors and the exclusion of workers from the industrial relations institutions combine to hold back workers’ bargaining power (Reference SéhierSéhier, 2017a). The prospect of sustainable restitution of productivity gains over the long term through increased real wages as implemented in the form of a post-war Fordist compromise in Western countries seems, so far, out of reach in today’s China.

Impediments to the construction of a Chinese-style Fordist wage relationship

The absence of linkage between productivity and wages has been a characteristic of the Chinese wage relationship for decades (Reference PiovaniPiovani, 2014; Reference Xu, Chen and LiXu et al., 2015), thus undermining the scenario according to which there could be an evolution towards a Fordist type of wage relationship. The reasons have to be sought in the extreme diversity of production regimes in the key industrial sectors of the Chinese economy. Reference Lüthje, Luo and ZhangLüthje et al. (2013) bring to light the great heterogeneity of wage relationships in various industries (automotive, electronics, textiles and clothing), which reflects a large variety of sectoral and regional capital accumulation regimes. So far, insufficient industrial upgrading in the most profitable sectors like electronics thus reinforces the fragmentation of the Chinese production system (Reference WenWen, 2018), and the evolution towards a Fordist regime seems unlikely in the near future.

The combination of ‘intensive’ (such as high-tech parks) and ‘extensive’ (low value-added production) capital accumulation strategies within complex production networks is reflected in the coexistence of industrial sectors at different levels of development. These industries are themselves spread throughout regions with various specific features that are maintained by local government actions and combined with the strong divide between urban and rural areas. China could more precisely be described as having a ‘variety of capitalisms within one country’ (Reference LüthjeLüthje, 2014b: 6) where the divides inherited from the past have built resilient fault lines that show no overall trend towards an accumulation regime that connects a rise in capitalistic intensity, rapid productivity gains and higher wages.

In every key sector of the Chinese economy, labour standards and job flexibility within enterprises have been institutionalised to varying degrees, based on various combinations of specifically Chinese features inherited from socialism together with influences from Japanese, Western and Taiwanese models. This accounts for the consistent separation both between labour productivity and wages, and between the fast and ongoing enrichment of the country and the constant drop in the share of wages in the value-added. The attempt to reorient the Chinese economy towards the domestic market is beginning to somewhat bear fruit (Reference Lemoine, Poncet and ÜnalLemoine et al., 2015), but this only marginally benefits employees.

This is a situation that Reference CommonsJR Commons (1909) considered: an imbalance of powers in the wage relationship that contributes to creating divides within the labour force, which also helps us understand why the attempt of industrial upgrading following the crisis of 2008–2009 did not result in a major overhaul of production regimes and labour practices (Reference LüthjeLüthje, 2014b). For the moment, a Fordist accumulation regime, characterised by the redistribution of productivity gains to benefit real wages, does not represent a likely evolution for the Chinese economy, which continues to be characterised by the under-consumption of entire sections of the working class, including the most stable industrial urban labourers. The counterpart is very high household savings which until now has been justified by the almost complete absence of a social welfare system for a large portion of the population, as well as very high education costs.

The dismantling of social insurance provisions has in fact been one of the consequences of the privatisation and reorganisation of the public sector, leading to the exclusion of large segments of the Chinese population (Reference Ngok and HuangNgok and Huang, 2014). Efforts have been made to unify the social welfare system with the intention of including the entire working population in health and retirement insurance systems by 2020. The goal of the central government, however, is being met with resistance by local governments responsible for the financial management of this system. Concerned with maintaining their attractiveness to industrial manufacturers, they often baulk at claiming what they are owed from the companies, while the richest provinces delay redistribution to the poorest provinces. Here again, migrant workers are the worst off as the majority among them remain concretely excluded from the social welfare system (Reference Jiang, Qian and WenJiang et al., 2018; Reference SéhierSéhier, 2017b).

