Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-vdxz6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T18:58:00.728Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Regulation of Informal Trade Credit (Ograyi) in Afghanistan

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  08 June 2021

Nafay Choudhury*
Affiliation:
Institute for Global Law and Policy, Harvard Law School, Cambridge
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This article explores the creation, circulation, and regulation of informal trade credit or “ograyi” in Afghanistan. The practice of ograyi allows businesses to access short-term credit, from either their suppliers or third parties, to acquire specified goods. This paper provides an account of the non-legal practices that regulate ograyi transactions. Ograyi vitally depends on the development of trust between parties. Clientelism helps to maintain stable relationships that can offset market unpredictability. Widespread market norms and practices establish the general behaviour of participants. Parties also renegotiate the terms of the contract if circumstances make it impossible for the creditor to repay the loan in the agreed timeframe. Furthermore, bank credit remains largely unavailable or unappealing to many businesses, and the legal system provides limited recourse in the case of contractual breach. Thus, the non-legal practices regulating ograyi serve as a substitute for legal coercion.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2021. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Asian Journal of Law and Society

1. Introduction

Despite international and domestic efforts geared at strengthening Afghanistan’s legal system, state law remains completely absent in much of Afghan social life. Nearly two decades of research have documented the profound normative pluralism that marks society.Footnote 1 Alongside enacted laws, Islamic and customary norms remain widely in circulation—often fusing with one another, thereby assuming a hybrid form that mixes the two though staying true to neither.Footnote 2 In many ways, this arrangement has not only been viewed as desirable, but even as necessary for the functioning of the state, since unofficial normative practices help to provide a source of order and stability that cannot be achieved solely through the formal legal system.Footnote 3

Against this backdrop, this article looks at the creation, circulation, and regulation of informal trade credit in the Afghan economy. When goods are transferred between a seller and a purchaser, the latter may lack the requisite funds to complete the transaction but may nonetheless be in a position to repay any funds received once he has acquired the items and resold them. Such instances are very common in Afghanistan, particularly since individual wealth is low, but traders and merchants still import a significant quantity of goods from abroad involving the regular turnover of high volumes of funds. The economy has thus developed a practice known as “ograyi,” which allows businesses to access short-term credit for their transactions in the form of trade credit, usually from their suppliers, but also from third parties. Ograyi is pervasive throughout the country, as anyone involved in business activities will be familiar with its operation, despite remaining relatively unknown to lay individuals. One cannot properly understand the Afghan economy unless one appreciates the functioning of ograyi, as it plays such a crucial role in the way businesses transact with one another. This study focuses on the regulatory practices that facilitate the operation of ograyi. This study shows the combination of factors that businesses rely upon to regulate their credit relations: (1) investing in relationships, thereby allowing trust to accrue over time; (2) relying on clientelism; (3) acting according to widespread market norms and practices; and (4) renegotiating contract terms in the event of a breach. This study further explains the challenges that banks face in providing businesses with credit and the difficulty in relying on courts for contractual enforcement.

The second part of the paper provides a brief review of how communities in different settings globally have been able to provide informal credit to individuals and businesses. The third part details the research methodology employed. The fourth part provides a background on Afghanistan’s economy and its markets, which helps to explain the need for informal credit. The fifth part details the general practice of ograyi in Afghanistan. The sixth part is the heart of the paper and details the factors that facilitate the regulation of informal trade credit. The seventh part explains the shortcomings of the country’s banking system, which bolsters the widespread practice of ograyi. The eighth part details the challenges of seeking recourse through courts. The paper strives to show how informal credit in Afghanistan—an economy-wide practice—is regulated almost entirely through a combination of personal trust, non-legal practices, and community norms. These factors serve as a substitute for formal legal coercion, as the courts provide limited relief to aggrieved businesses.

2. Background on local-level credit

The availability of credit is an essential aspect of a functioning market system.Footnote 4 Credit facilitates macroeconomic growth by allowing businesses to expand their activities by gaining access to resources that would otherwise be unavailable.Footnote 5 While, in developed societies, banks are the primary mode through which people are able to acquire credit, individuals in many developing societies remain unable to access such channels. A significant portion of people across the world work in the informal economy—that is, in economic activities that lack registration and that are not directly regulated by the state.Footnote 6 Such societies have often created their own community-level mechanisms that provide individuals with credit so that they may meet their respective needs. In general, these lending practices may be termed “informal credit” and the markets they create may be referred to as “informal credit markets.”Footnote 7

Three common arrangements designed to provide informal credit include rotating savings and credit associations (ROSCAs), pawnbrokers, and trade credit.Footnote 8 In a ROSCA, a group of people agree to individually contribute money towards a communal savings fund over a fixed period of time.Footnote 9 The total funds are then made available to each member on a rotating basis until all of the members have once been able to use the full pot of collected funds, after which the funds are returned to their respective contributors. Pawnbrokering involves a broker who provides another party with credit after detaining some form of collateral from the latter, often gold, jewellery, or some other movable item of value, thereby mitigating the risk of non-payment.Footnote 10 Pawnbrokering is likewise widespread across the developing and developed world, largely owing to its simplicity.Footnote 11 ROSCAs and pawnbrokers allow parties to avoid both the bureaucracy associated with formal institutionsFootnote 12 and credit evaluations.Footnote 13

Afghan society hosts a number of practices that bear functional similarities to ROSCAs and pawnbrokering. The sharing of credit amongst a group of individuals is often accomplished through the qawm—a porous concept often used to describe a “community,” which demarcates social insiders and outsiders.Footnote 14 Afghanistan is a networked society in which people are held together by densely overlapping social ties between family members and close friends.Footnote 15 Wealth is often maintained within these communities, as members will support each other with loans if a member requires assistance.Footnote 16 Nonetheless, while a qawm may provide a minimum social safety net for its members, it often lacks the necessary wealth for businesses to be able to scale up their activities. Pawnbrokering in Afghanistan is accomplished through the practice of gerawi, which involves the pledge of property—usually land—to a creditor in exchange for financing.Footnote 17 The level of credit provided is usually much less than the value of the land detained, and the land is returned to the debtor once the loan is repaid. During this period, the creditor is able to benefit from the use of the land, whether for his own use or in leasing it out to a third party.Footnote 18 One of the limitations of gerawi is the limited size of loans provided. As will be explained in this paper, sizeable credit is often required by traders, who buy and sell high volumes of goods but who do not necessarily own significant collateralizable wealth.

An alternate way for a party to gain credit is directly from the supplier who provides the goods—a practice known as trade credit.Footnote 19 The purchaser takes possession of items on credit and repays the outstanding amount along with interest at a future date. The credit is usually provided by the supplier specifically for the acquisition of particular goods. One reason why this arrangement persists is that suppliers may be in a better position than banks to assess and monitor credit arrangements.Footnote 20 For example, within New York’s diamond industry, one finds an elaborate trade financing system between large diamond “sight holders” and smaller “dealers.”Footnote 21 While banks may be reluctant to finance a dealer because they lack the specialized knowledge required to value gems, they may have greater confidence in financing larger sight holders who have better credit ratings; subsequently, these sight holders can use this credit to finance dealers while also assuming the monitoring costs as an industry insider.

In developing countries, small and medium-sized enterprises often find trade credit crucial for their business.Footnote 22 Many enterprises operate in the informal economy, or alternately may be formally registered but still unable to receive a bank loan. These businesses thus turn to informal credit for acquiring goods. Suppliers in countries with weak legal systems must be particularly cautious in ensuring that a potential debtor business can be trusted to repay the loan. New businesses thus face particular challenges in gaining credit, since, in the absence of a strong state or functioning legal system, firms depend on trust and reputation, which new entrants are naturally lacking.Footnote 23 Relational contracting is one means by which suppliers and purchasers are able to build trust with one another.Footnote 24 The supplier can rely on repeated-game incentives, since the purchaser will want to maintain ties with the supplier for future opportunities.Footnote 25 In the event of an eventual breach of contract, a party may not always be able to rely on sanctions such as reputational damage within the community of businesspeople.Footnote 26 Suppliers will often go to great lengths to renegotiate the terms of the contract, even if it entails a loss, since they see no hope of legal recourse.Footnote 27

A series of studies by John MacMillan and Christopher Woodruff looks at the regulation of informal credit in Vietnam. Within the Vietnamese private sector, businesses provide informal credit without relying on courtsFootnote 28 ; instead, businesses ensure contractual fulfilment by scrutinizing potential partners, invoking community sanctions, using written contracts to avoid ambiguities, and taking partial payments in advance for goods supplied.Footnote 29 Spreading negative gossip across business networks can also provide a means of sanctioning recalcitrant parties. A comparison of Vietnam with Eastern European countries revealed that “[s]ocial networks and reputation appear … to serve as substitutes for functioning legal systems, while business networks function better when courts are effective.”Footnote 30 These seminal studies of the Vietnamese context demonstrate the importance of studying the local environments in order to understand how different legal and non-legal arrangements may help to sustain informal credit markets.

The existing literature on informal credit largely focuses on the economic and structural details of the arrangement: the barriers faced by young firms in accessing trade creditFootnote 31 ; the variations in the types of organizations that provide trade credit and under what conditionsFootnote 32 ; and whether trade credit complements or substitutes for credit from financial institutions.Footnote 33 This literature has been far less preoccupied with the governance mechanisms of informal trade credit. While the works of MacMillan and Woodruff make a significant contribution in addressing this gap, the limited scope of their studies—based on quantitative data and interviews—leaves the door open for more varied explorations of the various governance mechanisms that may be implicated.

The current study on informal credit practices in Afghanistan provides a granular account of the practices, social structures, and market forces that provide a regulatory framework. A sustained study of the markets of Kabul sheds light on the microdynamics of interactions between actors that animate business life. Supplanting interviews with prolonged participant observations of market activities helps to provide a thick description of the various factors impacting the regulation of credit without making a priori assumptions on dependent and independent variables—and their relative weighting—characteristic of qualitative studies.Footnote 34 This study shows how a combination of trust relationship, clientelism, market norms and practices, and contract renegotiation help to ensure that trade credit transactions are fulfilled by debtors.

Informal credit permeates virtually every aspect of the Afghan economy despite the limited attention it has received within existing scholarship. Informal credit practices have been recorded from at least the late nineteenth century when hawala transfers (i.e. informal money transfers) represented Bills of Exchange.Footnote 35 At present, the informal mobile vendors that inundate the streets of Kabul largely rely on informal trade credit.Footnote 36 These vendors acquire their goods on credit and then repay their suppliers in instalments. In rural areas, informal credit helps to play a consumption-smoothing role, since families, largely relying on agricultural income, may face income shortages.Footnote 37 In the illicit opium market, opium cultivation is one of the few available sources of credit for poor people through the practice of salaam in which advances are made by landowners or third parties for future crops.Footnote 38 The existing literature nonetheless fails to capture the extent to which informal trade credit pervades the overall economy, as it is integral for the operation of businesses throughout the country, particularly those acquiring goods from abroad. Furthermore, virtually no study focuses on the governance aspects of the circulation of informal credit, which seems particularly important given the risks inherent in credit, the weaknesses of the legal system, and the economy-wide shortage of resources. This article thus addresses a gap in the current literature by focusing on the governance of informal trade credit in Afghanistan, as the practice helps to mobilize large amounts of capital amongst businesses.

3. Research methods

Various methods were employed during the course of this study, particularly interviews and participant observation. The researcher conducted an ethnographic study of Afghan markets between August 2017 and July 2018 for a wider doctoral project, and the data for this paper are based on a subset of the interviews and observations. In total, 57 interviews inform this study and can be broken down as follows: 31 business persons; 12 bank officials; five government officials; five central-bank officials; two judges; two litigation lawyers.

3.1 Semi-structured interviews

Significant time was spent in the markets of Kabul speaking with businesses to understand how they conducted transactions. Businesses ranged in size from a single person to a business with over 100 employees. The size of the latter was a distant exception, as businesses with 5–20 employees was the norm.Footnote 39 All interviews were conducted in Kabul, and the majority took place in Mandawi, the central market for merchants and traders.