The inclusion of social criteria in the evaluation of local officials represents a small step to foster the implementation of the recent regulations, such as the 2011 Social Insurance Law. However, despite significant progress in terms of the amount of spending and the coverage rate at the national level, the level of insurance granted to each worker remains low. The efforts made to develop indirect wages thus do not compensate for the low increase in direct wages.

The recent escalation in the number of conflicts related to social welfare has shown that collective pressure exerted by the base could require executives and employers to effectively implement reforms that are favourable to workers. For example, the strikes that took place at the Yue Yuen factory in Dongguan in April 2014 united 40,000 workers, while the one at the Lide factory in Guangzhou a few months later led more than 2,500 workers to organise over several months to recover social security back pay. It should therefore not be overlooked that in spite of the hardening of the regime with regard to activists, Chinese officials and the trade union may be forced to accept a greater participation of workers in the development and implementation of social welfare provisions, which is the only way to respond to employees’ need for economic security (Reference PérissePérisse, 2017).

Conclusion

While China seems to have been generally successful in its transition from a planned economy to a market economy, a hasty assessment might lead one to believe that it is an example of a model of development based on Kuznets and Lewis, with the increase in real wages since the end of the 1990s indicating the end of the demographic dividend. A closer examination, however, leads to a more nuanced understanding of this scenario based solely on the mechanics of labour market flows: while Chinese growth since the early 1980s can indeed be characterised by turning rural population into wage labour, it was accompanied by a weak institutionalisation of employment relationships and led to a structural imbalance unfavourable to workers.

This specific institutional configuration has been successful for long-term integration into GVCs. This productive system operates at a global scale under the thumb of large companies headquartered in developed countries, where, due to the contractual nature of the relations between buyers and subcontractors, it is possible to obtain high productivity from Chinese workers, for which wages remain low. Thus, contrary to appearances, even though real wages are rising, the share of wages in the nation’s wealth has not kept pace. This situation in which workers are not able to obtain compensation that is at least equal to their productivity reflects a form of organisation that favours the capitalist entrepreneur, which institutional economist Reference CommonsJR Commons (1909) calls a ‘competitive menace’: the employer’s market power leads to non-competitive wages.

Beyond the perverse effects of a development model aligned with capital accumulation (rise in income inequality and rampant social unrest), any evolution towards a Fordist type of accumulation regime remains unrealistic. Even though the government has called for change since the 2008–2009 crisis, Chinese productive structures continue to be affected by the fragmentations inherited from socialism, the various foreign models imported, and the form of integration within global production networks. None of the key sectors of the Chinese economy presents a trajectory towards ’Chinese-style’ Fordism, nor have we seen a shift of productivity gains towards employees. On the contrary, the move towards flexible labour and production imposed by the MNCs and their subcontractors has accentuated wage inequalities within each industry.

This situation is the combined result of an experimental laissez-faire approach during the 1990–2000s, when China’s integration in GVCs benefitted from specific labour institutions, and of the persistent will of the Communist Party to restructure the public sector to erect national champions in strategic fields. Reference CommonsCommons (1934) considered that in the building of the legal rules of capitalism, the most powerful social groups are able to influence the state, particularly to protect property rights against labour and social rights. These rules are stabilised until new social groups claim a fairer recognition of their contribution to wealth creation, as is currently the case with the rise in mingongs’ strikes, and their demand of genuine citizenship (Reference PérissePérisse, 2017). Thus, Chinese authorities find themselves faced with a dilemma: how can they foster industrial upgrading and at the same time ensure active economic growth that guarantees employment for all workers, which is the only way to ensure the much-desired social stability?

Funding

The author(s) received no financial support for the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article.

Footnotes

1. Global value chain (GVC) analysis was popularised by Reference Gereffi, Humphrey and SturgeonGereffi et al. (2005) and at the beginning relied on the distinction between the Centre and the Periphery in the globalised capitalism developed by Reference Wallerstein and HopkinsWallerstein et al. (1982).

2. Collecting statistics regarding labour issues faces technical obstacles related to the size of the country and the prevalence of an informal workforce. The political sensitivity of the question of inequality further reinforces the need to be cautious concerning official figures.