Business people were generally suspicious towards questions on their affairs. Academic research is still in its infancy in the country, particularly on economic matters. Thus, a continued issue that I faced was being viewed as a spy or—just as bad—an undercover tax collector. I thus relied on introductions by third parties.Footnote 40 Periodic visits also helped to build trust, as businessmen were happy to see my continued presence over a sustained period of time. Conversations with banking officials allowed me to understand how credit could be accessed through the banks.

3.2 Participant observation

I spent much of my time in the market-place alongside businessmen to understand the rhythm of their lives. Being in the market over the course of several months gave me exposure to some of the mundane practices that often go unnoticed. For example, shop owners would spend significant amounts of time talking with others in the market, whether over chai or in chance encounters. Such meetings helped to reaffirm social ties while also playing an information-sharing role. I also spent significant time in the offices of banking officials, observing their day-to-day activities and engaging in casual conversations to understand how they balanced between objectively upholding banking standards and maintaining social ties with those around them.

3.3 Judicial decisions

Unfortunately, written decisions were not particularly helpful, as the records were incomplete and, even when they existed, they often lacked many substantive details.Footnote 41 Thus, an alternate strategy was to collect the laws related to businesses, credit, and court procedures, and then gauge them against the experiences of those involved in court proceedings. For the latter, I gleaned information from judges, lawyers, and litigants, particularly businesses that decided to take their disputes to court.

4. Overview of Afghanistan’s economy

Trade is the economic bloodline of Afghanistan. Traders and merchants ensure that every possible good is imported into Afghanistan, including electronic goods, foodstuffs, medicines, and clothing items. The greatest volume of imports come from the neighbouring countries of Pakistan, Iran, and China, as well as other nearby countries, including Uzbekistan, India, Tajikistan, Russia, Turkey, and the United Arab Emirates (UAE).Footnote 42 Even during the Taliban government in the 1990sFootnote 43 as well as during the early parts of the twentieth century,Footnote 44 trade formed a central component of the Afghan economy. Because all the major routes to Kabul—and Afghanistan—are by land, virtually all these items arrive by transport truck.Footnote 45 The items arriving from abroad ensure that people are able to meet their daily needs. The cost of transporting goods along with the very low income of people throughout the country results in the items entering the country being of infamously poor quality.Footnote 46

The data below from the World Bank provide an indication of the extent to which imports play a central role in the economy (Figure 1). Since the fall of the Taliban in 2001 and the reconstruction of the country, the value of imports have amounted to well over 50% of the gross domestic product (GDP) (except in the last three years; see Figure 2).Footnote 47 In 2018, the countries supplying the most goods to Afghanistan were Pakistan (USD $1.3 billion), Iran (USD $1.2 billion), China (USD $1.18 billion), and Kazakhstan (USD $0.87 billion), corresponding to those countries in closest geographic proximity.

Figure 1. The value of imports and exports for Afghanistan. Source: Based on data from the World Bank.

Figure 2. Imports as a percentage of the GDP. Source: Based on data from the World Bank.

Many of these imported goods eventually find their way to the area of Mandawi. The famous street of Mandawi in the heart of Kabul has become shorthand for the central merchant market, covering an area of just a few square kilometres.Footnote 48 Incongruous buildings occupy every nook and cranny, as businesses compete not only to sell their products, but also for a space in which to carry out their affairs. While, on the face of it, Mandawi may seem like any other sprawling bazaar in Afghanistan, its distinguishing feature is the role of its more innocuous traders and merchants. Those selling directly to the public occupy the storefronts facing the street, whereas traders normally have their offices in more discrete locations within building courtyards, away from the bustle of daily traffic.

Traders—in the thousands in Mandawi—serve as clearing houses for goods that arrive from abroad.Footnote 49 Traders operate as wholesalers who distribute their goods to stores, businesses clients, or individual customers. This distribution network emanating from Mandawi extends well beyond the market and city into various parts of the country.Footnote 50 Traders are continually on the move, monitoring the delivery and quality of items from abroad and subsequently distributing goods to clients. They often travel around the city to collect payments from their customers.

Afghan traders possess a vast regional network that facilitates the well-organized movement of goods.Footnote 51 Many spend significant amounts of time outside the country where they are able to facilitate the initial acquisition of goods from abroad, leaving the day-to-day grunt-work to employees, often family members. Some traders set up offices in foreign countries, spending part of the year abroad purchasing goods and the remainder of the year distributing those goods in Kabul. Some even relocate to the foreign country altogether, thereby becoming involved exclusively in the supply-side of goods to Afghanistan.Footnote 52 Afghan traders thus form elaborate networks that facilitate the movement of goods from neighbouring countries to various parts of Afghanistan.

While the interactions of these traders with local and foreign businesses form the human architecture for the movement of goods, underlying these transactions are economic relationships. The practice of ograyi allows buyers to access credit to acquire goods, with the loan being repaid at a later time.

5. General practice of ograyi

Often, businesses will not have the requisite funds to pay their suppliers on the purchase date. Gaining access to credit is particularly difficult in Afghanistan given that the economy is stretched for resources. Potential creditors legitimately fear that their funds may disappear given the fluctuations in the market or as a result of a bad business decision on the part of the debtor (even those that are well intentioned). Debtors may also abscond with funds to another country, leaving the creditor without any recourse. Furthermore, banks are very conservative in their lending practices, making them largely inaccessible to traders. For this reason, market participants have come to rely on informal trade credit or ograyi.

Wholesalers are aware that the businesses that purchase their goods will often have insufficient funds to purchase a large stock outright. Rather, the purchaser will slowly accrue funds over a period of time by selling these goods. Thus, the purchaser will ask his supplier for an ograyi arrangement in which the stock of goods is acquired with a supply-side line of credit, thereby allowing him to receive the goods and pay the outstanding debt through weekly instalments. The two parties agree in advance on the weekly amount to be repaid. Often, an employee of the supplier’s shop will make weekly visits to those businesses with which it has an ograyi arrangement to collect payments until their outstanding debts have been fully repaid. While different credit arrangements exist in Afghanistan, ograyi specifically relates to credit circulating amongst businesses to facilitate the purchase and sale of goods.Footnote 53 Unlike other forms of credit available to parties, ograyi is generally unsecured and thus exposes the creditor to significant risks. Ograyi is the most common mode of financing for traders and merchants who import goods from abroad. The local industrial and production sectors in Afghanistan are very limited and incapable of meeting the needs of the population,Footnote 54 thereby necessitating foreign goods.

The supply chain of particular goods may involve several ograyi arrangements. For example, an initial supplier—possibly in China—may provide ograyi to a wholesaler in Kabul, who then provides ograyi to another business in Kabul, who subsequently provides ograyi to a smaller shop in the neighbouring province of Parwan (and the lay customers of this shop may even acquire the goods for personal use on credit). Ograyi thus facilitates goods being distributed widely throughout society. At each level, buyers will repay their immediate suppliers through periodic payments. While this network of connections created by ograyi may entail greater potential for profits, it also carries greater risks, since delays in payment by any debtor will have a cascading effect upwards in the supply chain. This risk is partially counterbalanced by the fact that creditors at each stage are generally better capitalized than their debtors. Furthermore, providing credit entails possessing a level of financial capital, since, below a certain threshold, any credit provided to a buyer would start cutting into the operating expenses of the creditor’s business.

Ograyi may take two general forms: (1) supply-side credit; and (2) cash credit from a money currency exchanger for the purchase of specified goods. In both instances, the creditor reaps a profit from the transaction.Footnote 55 The first case of ograyi as supply-size credit is common when both businesses are located within Afghanistan and when the supplier possesses sufficient capital. When both businesses are within the country, the supplier is able to regularly interact and monitor the debtor, thereby exerting pressure to ensure repayment. The creditor sells the item at its regular price plus a markup, thereby profiting not just from the sale of the item, but additionally from the fee associated with the delay in payment.

The second form of ograyi becomes necessary when the supplier is unwilling or unable to provide credit, and thus a third party must be introduced to facilitate the transaction. Many businesses only accept full payment for the item being sought. Suppliers in neighbouring countries without a presence in Afghanistan may be particularly reluctant to provide goods on credit, as they are unable to continuously monitor debtors and would lack any recourse in the case of a recalcitrant party. In these instances, Afghan money currency exchangers play a crucial role in facilitating the transaction. Exchangers are able to provide funds to businesses in the form of credit tied to the acquisition of specified goods. In this way, the ograyi arrangement is between the exchanger and the business acquiring the goods, without the involvement of the supplier. The exchanger assumes the risk in the event of a default.Footnote 56 According to central-bank regulations, exchangers are not permitted to accept savings deposits or offer ograyi to their clientsFootnote 57 ; however, the challenges of strict financial oversight have allowed the practice to continue with minimal state interference.

Ograyi is an important transaction for exchangers, as it keeps their capital in circulation, thereby generating profits.Footnote 58 The debtor is able to acquire goods for his business while the exchanger benefits from the service charges associated with the credit transaction. Furthermore, when a money exchanger offers ograyi, it is often combined with other services. As the supplier of the goods is often located abroad, the exchanger facilitates the hawala transaction. The exchange rate for the money being sent abroad to purchase the foreign goods will be set by the exchanger and will include a profit margin.Footnote 59 The gains from these various services can quickly accumulate, especially if the business taking credit makes timely repayments to the exchanger and quickly requests new transactions. For an exchanger, if an excess of funds were to remain idle, it would potentially represent a lost opportunity.

Ograyi became particularly widespread in Afghanistan after 2002 when hundreds of millions of dollars in aid money starting flowing into the country.Footnote 60 In 2010, Obama announced his Afghanistan strategy, which entailed transforming the country into a functioning democracy with Western-style state institutionsFootnote 61 ; subsequently, imports drastically increased. Between 2009 and 2012, the level of imports increased by over 50%.Footnote 62 The circulation of credit in the market during this period can be likened to the US economy prior to the collapse of the market due to subprime mortgages. People had general confidence in the market (even if ill placed), with the belief that new opportunities would continue steadily.Footnote 63 The sheer volume of international aid kept the entire economy afloat, which in turn helped traders because of the greater demand for imported goods.

The country’s economy took a drastic turn after 2014 when US troops began phasing out of the country and foreign funding largely dried up. Between 2014 and 2016, the level of imports significantly shrunk by nearly 25%.Footnote 64 Less foreign money entering the country translated into a significant reduction in the demand for goods across the economy. Many exchangers saw their reserves of capital shrink, whether due to businesses unable to repay their debts or investors who had reclaimed their funds. As the economy slowed after 2014, people lost their general confidence in the market and exchangers became much more cautious when providing ograyi to businesses.

Before going into the details on the informal regulation of ograyi, it is helpful to situate the practice within the wider institutional landscape of the country. In many societies, banks and other financial intermediaries perform the function of providing credit to eligible individuals and businesses.Footnote 65 Credit bureaus perform the role of gathering information so that creditors can make decisions about the creditworthiness of potential debtors. Many developing countries lack functioning credit bureaus and, even when present, they often only cover formally registered businesses even if a significant number of businesses operate in the informal sector. In such cases, assessments of creditworthiness end up being assumed by the creditors. In Afghanistan, banks face formidable challenges in assessing creditworthiness and, for this reason, they are overcapitalized and also have high collateral requirements.Footnote 66 Within the economic-development literature, some argue that stronger property rights can provide greater access to credit by making land collateralizable.Footnote 67 However, some 80% of land in Afghanistan is unregistered,Footnote 68 making it difficult for banks to use land as collateral in many cases.Footnote 69 Furthermore, businesses seeking to enforce contracts, including collateral contracts, require a functioning legal system with fair and efficient courts. However, corruption and inefficiency plague Afghan courts, rendering them amongst the worst legal fora globally for contractual enforcement.Footnote 70 Ograyi thus operates within an institutional environment in which banks are overcapitalized, collateral is suspect, property rights are weak, and the legal system is plagued by various shortcomings.

6. Informal regulation of ograyi

Ograyi allows parties to capitalize on opportunities lying outside of their immediate web of personal ties, since such networks may possess limited wealth. Building informal credit relationships with those outside of one’s immediate social circle creates new opportunities, which, in Afghanistan, plays a central role in the running of the entire economy.

Thus far, the discussion over informal credit paints a picture of what happens within the economy. However, what crucially remains to be answered is how this system of informal credit works, as it entails significant risks for creditors. This section looks at the various mechanisms that informally regulate the circulation of informal trade credit. Credit vitally depends on the development of trust between parties. Clientelism helps to maintain stable relationships that can offset market unpredictability. Various norms and practices have also become widespread, thereby establishing a general routine of behaviour for market participants. Finally, in the event of contractual breach, parties make efforts to renegotiate the terms of the contract.

6.1 Developing trust between parties

At its very core, the issuance of credit requires trust between two parties. Credit will not be offered if the parties do not trust each another.Footnote 71 Unfortunately, rampant corruption has eroded trust in public institutions, as Afghanistan ranks as one of the most corrupt countries in the world (172 out of 180 countries in 2018 in terms of corruption)Footnote 72 with individuals harbouring suspicion towards the government. People have little faith in the ability of public institutions to hold individuals accountable and, as a consequence, generalized, impersonal trust between people is weak.Footnote 73 Businesses expend significant resources in developing channels of trust that can help to mobilize credit. The process of trust creation thus warrants attention.

6.1.1 Building a reputation

Reputation is crucial for any business in the market. A business’s reputation has a direct impact on their ability to seek out opportunities. Building a reputation allows a business to signal to others that it is willing to undertake transactions that require faith in its abilities.

One of the principle means of building a reputation is by repaying debts in a timely manner. A business builds its reputation for being creditworthy by showing prompt repayments in a string of transactions over time. Timely debt repayments signal to others that a business is true to their word and thus can serve as a reliable partner. Conversely, being unpredictable or unreliable in repayments will damage a business’s reputation and thus its ability to attract business partners with whom it can arrange an ograyi transaction. Parties are aware that their second-party interactions may bear on their future relationships with a wide range of businesses, as information travels quickly across the market.

Expanding operations is another means by which a business can bolster its reputation. When a business is able to increase the size of its operations, it signals that it is financially strong. Increasing the volume of its activities, number of employees, or number of branch offices can all play a role in indicating that a business is growing. When a business is performing well, information on its good standing circulates throughout the market.

Religion and morality also play an important role in bolstering the reputation of businesses. Good religious character is associated with economic success.Footnote 74 One customer attributed the success of his supplier to his religious character: “He’s a good Muslim, that’s why his business is doing so well.” A business person signals his morally upright character through acts of charity, daily religious prayers, and religious gatherings for important events such as the purchase of a new house or the birth of child. Conversely, if a person cheats another or absconds with money, he may be accused of “not being a Muslim,” which is not to be taken literally, but rather as an indication of the moral worth of the party.

The influence that religion has on one’s reputation is most evident with respect to interest-bearing activities. Islamic law generally prohibits the charging of interest when funds are loaned to another party.Footnote 75 This prohibition on interest (locally called sood) is widely understood in the market and often serves as a metric of religiosity. Businesses engaging in interest-bearing transactions would be labelled sood-khur (a pejorative title that literally means “eating interest”). Other businesses would also distance themselves from the impugned business to protect their own reputation. Nonetheless, many businesses will devise workarounds, such as carrying out interest-bearing transactions in private or employing legal devices to hide the interest in a more involved transaction. An example of the latter is when the debtor is asked to repay the loan in a foreign currency and the creditor sets a higher-than-normal exchange rate such that it covers the outstanding principle plus a markup, which effectively serves as interest.Footnote 76

6.1.2 Pre-screening clients

A potential creditor starts the screening process of a debtor by entering into discussions with the goal of understanding its general activities. The creditor will amass information on its relationship with past and present clients, thereby assessing its reputation and character. This allows the creditor to gauge how co-operative the business has been in past dealings and its record in making timely payments. A visual inspection—possibly unannounced—of the business’s office can help to reveal any potential irregularities, such as lack of any activity or maintenance.

It is not a requirement that a potential debtor should have a previous relationship with credit or be a family relation. The entire exercise of assessing a new debtor and building trust between the parties is meant to unlock untapped potential through new social and economic linkages. The parties will often be strangers, and thus the debtor will seek to prove that his business is successfully running and capable of turning a profit from the loan. Creditors are in fact particularly cautious about giving loans to close family members, as they often have difficulty in recuperating funds from such clients. One money exchanger mentioned:

We give small loans to our friends. Sometimes for family members, friends, and so on, the loans are up to $10,000. However, after three to four months, they have still not returned [the sum] back to us. And we have difficulty reclaiming the full amount.

When the transaction is between family members or close friends, the economic ties may become blended with non-economic links, such as kinship, ethnicity, and otherwise. The creditor thus risks becoming bogged down due to over-socialization.Footnote 77 While the difference between socialized and over-socialized ties is a matter of degree, one distinguishing feature is whether the relationship primarily rests on economic or non-economic times. With close family members, since the ties are often primarily non-economic, debtors have a greater preponderance to be lax in their repayments, relying on their social ties to make up for the deficiency in their economic obligations.

Generally, potential creditors are wary about businesses that exhibit sudden changes in behaviour. If a new business rapidly expands its activity, a potential creditor will be suspicious about its source of wealth and customer base, particularly if the business is relatively unknown by others in the market.Footnote 78 Reputation is built gradually over time, and thus greater esteem is afforded to businesses that have expanded their operations incrementally as it evidences their ability to weather the contingencies of the market. Similarly, if a business with a long-standing presence in the market suddenly alters its conduct, either by suddenly seeking larger amounts of credit or changing its core operations (such as replacing its main product of sale with another), it may be an indication that the business is facing financial difficulty and pursuing a new strategy to remain afloat.

6.1.3 Gradual accretion of social capital

Similar to physical capital, trust between parties is a form of social capital that gains value over time.Footnote 79 Trust is highly valued because, like the millions of dollars being transacted daily, it is a scarce resource that is not openly available to all. Instead, individuals must exert time and effort, which allow trust to accrue incrementally. Trust emerges from the “concrete personal relations” between parties.Footnote 80

The accretion of social capital commences before the two parties initially transact with one another. The pre-screening exercising helps to slot businesses into different categories depending on their reputation. When parties begin to deal with each other directly (not necessarily on credit), they will form opinions of each other, with positive interactions helping to close the “social distance” between them.Footnote 81

If the supplier remains wary about the potential buyer, then he may require a full payment for the first several transactions, as it will give him time to assess the buyer’s ability to make timely repayments, frequency of purchases, and general demeanour. When he eventually becomes satisfied with the performance of the purchaser, the supplier may begin to provide goods on credit through an ograyi arrangement. Through prompt repayments, the debtor will be able to increase his credit line as time progresses. Moreover, the time and effort invested by both parties into the relationship increase the level of social capital—sometimes called “goodwill”—between them. Parties may also supplement economic ties with social ties, such as by inviting business partners to dinners and special occasions. The combination of these economic and social factors helps to increase the stock of social capital between the two parties (though over-socialized ties also entail certain risks, as discussed in the previous section).

6.1.4 Third-party guarantees

Often, a debtor is introduced to a potential supplier-cum-creditor through a common third party. Third-party introductions can play an important role in placing the potential debtor and creditor in close social proximity to one another. Identifying a debtor through his association with a known third party helps the supplier to understand how the purchaser is embedded within a particular matrix of social relations. The purchaser thus indirectly benefits from the reputation of the third party.

The third party may play one of three roles. First, the third party may choose to become directly involved in the transactions with the other two parties. For example, he may agree to contribute funds or, conversely, assist in repaying the loan. Second, he may provide a financial guarantee for the debtor in the event of non-payment. Third, and most commonly, the third party often simply serves as a character reference for the debtor, and thus the supplier must still assess whether the latter can be trusted with credit. In the last case, if the debtor fails to repay the loan or disappears, the supplier will not direct recourse against the guarantor. Nonetheless, the guarantor’s reputation would still be adversely affected, as it would signal that he cannot be trusted. For this reason, parties are generally cautious in providing third-party introductions and will only do so if they feel comfortable in vouching for the party in question.

6.1.5 Balancing trust and risk

Finally, it bears mentioning that a creditor’s reliance on trust must be gauged against his eye for opportunity. If the level of trust between creditors and debtors is low, then the creditor assumes significant risks in providing a loan. However, a creditor may still be willing to go forward with the transaction if he feels the potential for profits is high. As one businessman noted: “With big risks come big gains.” Once a creditor has screened the potential business, he will weigh the potential risks and uncertainties against the potential for reaping profits. In deciding on a risky but potentially lucrative transaction, a creditor will consider his risk-taking preferences, his faith in the debtor’s ability to complete the specific transaction in question, and, importantly, the potential profits of the transaction.

6.2 Clientelism

Trust is formed within a social milieu in which parties are constantly trying to promote stability while minimizing the uncertainties associated with market conditions and co-contractors. For this reason, clientelism helps in sustaining a level of familiarity by matching parties together over a period of time. Clifford Geertz’s study of the Moroccan bazaar showed how “buyers and sellers, moving along the grooved channels clientelization lays down, find their way again and again to the same adversaries.”Footnote 82 In this way, clientelism helps to provide stability over time. For Geertz, the term “adversary” connotes “egalitarian and oppositional” parties,Footnote 83 since each possesses a level of independence such that the master–slave relationship implied by patronage relations would not aptly capture the power dynamics. Parties are bound together by their complementary roles, as each possesses something the other requires. Solidarity between parties based on difference (what sociologist Emile Durkheim calls “organic solidarity”) is arguably more valuable than solidarity based on similarity (or “mechanical solidarity”), since the former helps to capitalize on synergies.Footnote 84 Put otherwise, each party is able to focus on its own abilities, which, in turn, helps in the success of the partnership.

In Mandawi, co-operation between suppliers and their purchasers is value-enhancing, as it provides each of them with access to new opportunities, despite the oppositional nature of the contractual arrangement. In an ograyi transaction, both suppliers and purchasers are dependent on one another. Suppliers seek to distribute their goods as widely as possible while purchasers require an initial input of resources before they make goods available to their clients. Informal credit helps to slacken the stress between the parties and, while it places a debt on the purchaser, it does not turn the relationship into one of subordination. This is evidenced by the fact that a supplier expends significant effort in finding a reliable debtor and, once found, also invests in the relationship so that it continues. As one businessman remarked: “suppliers want to find reliable debtors. It helps their own reputation if their client is a prominent business.”

The repeated interaction between suppliers and purchasers is advantageous for both parties. First, it reduces the searching costs of both suppliers and purchasers. Once the two have become matched, their relationship stabilizes, allowing each to direct their attention to other aspects of their business. Second, as the parties continue to interact with one another, they continue to accrue social capital, which helps to make greater amounts of credit available, while also increasing switching costs.

This is not to say that parties are forever locked into clientelistic relationships. Over time, switching costs may become less than the cost of remaining in the relationship, at which point the parties may terminate their dealings and go elsewhere.Footnote 85 Furthermore, Kabul’s economic environment fluctuates rapidly, with businesses regularly closing their offices, merging with other businesses, moving locations, or changing their primary area of activity—all of which may extinguish credit relationships between suppliers and purchasers. Thus, while clientelism provides stability for a certain period of time, in the long run, these relationships may become undone, thereby allowing parties to adjust to new market conditions.

6.3 Norms and practices of the market

Ograyi transactions do not take place in a market devoid of meanings and symbols. Rather, the market is replete with practices that facilitate the formation of trust and the practicability of ograyi. Within the market-place, information flows quickly between different corners, allowing parties to make informed decisions. Parties behave with a level of reciprocity, thereby facilitating the long-term wellbeing of their business relationships. In certain instances, one party will have to exercise flexibility, as circumstances may arise that make it impossible for the other party to fulfil their obligations as anticipated.