3. According to the GVC literature, industrial upgrading results from the improvement of products, processes and functions (Reference Gereffi, Humphrey and SturgeonGereffi et al., 2005), while social upgrading refers to the improvements of workers’ rights and of the quality of their employment (Reference Barrientos, Gereffi and RossiBarrientos et al., 2011).

4. Minimum wage policy is in the hand of each local government who is required to update the minimum wage at least every 2 years, depending on the local level of development and costs of living.

5. In the GVCs, the ‘lead firms’ have greater resources in different key sectors (brand, design, access to capital, technological advantage and so forth), which is reflected in greater ‘market power’. These firms are mainly located in developed countries, as it is very difficult for countries in the South to develop their ‘market power’ (Reference FernándezFernández, 2014). Several Chinese ‘lead firms’ are nonetheless starting to emerge, as indicated by 109 of them being among the Fortune 500 in 2017.

6. While compensations in coastal cities increased in the wake of the minimum wage, it was not a widespread phenomenon. The improvement in the share of wages in the value-added since 2011 is mainly an effect of the sharp slowdown in the Chinese growth due to the combined effects of forced restructuring of the labour-intensive industries and the investment-biased stimulus packages operative since 2010 leading to over capacities and low profitability. Relocations to the inland provinces have thus been led by the search for competitive wages, and the sweating system has become more entrenched by the use of subcontracted labour agencies (Reference LüthjeLüthje, 2014a).

7. A non-governmental organisation (NGO) report on the collective disputes of teachers confirms the union’s ineffectiveness in supporting employees’ demands, including in the public sector (China Labour Bulletin, 2016).

8. Facing escalating social unrest in the early 2010s, Guangdong province leaders launched experiences to improve the representativeness of workers in collective bargaining, under the supervision of the local ACFTU (All-China Federation of Trade Unions) branches. But the pressure of local businesses and the tightening of Xi’s regime eventually led to renounce to the adoption of new regulations.