6.3.1 Information sharing

Within the market, participants are regularly interacting with one another and exchanging information on ongoing activities and transactions. The multiple ties that any person has with others ensure that important information reaches every corner of the market in a short period of time. Businesses and individuals rely on information from others to assess the character of potential co-contractors.

Information travels across the market orally and is highly sought after by businesses. Clifford Geertz explained information in the Moroccan bazaar as being “poor, scarce, maldistributed, [and] inefficiently communicated.”Footnote 86 Mandawi bear many similarities, as information on transactions, behaviours, and prices is not collected by any central body, but rather moves unevenly through gossip, facilitated by the close physical and social proximity of businesses. Publicly available information pertains to the character and the type of transactions of different market actors, whereas information on volumes of wealth and profit margins usually remains undisclosed. The close proximity of the stores that regularly interact with one another means that information flows quickly across the market. When screening a potential debtor, a creditor will speak to past clients as well as stores located nearby the debtor’s office, keeping an ear out for any troubling rumours.

Breakfast and lunch in the bazaar serve as important times to collect information. Several businesspeople will meet in one store to break bread and exchange updates on business activities and other information that has caught their attention. Furthermore, the ritual of providing important clients or potential partners with chai allows information to be gleaned through casual conversations on business and non-business matters. If a supplier eventually provides a business with credit, then the weekly visits to the office of the debtor to collect payments serve as an opportunity to visually inspect the state of the business. Information quickly travels throughout the market, though also transforming with each transfer, impugning the quality of any single bit of information. Businesses thus verify information through a variety of sources to separate facts from fabrication.

6.3.2 Norms of reciprocity

As parties develop a personal relationship with each other, an expectation arises that each will be forthcoming. Thus, clientelism “is a reciprocal matter,” as both parties reap benefits by investing in the relationship.Footnote 87 Parties often exchange in-kind gifts to solidify their connection. One businessman remarked: “My uncle [the store owner] has one main client who he provides ograyi to. They have good relations, and my uncle even invites the owner to his house for dinner.”Footnote 88 Gifts and invitations are not merely philanthropic, but rather help to solidify the reciprocal partnership.Footnote 89

One instance in which reciprocity comes to the fore is when suppliers and purchasers have disagreements. At times, a shipment may arrive later than expected. At other times, the quality or nature of the item may be slightly different from what the purchaser anticipated. Alternately, the purchaser may be a few days behind schedule in making a payment. The parties may also disagree about a previously agreed-upon exchange rate. In the course of dealing with one another, such obstacles will inevitably arise. Parties operate on a give-and-take understanding, with one party sometimes foregoing the error and, other times, the other party acting similarly. To ensure a balance of interests, parties will keep a tab (often written) of each other’s actions to ensure that each side is reciprocating equitably. If either party were to stop being forthcoming, it would risk straining the relationship, possibly leading to an eventual breakdown.

6.3.3 Flexibility and empathy

Parties adopt a practice of remaining flexible with one another to account for contingencies that arise in the course of their dealings. Suppliers understand that debtors may periodically face difficulties in making payments, and thus will work with the debtor to find a solution. Strict adherence in all instances to the terms of repayment is not expected simply because it is not feasible. As in other settings, contractual breach is a market reality that needs to be worked around.Footnote 90 Parties are not interested in pursuing legal recourse for breach of contract. Thus, by observing a level of flexibility towards one another, parties can absorb contingencies that may otherwise put a strain on the relationship.

Flexibility is thus treated as a default understanding in their dealings. The level of flexibility depends on the particular circumstances and, importantly, the willingness of the debtor to work with the creditor towards a solution. Like trust, as the relationship grows, so too will the level of flexibility. Flexibility may extend to the repayment terms but will seldom involve the debt being fully written off. As the burden of the debt on the creditor increases, he will increase pressure for repayment and possibly convey threats, whether personal or legal.Footnote 91 Once this point has been reached, the social capital between the parties will also erode until the repayment is made.

6.4 Renegotiating the terms of the contract

In certain instances, a debtor will be unable to repay the outstanding loan due to one of several reasons. The debtor himself may be having difficulty in getting payments from his buyers, thus affecting his own ability to pay his creditors. For goods coming from foreign countries, delays in the shipment also cause delays in making repayments. In certain instances, the debtor may have simply made a bad business decision by acquiring goods on credit that are difficult to resell. In other instances, the market condition may have changed without any fault on the part of the debtor.

For a debtor who seeks to remain active in the market, it is important that he remains in contact with his creditor. Trust between the creditor and debtor will not immediately evaporate due to the non-payment, as creditors recognize that a variety of circumstances may have led to the breach. Nonetheless, a debtor must remain engaged with his creditor and show his willingness to try and resolve the problem. This does not imply that the creditor will dismiss the breach, as the debtor can expect to face social pressure to hasten the repayment. However, maintaining contact helps to preserve trust, particularly if the circumstances are truly extenuating, and can even strengthen the trust between them in the long run. Conversely, if a debtor fails to respond to telephone calls and meeting requests or moves the location of his store unannounced, such actions will adversely affect the relationship between the parties and the debtor’s ability to secure future credit. To avoid irreparable reputational damage, unprofitable businesses may even keep their stores in operation, since closing down would risk destroying the possibility of future business within the market.

At a certain point, the parties may take steps to renegotiate the terms of repayment, which may take one of two forms. First, the loan payment may remain the same but the repayment period may be extended. This arrangement is most likely if the creditor feels that, despite the delay in payment, the potential for future opportunity outweighs the need for charging additional fees. If the parties are family members or have built significant social capital between them, additional charges may strain their relationship beyond the immediate transaction. Second, the repayment period may be extended with additional fees. This arrangement is most common when the parties have an arms-length relationship with each another or when the prospect of future transactions is uncertain. The additional fees serve to offset the losses incurred by the creditor due to the late payment.Footnote 92

Besides renegotiating the terms of the contract, the creditor will also take the breach into consideration in providing future lines of credit. While the parties may continue to work with one another, the level of credit will likely change. The debtor will have to repay the outstanding amount before getting more credit. If the parties have prior dealings, the creditor may be able to decide on the appropriate level of credit based on those earlier transactions. The creditor will likely be stricter in requiring timely repayments in future transactions and may visually inspect the business location and activities of the debtor to determine whether to resume providing credit and at what level.

7. Bank ineffectiveness

The continued success of the informal economy is tied to the turbulent recent history of the Afghan banking sector, which was built at near lightning speed, with billions of dollars of military aid and development money streaming into the country from international sources. The sector took a significant hit in September 2010 with the near collapse of Kabul Bank, one of the country’s largest financial institutions at the time. The bank was found to be engaging in fraudulent activities, eventually leading to a bank run with nearly half of its USD $1.3 billion in deposits being withdrawn within a few days.Footnote 93 A number of regulatory lapses by Da Afghanistan Bank (DAB), the country’s central bank, allowed the fraudulent activities of Kabul Bank to fester unchecked.Footnote 94 Investigations revealed that the United States Agency for International Development (USAID), along with its implementing partners BearingPoint and Deloitte, did not follow up on early warning signs of poor oversight when providing technical assistance to DAB from 2003 until 2011.Footnote 95 Following an extensive evaluation on anti-money laundering (AML) and combatting the financing of terrorism (CFT) commissioned by the International Monetary Fund,Footnote 96 the Financial Action Task Force (FATF), an intergovernmental body that promotes the international financial system, placed Afghanistan on its grey list in 2012.Footnote 97 In June 2017, after improving its regulatory framework, which included passing AML/CFT laws, Afghanistan was removed from the grey list.Footnote 98

At present, banks remain largely conservative when issuing loans. As an indication of the conserving lending policies, the 2018 annual report by the DAB on the banking sector disclosed that the gross volume of deposits across was AFN 273.78 billion, whereas gross loans issued by banks stood at AFN 41.43 billion (i.e. only 15.1% of deposit holdings were loaned out).Footnote 99 In many developing settings, banks host an extreme surplus of liquidity because of the challenges in providing credit.Footnote 100 The stringent lending policies of banks are in part a response to stricter central-bank regulations following the Kabul Bank incident and in part a response to the difficulty more generally of ensuring that loans are adequately secured against default. These policies end up making bank loans largely inaccessible or, alternately, impractical for small and medium-sized enterprises, which make up the vast majority of shops in Mandawi and across Afghanistan.

Four principal factors dissuade traders from taking bank loans to pay for their transactions. First, the collateral requirements pose an exceedingly high barrier for businesses seeking credit. Central-bank regulations suggest that a loan should be secured for 100% of its value.Footnote 101 The actual practice of banks is to seek even great collateral, in the range of 150–200% of the loan value. This practice is conflated with the convention across banks of significantly undervaluing collateral—by up to 50%.Footnote 102 Traders make their profits from the turnover of goods, and thus may require credit that is several times the value of the property they own. Furthermore, traders also may live in unregistered areas of Kabul and banks are generally more reluctant in accepting unregistered land as collateral.Footnote 103 The combination of these factors makes it difficult for many traders to meet the collateral requirements set by banks.

Second, acquiring a bank loan is a time-consuming process. According to one banking official, an individual or business may need 7–25 days to get a loan, since the bank’s primary objective is hedging risks.Footnote 104 According to one banker:

A loan request first goes through the financial audit team, which will take a week. This is where the risk is assessed. Depending on the size of the loan, the property may need to be assessed by the business development team. The final step is the registration of the property deed as a guarantee in the bank’s name.

This timeline is incongruent with the schedules of businesses. Given the fluctuations in the market, a sudden need for goods may arise if the business is to capitalize on the opportunity to make a profit. Constantly waiting for bank loans to be approved would seriously affect the competitiveness of a business.Footnote 105 Furthermore, ograyi generally involves a repayment of the debt in a short period of time and, once repaid, the issuance of more credit; thus, in the course of a year, a business is able to undertake a significant number of ograyi transactions, which would be especially difficult to perform through a bank.

Third, bank loans do not provide the flexibility available through ograyi transactions. Businesses may sometimes need flexibility if they are unable to repay their loans in a timely manner. Suppliers can afford some level of flexibility to ograyi clients, whereas a bank is stricter in seeking repayments, since overdue loans may affect its credit rating.Footnote 106 Similarly, each time a bank loan is sought, a customer must complete the relevant paperwork, whereas, with an ograyi transaction, once the parties trust one another, a simple phone call by the debtor may be sufficient for funds to be released.Footnote 107

Fourth, some businesses avoid bank loans because they view interest fees as haram (i.e. unlawful according to Islamic law).Footnote 108 As mentioned previously, businesses dealing with interest transactions risk suffering damage to their reputation, as they would be viewed as engaging in morally unacceptable activities. Religious doctrine thus plays some role in the way businesses perceive banks. Nonetheless, religion was cited far less often than the other reasons for avoiding bank loans, implying that businessmen were driven more by pragmatism than piety.

It is finally worth noting that the claim made by some businesses that high interest rates dissuade them from taking bank loans seems inconsistent with actual market practices. Currently, the annual interest rate for bank loans is 15–21%, corresponding to a monthly rate of 1.25–1.75%. In an ograyi transaction, the supplier of credit may be either a business or a money currency exchanger. In the first case, the price of goods sold using ograyi usually includes a markup compared to goods bought in lump sum. Businesses indicated a markup in the order of 8–12% with the ograyi lasting between one week and one month.Footnote 109 In the second case in which ograyi involves a money exchanger, by comparing the market exchange rate with the exchange rate in an ograyi transaction in which the repayment is made in another currency,Footnote 110 one can deduce an interest rate in the order of 2–3.5% for a one-week to one-month loan. In both cases, the bank’s interest rate is less than the ograyi rate. Nonetheless, suppliers and exchangers emphasize that prices are decided using a “total-package” approach, which considers pre-existing trust between the parties, the likelihood of future dealings, the volume of goods purchased, and the amount paid up front. Ograyi is also often tied to other transactions such as the hawala transfer of the funds from the purchaser to the supplier. At a minimum, it cannot be clearly demonstrated that ograyi is financially more advantageous that a bank loan.

8. Perils of legal recourse

The court remains available to aggrieved parties seeking recourse through official state channels. The government and international community have invested significant funds in trying to improve the judiciary. Between 2005 and 2014, the US State Department provided some $241 million through the Justice Sector Support Program (JSSP), which targeted training officials, justices, prosecutors, and defence lawyers, as well as improving the case-management system and administrative capacity.Footnote 111 Nonetheless, such efforts have failed to bring about observable improvements to the legal system.Footnote 112 An audit of the JSSP revealed its utter failure, with no evidence that programmes brought about tangible benefits, since justice institutions did not subscribe to their efforts.Footnote 113

The judiciary has been criticized for being one of the country’s most corrupt institutions.Footnote 114 Courts in Afghanistan are widely viewed as being “firmly under the executive’s control; highly susceptible to outside influences; and widely … corrupt, predatory, and rent seeking.”Footnote 115 The copious amounts of red tape required for simple administrative tasks—vehicle registration requires as many as 27 signatures—have caused people to turn to bribes and informal arrangements to help to expedite their affairs. Nonetheless, the courts remain available to any party seeking their assistance.

The following passage presents the experiences of a businessman named Farhad who sought legal recourse for an ograyi agreement in which the co-contractor had failed to make payments. The passage is reported at length to provide a first-hand account of Farhad’s experience—and frustration—with the legal processFootnote 116 :

I used to own a shop in Mandawi that sold snacks [i.e. cookies, chips, etc.]. Nazar, another storeowner in his fifties, kept calling me asking for snacks. I did not know who he was, nor did others in the marketplace. He was persistent, and so I visited his house one day to understand his financial condition, and he seemed to be doing well financially. So I gave him USD $5500 worth of snacks. I agreed to an ograyi, where he would pay every 5000 AFN (approximately USD $75) every Tuesday. The first three times, he paid the 5000 AFN, but then he stopped. I called him many times, but he kept saying that the payment will be coming soon. But he never paid.

I decided to take legal action. I had to bribe a police officer for him to serve a summons on Nazar, and then again I had to pay the officer to transfer the file [from his office] to the court. On the first day, the court staff kept me waiting 3–4 hours and then told me to return the next day. They even told me to bring Nazar, though I had no power to force him to come. We finally came before the judge, and on several occasions, she [i.e. the judge] insisted that I give Nazar extra time. I agreed to this three times, but Nazar would not respond to my calls and even moved his shop without notice. I eventually found him, and again he told me that he would pay me, “Inshallah.” In the courtroom, he once event knelt to touch my feet to ask for more time. After 3 months of returning to the court every second day, I asked the judge for a final ruling.Footnote 117 Eventually, she issued her judgment [against Nazar] and told me to take it to the police for enforcement.

Outside of the judge’s room, I told Nazar that it would be over if he paid me. He became angry and claimed that I had threatened him. I knew this was a tactic to avoid paying me. I went to the Attorney General’s office to register my court judgement and to inform them that Nazar had made a false claim that I had threatened him. This way, I was protecting myself in case he later wanted to claim I threatened him.

It has been six months, and I have not yet seen a single dollar. Asking for help from the police will require paying them. Also, Nazar is the type of person who would cause more problems, which is not worth my time and safety.

While assessments of trust are normally integral when issuing credit, the ultimate weighing of risks versus opportunities is done at the individual level. Farhad explained why he decided to trust Nazar despite not having accrued sufficient social capital with him through prior transactions:

To make money in the market, one has to take risks. That’s the nature of the business. When I did the background check of Nazar, even though no one knew him, I did not get negative information about him. His economic condition seemed good. And he seemed very interested in selling. So I decided to take a risk.

Farhad decided to provide goods on credit without having a prior business relationship with the business partner or without being able to verify Nazar’s business profile through references in the market. Farhad attempted to offset this lack of information by visiting Nazar’s house and gauging his economic condition based on visual inspection. Trust often entails an element of risk, as it leaves one party vulnerable to the actions or inactions of another.Footnote 118 The perils of Farhad’s experience speak to the difficulties in balancing assessments of trust, risk, and opportunity.

Nazar’s engagement with the legal system reveals the general treatment of ograyi by the court. First, it is important to note the court’s willingness to receive the case. From the perspective of the commercial court, an ograyi dispute is principally an issue of breach of contract. The court’s task is thus to discern the facts surrounding the alleged breach. The ograyi transaction often has no written contract, either because the parties are accustomed to informality or because parties do not want to signal their scepticism about the relationship. Documents, if they even exist, often take the form of inconsistent ledgers and receipts, which are supplemented by the information of the parties and their witnesses. Through this bricolage of information, the judge will assess the nature and severity of the breach. Second, the court repeatedly insists that the parties seek to find a solution outside of the court. The judge asked Farhad on three separate occasions to try resolving the dispute outside of the court by giving Nazar more time (which Farhad entertained though to no avail). The official status of the court can serve as an added impetus to resolve the dispute informally as the parties feel the looming “shadow of the law.” In a different context, police and judges sometimes receive complaints from women of mistreatment by their husbands.Footnote 119 Rather than dealing with these cases through legal channels, these officials would encourage these women to approach their elder male relatives to mediate a solution.Footnote 120 Judges may sometimes remand the case to elders and religious leaders best suited to arbitrate a solution, thus preferring “court-supervised councils” over the heavy hand of the law.Footnote 121 In this way, judges (and police) may assume the role of mediator in trying to resolve a conflict through a variety of methods beyond their specific mandate.Footnote 122

In sum, Farhad’s case shows the difficulties in contractual enforcement through the courts. The court proceeding took a total of four months and ultimately provided Farhad only with a written judgment. However, he would still need it to be enforced by the police, which he decided not to pursue, as he would have to continue paying bribes though the final outcome remained uncertain. Thus, his case remains unresolved. On the Doing Business Index of the World Bank, Afghanistan ranked 181 out of 190 countries (190 being lowest) for contractual enforcement in 2019, with claims taking an average of 1,642 days from the date of the lawsuit until payment and enforcement expenses amounting to approximately 29% of the claim value.Footnote 123

Farhad’s case reveals the difficulty—though not impossibility—of having an ograyi transaction enforced by the court. The legal process is time-consuming and requires paying bribes at various stages if aggrieved parties hope for their case to move forward. Even a favourable decision may be foiled due to the difficulties in enforcement and the ability of recalcitrant debtors to prolong conflicts. Thus, the general sentiment amongst creditors is to carry out ograyi transactions with little confidence in the court’s ability to provide redress in the event of a contractual breach.

9. Conclusion

One of the challenges facing fragile and post-conflict settings is promoting economic development, since businesses face a shortage in the investment capital necessary for carrying out transactions. The circulation of credit eases market rigidities by facilitating the movement of goods and allowing businesses to scale up their activities. In Afghanistan, ograyi permeates every corner of the market, forming an elaborate network that connects foreign suppliers, urban wholesalers, small-scale urban and rural businesses, and money currency exchangers. Large businesses provide credit to smaller businesses, while money exchangers provide credit to businesses that import large shipments of goods into the country.

Decisions on whether or not to provide informal trade credit are made relationally between businesses. To ensure contractual fulfilment, creditors carefully assess potential debtors when deciding whether to provide credit and at what level. Creditors and debtors invest resources in building trust between each other, which involves assessing reputation, pre-screening clients, accumulating social capital, and co-opting third-party guarantors. Clientelism and widespread market practices and norms help to establish steady routines of behaviour. If a breach occurs, parties make efforts to renegotiate the terms of the contract. Through an imprecise science, creditors rely on a combination of these factors when deciding whether to issue credit to other parties. The surrounding environment also contributes to the prevalence of informal credit, as bank credit remains largely unavailable or unappealing to businesses and the legal system provides limited recourse in the case of contractual breach. The informal regulation of trade credit serves as a substitute for legal coercion.

The current study shows how economic opportunities are created in unstable environments, in which parties rely on non-legal practices to facilitate informal credit transactions. It also points to some of the limits of such market arrangements. Because of the high level of personal trust required between parties, significant resources must be spent on relationship building, slowing the ability of parties to scale up their activities. Furthermore, moving from a society largely characterized by small and medium-sized businesses to one that hosts large firms arguably requires a functioning state that can support corporate structures and shareholder protections. A more strongly functioning state may also provide access to larger volumes of credit through banks. Thus, while informal credit provides a viable means of assisting businesses when banks and state institutions are weak, this arrangement does not negate the potential importance of the latter for long-term economic growth.

Acknowledgements

David Nelken and Florian Grisel provided helpful reviews of this article. The Afghan Institute for Strategic Studies provided an institutional home during my fieldwork; I thank the Director General, Davood Moradian, for his continued support. I also thank Farhana Rahman, Zulfiqar Ali Khan, Ahmad Milad Assakzai, Mohammad Amin Amin, Abdul Musawer Ishan, Amir Khan Saleh, Naveed Saifi, and Wahidullah Haidari for assistance at various stages of the research. My fieldwork was supported by a Sociolegal Studies Association research grant. I presented portions of this paper at the Conference on Identities in Contemporary Afghanistan at Yale University and the Afghanistan in Academia Conference at the School of Oriental and African Studies, where the participants provided enriching feedback. The usual disclaimer applies.

Footnotes

2 De Lauri (Reference De Lauri2013), p. 540. More generally, for literature on third space, see e.g. Bhabha (Reference Bhabha1994).

3 Choudhury (Reference Choudhury2017), supra note 1.

4 Coghlan (Reference Coghlan2011), p. 27; Gilchrist & Zakrajšek (Reference Gilchrist, Egon, Steven, Hans and Kuipers1998), p. 129.

5 Ibid., p. 129; De Gregorio & Guidotti (Reference De Gregorio and Guidotti1995).

6 Various definitions exist regarding the informal economy. However, I intentionally avoid this discussion, since it is not a central theme of this paper. For a more detailed discussion on the notion of “informal economy,” see e.g. Portes & Haller (Reference Portes, William, Smelser and Swedberg2010).

7 A variety of reasons explain the emergence of an informal credit market: licences are not required; it is not regulated by the central bank; it facilitates small savings; it is not always profit-motivated; it may possess its own organizational structure; it does not require collateral; its services are localized and often personalized; the identity of borrowers is well known; it may have multiple proprietorship as in the case micro-credit; it relies on close informational links between individuals; repayment rates are better than bank rates; it encourages reciprocal credit disbursal; it encourages community participation. See e.g. Srinivas (Reference Srinivas2016).

8 Other arrangements include informal credit unions and informal money lenders. See e.g. Srinivas & Higuchi (Reference Srinivas and Yoichiro1996).

9 Besley, Coate, & Loury (Reference Besley, Coate and Loury1993); Besley, Coate, & Loury (Reference Besley, Coate and Loury1994); Biggart (Reference Biggart2001); Bouman (Reference Bouman1977); Bouman (Reference Bouman1995). ROSCAs have been the object of study for several decades. See Ardener (Reference Ardener1964); Geertz (Reference Geertz1962). Recent research has also focused on the governance of ROSCAs through the interplay of official laws and community practices. See Yimer et al. (Reference Yimer, Wim and Mehreteab2018).

10 Bouman & Houtman (Reference Bouman and Houtman1988).

12 Biggart, supra note 9.

13 Skully, supra note 11.

14 Barfield (Reference Barfield2008), supra note 1; Barfield (Reference Barfield2010), supra note 1; Rubin (Reference Rubin2015).

15 Beall & Schütte (Reference Beall and Stefan2006), p. 51.

16 Schütte (Reference Schütte2009), p. 485.

17 Klijn (Reference Klijn2006), p. 17; Rahimi (Reference Rahimi2015), p. 744.

18 The gerawi arrangement is highly flexible and may take a number of configurations. The creditor may occupy the pledged land for his own use; he may lease the land for his own use at a highly discounted price; he may lease out the land to a third party; he may allow the debtor to remain on the land and collect rents from the debtor. See e.g. Rahimi, supra note 17, p. 758.