References

Almeida, R (2009) Openness and technological innovation in East Asia: have they increased the demand for skills? Discussion paper no. 4474. World Bank and IZA. Available at: http://ftp.iza.org/dp4474.pdf (accessed 28 January 2017).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barboza, D (2016) How China built ‘iPhone City’ with billions in perks for Apple’s partner. The New York Times, 29 December. Available at: https://www.nytimes.com/2016/12/29/technology/apple-iphone-china-foxconn.html (accessed 20 February 2019).Google Scholar
Barrientos, S (2013) ‘Labour chains’: analysing the role of labour contractors in global production networks. Journal of Development Studies 49(8): 10581071.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barrientos, S, Gereffi, G, Rossi, A (2011a) Economic and social upgrading in global production networks: a new paradigm for a new world. International Labour Review 150(3–4): 319340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barrientos, S, Mayer, F, Posthuma, A (2011b) Decent work in global production networks: framing the policy debate. International Labour Review 150(3–4): 297317.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boyer, R (2011) The Chinese growth regime and the world economy. In: Boyer, R, Uemura, H, Isogai, A (eds) Diversity and Transformations of Asian Capitalisms. Abingdon: Routledge, pp. 184205.Google Scholar
Butollo, F (2015) Moving beyond cheap labour? Industrial and social upgrading in the garment and LED industries of the Pearl River Delta. Journal of Current Chinese Affairs 42(4): 139170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cai, F (2018) Population dividend and economic growth in China, 1978-2018. China Economic Journal 11(3): 243258.Google Scholar
Cai, F, Du, Y (2011) Wage increases, wage convergence, and the Lewis turning point in China. China Economics Review 22(4): 601610.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chan, A, Siu, K (2010) Analyzing exploitation: The mechanisms underpinning low wages and excessive overtime in Chinese export factories. Critical Asian Studies 42(2): 167190.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chan, J, Pun, N, Selden, M (2015) Interns or workers? China’s student labor regime. The Asia-Pacific Journal 13(36): 125.Google Scholar
Chen, Q, Zhu, K, Chen, X , et al. (2018) Distinguishing China’s processing trade in the world input-output table and quantifying effects. Economic Systems Research. Epub ahead of print 23 October 2018. DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/09535314.2018.1534225.Google Scholar
Chen, Y (2019) The myth of Hukou: Re-examining hukou’s implications for China’s development model. Review of Radical Political Economics 51(2): 282297.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
China Labour Bulletin (2016) Over-worked and under-paid: The long-running battle of China’s teachers for decent work. China Labour Bulletin. Available at: http://www.clb.org.hk/sites/default/files/Teachers%20final.pdf (accessed 14 September 2017).Google Scholar
China Labour Bulletin (2017) China’s middle-class incomes fail to take off in 2017. China Labour Bulletin. Available at: http://www.clb.org.hk/content/china%E2%80%99s-middle-class-incomes-fail-take-2017 (accessed 14 September 2017)Google Scholar
China Labour Bulletin (2018) Converging demands in Chinese workers’ collective actions. China Labour Bulletin. Available at: http://clb.org.hk/content/converging-demands-chinese-workers%E2%80%99-collective-actions (accessed 30 August 2018).Google Scholar
Clarke, S, Pringle, T (2009) Can party-led trade unions represent their members? Post-Communist Economies 21(1): 85101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Commons, JR (1909) American shoemakers: 1648-1895: a sketch of industrial evolution. Quarterly Journal of Economics 24(1): 3984.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Commons, JR (1934) Institutional Economics: Its Place in Political Economy. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Cui, Y, Lu, C (2018) Are China’s unit labour costs still competitive? A comparison with ASEAN countries. Asian-Pacific Economic Literature 32(1): 5976.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cui, Y, Meng, J, Lu, C (2018) Recent developments in China’s labor market: labor shortage, rising wage and their implications. Review of Development Economics 22(3): 12171238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Das, M, N’Diaye, P (2013) Chronicle of a decline foretold: has China reached the Lewis turning point? International Monetary Fund, Working paper no. 13/26. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Available at: http://dragon-report.com/Dragon_Report/Challenges_files/wp1326.pdf (accessed 28 January 2017).Google Scholar
Fabre, G (2018) China’s digital transformation: Why is artificial intelligence a priority for Chinese RD? HAL Id: halshs-01818508. Available at: https://halshs.archives-ouvertes.fr/halshs-01818508v2/documentGoogle Scholar