19 Biais & Gollier (Reference Biais and Christian1997); Bouman, supra note 9; Petersen & Rajan (Reference Petersen and Rajan1997); Seifert, Seifert, & Protopappa-Sieke (Reference Seifert, Seifert and Protopappa-Sieke2013).

20 The proliferation of trade credit has a number of explanations beyond simply the inaccessibility of banks. See Fisman & Love (Reference Fisman and Inessa2003). First, trade credit is more likely to arise when the goods can be easily seized and resold by the seller. See Maksimovic & Frank (Reference Maksimovic and Frank1998); Mian & Smith (Reference Mian and Smith1992). Thus, depreciable or highly specific goods are less likely to be suitable for trade credit. Second, trade credit can serve as a means for a supplier to signal the quality of its products. See Emery & Nayar (Reference Emery and Nandkumar1998); Lee & Stowe (Reference Lee and Stowe1993). Third, in industries that require complex inputs from suppliers, the latter may be more inclined to provide trade credit because of the ability to exact significant punishment in the case of non-payment. See Cunat (Reference Cunat2001). Fourth, in industries with limited competition among suppliers, suppliers may be able to charge higher prices through trade credit when price elasticity is greater for cash customers than for credit customers (i.e. credit-customer demand is less sensitive to price increases than the demand of cash customers), provided the market also exhibits adverse selection (i.e. sellers have information on buyers but not vice versa). See Brennan, Maksimovics, & Zechner (Reference Brennan, Vojislav and Josef1988).

21 Bernstein (Reference Bernstein1992), p. 118.

22 Ghate (Reference Ghate1992).

23 Fisman & Love, supra note 20.

24 Macneil (Reference Macneil1978); Macneil (Reference Macneil1985).

25 Clay (Reference Clay1997), p. 210.

26 Fafchamps (Reference Fafchamps1996), p. 444.

27 Hendley, Murrell, & Ryterman (Reference Hendley, Murrell, Ryterman and Murrell2001), p. 56.

28 McMillan & Woodruff (Reference McMillan and Christopher1999b), p. 1285.

29 McMillan & Woodruff (Reference McMillan and Christopher1999a), p. 637.

30 McMillan & Woodruff (Reference McMillan and Christopher2000), p. 2450.

31 Fisman & Love, supra note 20.

32 See e.g. Cull, Xu, & Zhu (Reference Cull, Xu and Zhu2009). Their research shows that, in China, poorly performing state-owned enterprises are more likely to provide trade credit to firms with limited access to credit, whereas profitable (rather than unprofitable) private firms are more like to provide credit to customers with limited credit access.

33 Demirgüç-Kunt & Maksimovic (Reference Demirgüç-Kunt and Maksimovic2001). This World Bank study involving a mixture 39 developed and developing countries finds that trade credit complements bank loans. Conversely, Bose (Reference Bose1998) finds that, in less developed countries, the availability of cheap credit in the formal sector worsened credit terms and availability in the informal sector.

34 Nelken (Reference Nelken2004), p. 9. To help to interpret the participant observations arising during the course of the fieldwork, this study draws on literature from sociology and anthropology.

35 Hanifi (Reference Hanifi2004), p. 200. For a discussion more generally on hawala, see Thompson (Reference Thompson2011).

36 Schütte, supra note 16, p. 477.

37 Klijn & Pain (Reference Klijn and Adam2007), p. 19. Also see e.g. Mallett & Pain (Reference Mallett and Adam2017); Minoia, Mumatz, & Pain (Reference Minoia, Wamiqullah and Adam2014); Minoia & Pain (Reference Minoia and Adam2017); Shaw & Ghafoori (Reference Shaw and Ihsanullah2019). Agriculture is mentioned due to the widespread dependence on agriculture-related work in the countryside. However, people in any occupation may occasionally require credit. Families dependent on remittances from labour migrants or causal labourers may go through periods with less funds. Even teachers and government employees may not receive their salary for several months, thus requiring credit to meet their immediate needs.

38 Mansfield & Pain (Reference Mansfield and Adam2007), p. 13. Also see Pain (Reference Pain2008); Ward et al. (Reference Ward, Mansfield and Oldham2008).

39 The Afghan market is replete with small and medium-sized enterprises, with very few large businesses. Nonetheless, I do not differentiate businesses according to size, as this was unnecessary for understanding the regulation of informal credit.

40 Scholars have noted that it is sometimes necessary for a researcher to build a personal “tribe” of interconnections that they can rely upon for introductions to third parties, as its members can vouch for the name of the researcher. See Malejacq & Mukhopadhyay (Reference Malejacq and Dipali2016). These discussions relate to a slowly emerging body of scholarship on conducting fieldwork in dangerous areas. See Massoud (Reference Massoud2016).

41 Afghanistan is a civil-law jurisdiction (at least nominally). Unlike common-law jurisdictions in which court decisions often contain legal reasoning, written decisions in civil-law jurisdictions often lack such details and instead contain a summary of the facts, the relevant provision of law, and a pronouncement of the outcome. For a discussion of civil-law jurisdictions generally, see Merryman & Pérez-Perdomo (Reference Merryman and Pérez-Perdomo2007).

42 Marsden (Reference Marsden2015); Marsden (Reference Marsden2018); Rahim (Reference Rahim2018). For a discussion on Afghanistan’s geopolitical connections in the region more generally, see Monsutti (Reference Monsutti2013).

44 Sadat (Reference Sadat1999).

45 Goods originating in more distant locations, such as China, Turkey, or the UAE, will travel by ship for the first portion of their trip until they reach the port cities of either Bandar Abbas or Charbahar, both in Iran. The Charbahar port specifically aims at increasing trade between Afghanistan and India. See Mutfi, Amirahmadian, & Sachedva (Reference Mutfi, Amirahmadian and Sachedva2018). From these two ports, goods may board a train to the Iran–Afghan border in eastern Iran; however, the final stretch into Afghanistan is always by truck.

46 This factor also explains the size of the used-goods markets as well as the prevalence of repair stores for virtually every type of item. Luxury items are also imported from abroad and are sold to the small percentage of wealthy citizens.

47 The last three years have also seen a corresponding dip in exports. This period has been characterized by an increase in insecurity, suggesting that insecurity may be adversely affecting the movement of goods into and out of the country.

48 Many of the buildings are over 50 years old, having withstood decades of civil war and regime changes. The decayed walls of many buildings still have bullet holes, a near-permanent reminder of the suffering that once marked the country. The streets are virtually impassable as people rush in every direction, cars and motorbikes deliver goods to their owners, and donkeys slowly plod along with moving stalls strapped to their backs. The poor electrical work of buildings alongside the high volume of usage has led to a number of fires in the market in recent years.

49 Wholesalers are often themselves merchants or, alternately, may work with a trader who imports particular goods.

50 A wholesaler will provide goods to a variety of customers, many of whom will be outside of Kabul. The goods may pass through Kabul or may be transferred directly to a customer from the originating source if the wholesaler finds such an arrangement to be more expeditious.

51 Marsden (Reference Marsden2016), supra note 43; Marsden (Reference Marsden2018), supra note 42.

52 The decision to relocate abroad is often motivated by non-economic factors, as many traders relocate because of safety concerns.

53 Two other credit arrangements are gerawi (see note 18 and the accompanying discussion in the main text) and sar qulfi (a deposit by businesses to the building owner for the right to use the shop location). Both of these arrangements are secured with collateral.

54 OECD (2019).

55 For a discussion of the fees associated with ograyi as compared to a bank loan, see the discussion in the main text associated with note 109.

56 An employee of the currency exchange shop will then visit the debtor each week to collect payments.

57 The rules governing money exchangers can be found in the central-bank regulation Muqarara Tanzim Fa-aliat hai Sarrafan va Fraham Konandagan Khidamat Puli [The Regulation of the Activities of Money Exchangers and Money Service Providers] 1398 [2019].

58 Businesses throughout Kabul often keep a deposit of funds with exchangers; subsequently, an exchanger is able to utilize these funds for other transactions, such as providing certain customers with credit.

59 In this way, the exchanger is able to avoid directly charging interest by incorporating the profit level into the exchange rate. The hawala transfer also entails a separate fee.

60 For the effects of foreign aid on the Afghan economy, see e.g. Bizhan (Reference Bizhan2018a); Bizhan (Reference Bizhan2018b); Suhrke (Reference Suhrke2011).

61 Swenson (Reference Swenson2017), p. 115.

62 Between 2005 and 2012, imports increased by a staggering 184% (data based on World Bank statistics). Refer to Figure 1 showing the volume of inputs and exports from 2002 to 2017.

63 I resided in Kabul for much of 2012–16. At the start of this period, US dollars had flooded the market to the extent that people could buy loaves of Afghan bread (each costing roughly $0.20) with USD $100 bills, and the bakers would know exactly how much change to provide. However, this economic reality was short-lived. During December 2018, the economy became significantly weaker. Between 2015 and 2017, the number of people living below the poverty line increased from 39.1% to 54.5%. See Data.adb.org (2017).

64 In 2012, the US announced its intention to pull out from Afghanistan. Between 2012 and 2016, the volume of imports shrunk by 36%.

65 Another obvious way in which a business can raise funds is by incorporating and subsequently issuing stocks and bonds. However, I do not explore this method of fundraising in this paper, since it is largely absent in Afghanistan.

66 In 2010, Afghanistan established a collateral registry, which is administered by the Public Credit Registry of the central bank. The goal of the registry is to make information on collateralized properties available to creditors so that they can protect themselves against risks. One problem about the collateral registry is that creditors are not required to register collateral and thus the database is incomplete. According to Afghan bankers, the registry is checked before accepting collateral for a loan, but the final assessment also relies on other information possessed by the bank, such as past dealings, evidence of cash flow and profitability, and reputation. The barriers that Afghan businesses face in accessing bank loans is detailed in Section 7 of this paper.

67 The argument is made most strongly by De Soto (Reference De Soto2000). Conversely, others are more cautious about the ability of property rights to promote economic activity. See e.g. Kennedy (Reference Kennedy2011).

68 Gaston & Dang (Reference Gaston and Lillian2015), p. 3. It is estimated that less than 30% of land in urban areas and 10% of land in rural areas has been registered. See World Bank (2019). Efforts are underway to title more of the land throughout the country; however, this process will take many years. Ibid. For a review more generally of property rights and registration in Afghanistan, see Alden Wily (Reference Alden Wily2013).

69 According to my interviews, some banks will accept untenured land as collateral, being aware that the risks associated with such land are also higher.

70 The problems plaguing the legal system are discussed in Section 8 of this paper.

71 Distrust is not necessarily the opposite of trust, since both trust and distrust may be beneficial in protecting against harm. See Hardin (Reference Hardin2001); Hardin (Reference Hardin and Hardin2004); Hawley (Reference Hawley2014). Instead, it may be more useful to consider uncertainty in opposition to trust and distrust, since uncertainty renders it difficult to plan subsequent actions and decisions. See Luhmann (Reference Luhmann1979).

72 Transparency.org (2018).

74 The converse association—that good business people are generally religious—was not immediately evident, since business success could be attributed to many activities, including cheating and fraud.

75 For a discussion on the prohibition of interest (referred to as riba in Arabic) in Islamic law, see Saeed (Reference Saeed1999).

76 In Islamic law, this arrangement would be considered a form of hiyal, which denotes “legal fictions” or “legal devices” that are “used to achieve a certain objective, law or not, through lawful means.” See Horii (Reference Horii2002), p. 312.

77 Granovetter (Reference Granovetter1985), p. 485.

78 A small number of creditors are keen to invest in new businesses; however, these tend to be the newer, younger, and less experienced creditors, who also have a greater propensity to incur losses. More experienced creditors are more heedful in their assessments of who may be creditworthy.