Fernández, VR (2014) Global value chains in global political networks: tool for development or neoliberal device? Review of Radical Political Economics 47(2): 209230.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, E, Lee, CK (2010) Remaking the world of Chinese labour: a 30-year retrospective. British Journal of Industrial Relations 48(3): 507533.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gao, L, Yan, J, Du, Y (2018) Identifying the turning point of the urban-rural relationship: evidence from macro data. China & World Economy 26(1): 106126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gereffi, G, Humphrey, J, Sturgeon, T (2005) The governance of global value chains. Review of International Political Economy 12(2): 78104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gimet, C, Guilhon, B, Roux, N (2015) Social upgrading in globalized production: the case of the textile and clothing industry. International Labour Review 154(3): 303327.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayter, S (2004) The social dimension of global production systems: a review of the issues. Policy Integration Department, Working paper no. 25. Geneva: International Labour Organization.Google Scholar
Hering, L, Poncet, S (2009) The impact of economic geography on wages: disentangling the channels of influence. China Economic Review 20(1): 114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hui, ES-L, Chan, CK-C (2016) The influence of overseas business associations on law-making in China: a case study. The China Quarterly 225: 145168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
International Labour Organization (ILO) (2014) Global Wage Report. Geneva: ILO. Available at: http://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/—dgreports/—dcomm/—publ/documents/publication/wcms_324678.pdf (accessed 5 April 2017).Google Scholar
International Labour Organization (ILO) (2016a) Global Wage Report. Geneva: ILO. Available at: http://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/—dgreports/—dcomm/—publ/documents/publication/wcms_537846.pdf (accessed 5 April 2017).Google Scholar
International Labour Organization (ILO) (2016b) Wage, productivity and labour share in China. Research note, ILO Regional Office for Asia and the Pacific, April. Available at: https://www.ilo.org/wcmsp5/groups/public/—asia/—ro-bangkok/documents/publication/wcms_475254.pdf (accessed 15 January 2019).Google Scholar
Jiang, J, Qian, J, Wen, Z (2018) Social protection for the informal sector in urban China: institutional constraints and self-selection behaviour. Journal of Social Policy 47(2): 335357.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaufman, B (2010) Institutional economics and the minimum wage: broadening the theoretical policy debate. Industrial and Labour Relations Review 63(3): 427453.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaufman, B (2018) How capitalism endogenously creates rising income inequality and economic crisis: the macro political economy model of early industrial relations. Industrial Relations 57(1): 131173.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knight, J, Deng, Q, Li, S (2011) The puzzle of migrant labour shortage and rural labour surplus in China. China Economic Review 22(4): 585600.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Korzec, M, Howe, C (1992) Labour and the Failure of Reform in China. New York: St Martin’s Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuznets, S (1955) Economic growth and inequality. American Economic Review 45(1): 128.Google Scholar
Lakhani, T, Kuruvulla, S, Avgar, A (2013) From the firm to the network: global value chain and employment relations theory. British Journal of Industrial Relations 51(3): 440472.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, CH (2009) Industrial relations and collective bargaining in China. Working paper, October. Geneva: International Labour Organization. Available at: https://www.ilo.org/beijing/what-we-do/publications/WCMS_146612/lang–en/index.htmGoogle Scholar
Lemoine, F, Poncet, S, Ünal, D (2015) Spatial rebalancing and industrial convergence in China. China Economic Review 34(C): 3963.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, WA (1955) The Theory of Economic Growth. London: George Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Li, H, Li, L, Wu, B (2012) The end of cheap Chinese labour. Journal of Economic Perspectives 26(4): 5774.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, S (2016) Recent Changes in Income Inequality in China: World Social Science Report. Paris: UNESCO, pp. 8488.Google Scholar
Li, Y, Kanbur, R, Lin, C (2018) Minimum wage competition between local governments in China. The Journal of Development Studies. Epub ahead of print 30 October 2018. DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00220388.1536263.Google Scholar
Lüthje, B (2014a) Labour relations, production regimes and labour conflict in the Chinese automotive industry. International Labour Review 153(4): 535560.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lüthje, B (2014b) Why no Fordism in China? Regimes of accumulation and regimes of production in Chinese manufacturing industries. Working paper no. 3, January. Frankfurt am Main: Institut Für Sozialforschung. Available at: http://www.ifs.uni-frankfurt.de/wp-content/uploads/IfS-WP3-Luethje-Why-No-Fordism-in-China.pdf (accessed 14 September 2017).Google Scholar
Lüthje, B, Butollo, F (2017) Why the Foxconn model does not die: production networks and labour relations in the IT industry in South China. Globalizations 14(2): 216231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lüthje, B, Luo, S, Zhang, H (2013) Beyond the Iron Rice Bowl. Regimes of Production and Industrial Relations in China. Frankfurt; New York: Campus Verlag.Google Scholar
Marx, K (2015 [1887]) Capital: A Critic of Political Economy (trans. Fowkes, B), vol. 1. London: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
McIntyre, R, Ramstad, Y (2004) Not only Nike’s doing it: ‘Sweating’ and the contemporary labour market. In: Champlin, DP, Koedler, JT (eds) The Institutionalist Tradition in Labour Economics. London: M. E. Sharpe, pp. 297313.Google Scholar
Nathan, D, Sarkar, S (2011) A note on profits, rents and wages in global production networks. Economic and Political Weekly 46(36): 5357. Available at: http://www.capturingthegains.org/pdf/EPW_xlvi_36.pdf (accessed 28 January 2017).Google Scholar
National Bureau of Statistics China (NBS) (2016) Investigative report on the monitoring of rural migrant workers (2015年农民工监测调查报告). Available at: http://www.stats.gov.cn/tjsj/zxfb/201704/t20160428_1349713.html (accessed 28 May 2017).Google Scholar
National Bureau of Statistics China (NBS) (2016) Investigative report on the monitoring of the country’s migrant workers in 2015 (2016年农民工监测调查报告). Available at: http://www.stats.gov.cn/tjsj/zxfb/201704/t20170428_1489334.html (accessed 30 June 2018).Google Scholar
Ngok, KL, Huang, G (2014) Policy paradigm shift and the changing role of the state: the development of social policy in China since 2003. Social Policy and Society 13(2): 251261.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Périsse, M (2017) Labour law in China: how does it contribute to the economic security of the workforce? A Commonsian reading. Journal of Economic Issues 51(1): 126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piovani, C (2014) Class power and China’s productivity miracle: applying the labour extraction model to China’s industrial sector, 1980-2007. Review of Radical Political Economy 46(3): 331354.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rossi, A, Luinstra, A, Pickles, J , et al. (2014) Towards Better Work: Understanding Labour in Apparel Globalization Chains (Advances in Labour Studies). Geneva: International Labour Organization.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Séhier, C (2017a) Can the Chinese government rebalance the accumulation regime? An analysis through the transformations of the wage-labour nexus. Revue de la régulation. Available at: http://regulation.revues.org/12241 (accessed 5 April 2017).Google Scholar
Séhier, C (2017b) The erratic development of labour welfare in China. Geopolitica 6(1): 91118.Google Scholar
Solinger, D (1999) Contesting Citizenship in Urban China: Peasant Migrants, the State, and the Logic of the Market. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Song, Y (2017) Six central features of the Chinese labour market. International Labour Review 156(2): 213242.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walder, A (1986) Communist Neo-traditionalism: Work and Authority in Chinese Industry. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Wallerstein, I, Hopkins, TK (1982) World-Systems Analysis: Theory and Methodology. Beverly Hills, CA: SAGE.Google Scholar
Wen, D (2018) Domestic value-added in China’s exports to the world and its partners. The Chinese Economy 51(1): 4568.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Xu, Z, Chen, Y, Li, M (2015) Are Chinese workers paid the correct wages? Measuring wage underpayment in the Chinese industrial sector, 2005-2010. Review of Radical Political Economics 47(3): 446459.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, L (2016a) Rebalancing in China, progress and prospects. Working paper, WP/16/183. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Available at: https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2016/wp16183.pdf (accessed 28 January 2017).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, W (2016b) The evolution of China’s pay inequality from 1987 to 2012. Journal of Current Chinese Affairs 45(2): 183217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, Y, Shao, T, Dong, Q (2018) Reassessing the Lewis turning point in China: evidence from 70,000 rural households. China & World Economy 26(1): 417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhu, S, Pickles, J (2014) Bring in, go up, go west, go out: upgrading, regionalisation and delocalisation in China’s apparel production networks. Journal of Contemporary Asia 44(1): 3663.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Real annual wages of Chinese urban workers 1978–2015 (RMB).Sources: China Statistical Yearbooks, various years, Tables 4–11.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Annual average wages of urban workers by region 2004–2015 (RMB).Sources: China Statistical Yearbooks, various years, Tables 4–16.Coastal provinces: Beijing, Tianjin, Shanghai, Jiangsu, Zhejiang, Fujian, Shandong, Guangdong, Hebei and Hainan.

Figure 2

Figure 3. Labour productivity and average labour compensation in China, 2000–2013 (100 = 2000 base year).Source: ILO (2016b: Figure 6).

Figure 3

Figure 4. China’s Labour Share in GDP (%), 1978–2015.Source: Cui et al. (2018: 1237).Total bill of employees in urban units.