79 For a discussion on social capital, see e.g. Coleman (Reference Coleman1988).

80 Granovetter, supra note 77, p. 490.

81 Granovetter (Reference Granovetter1973), p. 1361.

82 Geertz (Reference Geertz1978), p. 30.

83 Ibid., p. 30.

84 See generally e.g. Durkheim (Reference Durkheim and Halls1984).

85 While the social capital that has accrued between the parties will be dissolved, the debtor’s reputation as a reliable business will continue to circulate in the market.

86 Geertz, supra note 82, p. 29.

87 Ibid., p. 30.

88 This is a strategy pursued by businessmen who have a small number of prominent clients. Invitations help to strengthen existing relations and could open new leads. However, some businessmen, particularly rich and prominent ones, avoid accepting invitations, since they pose risks to their personal safety.

90 Fafchamps, supra note 26; Fafchamps (Reference Fafchamps2002); Paquin (Reference Paquin2012).

91 It is uncommon for a business to hire gangs or private third parties to carry out threats. The one exception is if the creditor is a particularly strong businessman or connected to a powerful official and thus could get away with such intimidation.

92 Sometimes a creditor will seek to charge additional fees for late payment but will want to avoid an outright application of interest. The creditor may then ask for the late payment to be repaid in another currency, at an inflated exchange rate. For example, if the original agreement is to repay USD $1,000 in three months in Afghani currency with a rate of USD $1 = AFG 80, the creditor may extend the period to six months and ask for repayment in Afghani at a rate of USD $1 = AFG 90. In this way, interest is effectively couched within the exchange rate.

93 Kabul Bank was established in 2004 by its founder and chairman, Sherkhan Farnood. Initially involved closely in its operation, by 2008, Farnood had relinquished much of his authority to the chief executive officer, Khalilullah Ferozi. Under Ferozi’s leadership, bank funds were distributed to Afghan elites and influential persons, including hundreds of thousands of dollars going to President Karzai’s brother, and other funds going to Karzai’s election-campaign manager as well as the former minister of finance, Omar Zakhilwal. In 2009, Ferozi sought to depose Farnood of his position in the bank. In seeking to execute this operation, Ferozi had the support of Mahmood Karzai, brother of then President Karzai, and Haseen Fahim, brother of the former first vice president, Marshal Qasim Fahim, both of whom were shareholders in the bank. When Farnood realized what was happening, he reported the activities of the bank to the Washington Post. See Higgins (Reference Higgins2010), which put the fraudulent activities of the bank into the public eye. Subsequent investigations into the activities of Kabul Bank show a complex set of fraudulent operations in which nearly USD $900 million were laundered through the purchase of oil and gas in foreign countries at artificially inflated prices. See McLeod (Reference McLeod2016). Much of the funds ended up in Dubai through loans and disbursements to Afghan political elites for the purchase of luxury villas as well as the financing for various Dubai-based property and investment companies. The total collapse of the bank from the sudden withdrawal of funds by depositors was avoided when the central bank provided a loan of $825 million as a lender of last resort.

94 The lapses on the part of the Financial Supervision Department of the DAB include: inadequate background checks on the bank’s shareholders; failure to confirm that the bank’s operations were consistent with its licence; no on-site visits for the first 2.5 years of Kabul Bank’s operations; no technical specialist to assist with the on-site visits to verify information. See SIGAR Audit Report (2014a), p. 4.

95 BearingPoint was initially awarded the $92 million contract, which was sold to Deloitte in 2009 SIGAR Audit Report (2014a), pp. 6–7. During training sessions by foreign consultants, when DAB regulators were told that they had the power to monitor and even replace potentially corrupt banking officials, their incredulous response was that powerful banking officials had the power to depose them. See OIG (2011), p. 5.

96 IMF (2011).

97 In early 2014, Afghanistan’s standing fell to the “dark-grey” list as FATF did not note significant improvements. The country was able to avoid being blacklisted by passing AML/CFT laws in June 2014.

98 The DAB must be applauded for making significant strides in recent years in their oversight of financial institutions. Nonetheless, their supervision competencies still require greater development. During the course of my interviews, one banker remarked: “We get many auditors coming in. The funniest are the DAB auditors, since they ask us what it is they should be looking for” (emphasis was made by the banker).

99 DAB (2018).

100 Freedman & Click (Reference Freedman and Click2006).

101 Art. 7 of the Asset Classification and Provisioning Regulation of the DAB defines the various classifications of loans depending on whether they are likely to be repaid and secured by collateral. The highest rating for a loan is “standard” and loans in this class are fully secured (i.e. 100% of the loan value). As the level of collateral decreases, so too does the classification of the loan. As the number of substandard loans increases, the credit rating of the bank correspondingly decreases. DAB audits the banks and rates them according to the CAMELS (capital adequacy, asset quality, management, earnings, liquidity, and sensitivity) rating system.

102 One of the reasons for the low valuation of property is that people are reluctant to purchase foreclosed property, since they may face problems from the original owner, particularly if the latter is a powerful individual or politician.

103 Certain initiatives such as the Afghan Credit Guarantee Foundation (ACGF) based in Germany try to provide a corrective by securitizing select qualifying loans made by partner financial institutions in Afghanistan that meet ACGF’s loan criteria. While this added level of securitization helps to mitigate bank risk, it does not immediately translate into greater loan accessibility for businesses, as they must still meet that considerable collateral requirement of the bank. Because of the stringent requirement that a debtor must meet to qualify for ACGF coverage, the programme works best for loans that already meet a high threshold of security, which largely excludes loans sought by traders and merchants. ACGF also provides technical assistance to businesses, which arguably is a more direct form of support.

104 A period of 25 days was required by banks that undertook a particularly elaborate review process before issuing loans. At the other end of the spectrum, one bank mentioned that credit assessments could be make within one week if all the relevant information was provided.

105 One of the reasons for the unsteady demand of goods is irregular income, as much of the population operates in the informal economy or in irregular work. Even government employees suffer several months of delay in receiving their salary. Other factors, such a winter with unusually heavy snowfall, may also contribute to the uneven demand for items.

106 See discussion of asset classification at note 101.

107 For example, a client may telephone a money exchanger and ask for funds to be transferred to the supplier of certain goods. Provided the client and exchanger have a positive relationship, the request will be carried out.

108 One former businessman recounted how he and his business partner tried to get a loan from the bank but the partner pulled out, as he was against interest being charged on the principle.

109 This rate is based on conversations with 20 businesses on their transactions.

110 See the discussion in the main text accompanying note 76.

111 Swenson, supra note 61, p. 130.

112 Suhrke, supra note 60; Suhrke & Borchgrevink (Reference Suhrke and Kaja2009).

113 SIGAR Audit Report (2014b).

114 TOLOnews (2013).

115 Swenson, supra note 61, p. 119.

116 I recounted this story to a dozen businesspeople, and all of them confirmed its reasonableness and were largely unsurprised by the outcome. Names have been changed to preserve anonymity.

117 The Dari term sargar doni entails running around to complete a task without achieving any beneficial outcome.

118 Nooteboom (Reference Nooteboom2002).

119 Billaud (Reference Billaud2015), p. 98.

120 Ibid.

121 Ibid., p. 100.

122 Choudhury (Reference Choudhury2017), supra note 1.

123 Doingbusiness.org (2019).

References

Ahmed, Faiz (2007) “Shari’a, Custom, and Statutory Law: Comparing State Approaches to Islamic Jurisprudence, Tribal Autonomy, and Legal Development in Afghanistan and Pakistan.” 7 Global Jurist 154.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alden Wily, Liz (2013) Land, People, and the State in Afghanistan: 2002–2012, Kabul: Afghanistan Research and Evaluation Unit.Google Scholar
Ardener, Shirley (1964) “The Comparative Study of Rotating Credit Associations.” 94 Journal of the Royal Anthropological Institute of Great Britain and Ireland 201–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barfield, Thomas (2008) “Culture and Custom in Nation-Building: Law in Afghanistan.” 60 Maine Law Review 347–73.Google Scholar
Barfield, Thomas (2010) Afghanistan: A Cultural and Political History, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Beall, Jo, & Stefan, Schütte (2006) Urban Livelihoods in Afghanistan, Kabul: Afghanistan Research and Evaluation Unit.Google Scholar
Bernstein, Lisa (1992) “Opting Out of the Legal System: Extralegal Contracting in the Diamond Industry.” 21 Journal of Legal Studies 115–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, Timothy, Coate, Stephen, & Loury, Glenn (1993) “The Economics of Rotating Savings and Credit Associations.” 83 The American Economic Review 792810.Google Scholar
Besley, Timothy, Coate, Stephen, & Loury, Glenn (1994) “Rotating Savings and Credit Associations, Credit Markets and Efficiency.” 61 The Review of Economic Studies 701–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhabha, Homi (1994) The Location of Culture, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Biais, Bruno, & Christian, Gollier (1997) “Trade Credit and Credit Rationing.” 10 The Review of Financial Studies 903–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Biggart, Nichol Woolsey (2001) “Banking on Each Other: The Situational Logic of Rotating Savings and Credit Associations.” 4 Advances in Qualitative Organization Research 129–55.Google Scholar
Billaud, Julie (2015) Kabul Carnival: Gender Politics in Postwar Afghanistan, Philadelphia, PA: University of Pennsylvania Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bizhan, Nematullah (2018a) “Aid and State-Building, Part II: Afghanistan and Iraq.” 39 Third World Quarterly 1014–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bizhan, Nematullah (2018b) Aid Paradoxes in Afghanistan: Building and Undermining the State, Oxford and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Bose, Pinaki (1998) “Formal–Informal Sector Interaction in Rural Credit Markets.” 56 Journal of Development Economics 265–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bouman, F. J. A. (1977) “Indigenous Savings and Credit Societies in the Third World: A Message.” 1 Savings and Development 181219.Google Scholar
Bouman, F. J. A. (1995) “Rotating and Accumulating Savings and Credit Associations: A Development Perspective.” 23 World Development 371–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bouman, F. J. A., & Houtman, R. (1988) “Pawnbroking as an Instrument of Rural Banking in the Third World.” 37 Economic Development and Cultural Change 6989.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brennan, Michael J., Vojislav, Maksimovics, & Josef, Zechner (1988) “Vendor Financing.” 43 Journal of Finance 1127–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caskey, John P. (1991) “Pawnbroking in America: The Economics of a Forgotten Credit Market.” 23 Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 8599.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Choudhury, Nafay (2014) “Pluralism in Legal Education at the American University of Afghanistan.” 37 Suffolk Transnational Law Journal 249–88.Google Scholar
Choudhury, Nafay (2017) “Revisiting Critical Legal Pluralism in Afghanistan: Normative Contestations in the Afghan Courtroom.” 4 Asian Journal of Law and Society 229–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clay, Karen (1997) “Trade Without Law: Private-Order Institutions in Mexican California.” 13 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 202–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coghlan, Richard (2011) Money, Credit and the Economy, New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Coleman, James S. (1988) “Social Capital in the Creation of Human Capital.94 American Journal of Sociology S95120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cull, Robert, Xu, Lixin Colin, & Zhu, Tian (2009) “Formal Finance and Trade Credit during China’s Transition.” 18 Journal of Financial Intermediation 173–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cunat, Vicente (2001) “Inter-Firm Credit and Industrial Links.” PhD diss., London School of Economics and Political Science.Google Scholar
DAB (2018) Economics & Statistics Bulletin: Annual, 2018, Kabul: Da Afghanistan Bank.Google Scholar
Data.adb.org (2017) “Basic Statistics, Asia and the Pacific,” https://data.adb.org/dataset/basic-statistics-asia-and-pacific (accessed 12 February 2019).Google Scholar
De Gregorio, Jose, & Guidotti, Pablo E. (1995) “Financial Development and Economic Growth.” 23 World Development 433–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Lauri, Antonio (2013) “Corruption, Legal Modernisation and Judicial Practice in Afghanistan.” 37 Asian Studies Review 527–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Soto, H. (2000) The Mystery of Capital, New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Demirgüç-Kunt, Asli, & Maksimovic, Vojislav (2001) Firms as Financial Intermediaries: Evidence from Trade Credit Data, Policy Research Working Paper 2696, Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Doingbusiness.org (2019) “Ease of Doing Business in Afghanistan,” http://www.doingbusiness.org/en/data/exploreeconomies (accessed 19 June 2019).Google Scholar
Durkheim, Emile (1984) The Division of Labour in Society, trans. Halls, W. D., London: The Macmillan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Emery, Gary, & Nandkumar, Nayar (1998) “Product Quality and Payment Policy.” 10 Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting 269–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fafchamps, Marcel (1996) “The Enforcement of Commercial Contracts in Ghana.” 24 World Development 427–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fafchamps, Marcel (2002) “Spontaneous Market Emergence.” 2 The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics 137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisman, Raymond, & Inessa, Love (2003) “Trade Credit, Financial Intermediary Development, and Industry Growth.” 58 The Journal of Finance 353–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Francois, Marie Eileen (2006) A Culture of Everyday Credit: Housekeeping, Pawnbroking, and Governance in Mexico City, 1750–1920, Lincoln and London: University of Nebraska Press.Google Scholar
Freedman, Paul L., & Click, Reid W. (2006) “Banks That Don’t Lend? Unlocking Credit to Spur Growth in Developing Countries.” 24 Development Policy Review 279302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gaston, Erica, & Lillian, Dang (2015) Addressing Land Conflict in Afghanistan, Special Report 372, Washington, DC: United States Institute of Peace.Google Scholar
Geertz, Clifford (1962) “The Rotating Credit Association: A ‘Middle Rung’ in Development.” 10 Economic Development and Cultural Change 241–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geertz, Clifford (1978) “The Bazaar Economy: Information and Search in Peasant Marketing.” 68 The American Economic Review 2832.Google Scholar
Ghate, Prabhu (1992) Informal Finance: Some Findings from Asia, Hong Kong: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Gilchrist, Simon, & Egon, Zakrajšek (1998) “The Importance of Credit for Macroeconomic Activity: Identification through Heterogeneity,” in Steven, Brakman, Hans, van Ees, & Kuipers, Simon K., eds., Market Behaviour and Macroeconomic Modelling, London: Palgrave Macmillan UK, 129–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granovetter, Mark (1973) “The Strength of Weak Ties.” 78 American Journal of Sociology 1360–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granovetter, Mark (1985) “Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness.” 91 American Journal of Sociology 481510.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hanifi, Shah Mahmoud (2004) “Impoverishing a Colonial Frontier: Cash, Credit, and Debt in Nineteenth-Century Afghanistan.” 37 Iranian Studies 199218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hardin, Russell (2001) “Distrust.” 81 Boston University Law Review 495522.Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell (2004) “Distrust: Manifestations and Management,” in Hardin, Russell, ed., Distrust, New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 333.Google Scholar
Hawley, K. (2014) “Trust, Distrust and Commitment.48 Noûs 120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hendley, Kathryn, Murrell, Peter, & Ryterman, Randi (2001) “Beyond the Tip of the Iceberg: Business Disputes in Russia,” in Murrell, P., ed., Assessing the Value of Law in Transition Economies, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 5693.Google Scholar
Higgins, Andrew (2010) “In Afghanistan, Signs of Crony Capitalism: Retrieved February 2, 2019,” Washington Post, 22 February.Google Scholar
Horii, Satoe (2002) “Reconsideration of Legal Devices (Hiyal) in Islamic Jurisprudence: The Hanafis and Their Exits (Makharij)” 9 Islamic Law and Society 312–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
IMF (2011) Islamic Republic of Afghanistan: Detailed Assessment Report on Anti-Money Laundering and Combating the Financing of Terrorism, No. IMF Country Report No. 11/317, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kennedy, David (2011) “Some Caution about Property Rights as a Recipe for Economic Development.1 Accounting, Economics, and Law 162.Google Scholar
Khan, Hamid M. (2015) Islamic Law, Customary Law, and Afghan Informal Justice, Washington, DC: United States Institute of Peace.Google Scholar
Klijn, Floortje (2006) Informal Credit Practices in Rural Afghanistan. Case Study 1: Herat, Kabul: Afghanistan Research and Evaluation Unit.Google Scholar
Klijn, Floortje, & Adam, Pain (2007) Finding the Money: Informal Credit Practices in Rural Afghanistan, Kabul: Afghanistan Research and Evaluation Unit.Google Scholar
Lee, Yul W., & Stowe, John D. (1993) “Product Risk, Asymmetric Information, and Trade Credit.” 28 Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 285300.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luhmann, Niklas (1979) Trust and Power, New York: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Macneil, Ian R. (1978) Contracts: Exchange Transactions and Relations, New York: Foundation Press.Google Scholar
Macneil, Ian R. (1985) “Relational Contract: What We Do and Do Not Know.” 1985 Wisconsin Law Review 483525.Google Scholar
Maksimovic, Vojislav, & Frank, Murray Z. (1998) “Trade Credit, Collateral, and Adverse Selection,” University of Maryland, https://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=87868 (accessed 1 March 2019).Google Scholar
Malejacq, Romain, & Dipali, Mukhopadhyay (2016) “The ‘Tribal Politics’ of Field Research: A Reflection on Power and Partiality in 21st-Century Warzones.” 14 Perspectives of Politics 95117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mallett, R., & Adam, Pain (2017) Markets, Conflict and Recovery: Findings from the Secure Livelihoods Research Consortium, London: Secure Livelihoods Research Consortium.Google Scholar
Mansfield, David, & Adam, Pain (2007) Evidence from the Field: Understanding Changing Levels of Opium Poppy Cultivation in Afghanistan , Briefing Paper Series, Kabul: Afghanistan Research and Evaluation Unit.Google Scholar
Marsden, Magnus (2015) “From Kabul to Kiev: Afghan Trading Networks across the Former Soviet Union.” 49 Modern Asian Studies 1010–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marsden, Magnus (2016) Trading Worlds: Afghan Merchants across Modern Frontiers, London: C Hurst & Co. Publishers Ltd.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marsden, Magnus (2018) “Beyond Bukhara: Trade, Identity and Interregional Exchange across Asia.” 29 History and Anthropology S84100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Massoud, Mark Fathi (2016) “Field Research on Law in Conflict Zones and Authoritarian States.” 12 Annual Review of Law and Social Science 85106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mauss, Marcel (1966) The Gift: Forms and Functions of Exchange in Archaic Societies, trans. Cunnison, Ian, London: Cohen & West Ltd.Google Scholar
McLeod, Grant (2016) Responding to Corruption and the Kabul Bank Collapse, Washington, DC: United States Institute of Peace.Google Scholar
McMillan, John, & Christopher, Woodruff (1999a) “Dispute Prevention without Courts in Vietnam.” 15 Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 637–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McMillan, John, & Christopher, Woodruff (1999b) “Interfirm Relationships and Informal Credit in Vietnam.” 114 The Quarterly Journal of Economics 1285–320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McMillan, John, & Christopher, Woodruff (2000) “Private Order under Dysfunctional Public Order.” 98 Michigan Law Review 2421–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meininghaus, Esther (2007) “Legal Pluralism in Afghanistan,” ZEF Working Papers Series—Amu Darya Series Paper No. 72, Bonn: University of Bonn, Center for Development ResearchGoogle Scholar
Merryman, J. H., & Pérez-Perdomo, Rogelio (2007) The Civil Law Tradition: An Introduction to the Legal Systems of Europe and Latin America, Palo Alto: Stanford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mian, Shehzad L., & Smith, Clifford W. (1992) “Accounts Receivable Management Policy: Theory and Evidence.” 47 The Journal of Finance 169200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Minoia, Giulia, & Adam, Pain (2017) Understanding Rural Markets in Afghanistan, London: Secure Livelihoods Research Consortium.Google Scholar
Minoia, Giulia, Wamiqullah, Mumatz, & Adam, Pain (2014) The Social Life of the Onion: The Informal Regulation of the Onion Market in Nangarhar, Afghanistan, London: Secure Livelihoods Research Consortium.Google Scholar
Monsutti, Alessandro (2013) “Anthropologizing Afghanistan: Colonial and Postcolonial Encounters.” 42 Annual Review of Anthropology 269–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morris, Stephen D., & Klesner, Joseph L. (2010) “Corruption and Trust: Theoretical Considerations and Evidence from Mexico.” 43 Comparative Political Studies 1258–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mutfi, Abdul Qadeer, Amirahmadian, Bahram, & Sachedva, Gulshan (2018) Strategic Analysis of the Charbahar Port: Afghanistan-Iran-India Relations, No. AISS-P-013-2018, Kabul: Afghan Institute for Strategic Studies.Google Scholar
Nelken, David (2004) “Using the Concept of Legal Culture.” 29 Australian Journal of Legal Philosophy 126.Google Scholar
Nooteboom, Bart (2002) Trust: Forms, Foundations, Functions, Failures, and Figures, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
OECD (2019) Boosting Private Sector Development and Entrepreneurship in Afghanistan, Paris: Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development.Google Scholar
OIG (2011) Review of USAID/Afghanistan’s Bank Supervision Assistance Activities and the Kabul Bank Crisis, No. F-306–11–003-S, Kabul: Office of Inspector General, United State Agency for International Development.Google Scholar
Pain, Adam (2008) Opium Poppy and Informal Credit, Kabul: Afghanistan Research and Evaluation Unit.Google Scholar
Paquin, Julie (2012) Legal Reform and Business Contracts in Developing Economies: Trust, Culture, and Law in Dakar, London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Petersen, Mitchell A., & Rajan, Raghuram G. (1997) “Trade Credit: Theories and Evidence.” 10 The Review of Financial Studies 661–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Portes, Alejandro, & William, Haller (2010) “Informal Economy,” in Smelser, Neil J. & Swedberg, Richard, eds., The Handbook of Economic Sociology, Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press, 403–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rahbari, Siavash (2018) “From Normative Pluralism to a Unified Legal System in Afghanistan?” 5 Asian Journal of Law and Society 289314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rahim, Ahmad Shoaib (2018) “Afghanistan’s Dependence on Pakistan: Trade, Transit and the Cost of Being Landlocked” 1 Kardan Journal of Economics and Management Sciences 121.Google Scholar
Rahimi, Haroun (2015) “The Customary Practice of Gerawee in Afghanistan: A Case for Transitioning to Real Equity-Based Finance.2 Indonesian Journal of International & Comparative Law 743–74.Google Scholar
Rashid, Ahmed (2001) Taliban: The Story of Afghan Warlords, London: Pan.Google Scholar
Rubin, Alissa J. (2015) “Flawed Justice after a Mob Killed an Afghan Woman,” New York Times, 26 December.Google Scholar
Sadat, Mir Hekmatullah (1999) “The Life of a 102 Year-Old Afghan Entrepreneur: An Economic Perspective,” Afghan Magazine, https://afghanmagazine.com/post/186474964049/the-life-of-a-102-year-old-afghan-entrepreneur-an (accessed 1 March 2019).Google Scholar
Saeed, Abdullah (1999) Islamic Banking and Interest: A Study of the Prohibition of Riba and its Contemporary Interpretation, 2nd edn, Leiden: Brill.Google Scholar
Schütte, Stefan (2009) “Informal (In)Security in Urban Afghanistan.” 42 Iranian Studies 465–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seifert, Daniel, Seifert, Raif W., & Protopappa-Sieke, Margarita (2013) “A Review of Trade Credit Literature: Opportunities for Research in Operations.” 231 European Journal of Operational Research 245–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shapiro, Susan P. (1987) “The Social Control of Impersonal Trust.” 93 American Journal of Sociology 623–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shaw, Tom, & Ihsanullah, Ghafoori (2019) On Borrowed Time: The Limits of Informal Credit for Livelihood Security in Herat, Afghanistan, No. 69, London: Secure Livelihoods Research Consortium.Google Scholar
SIGAR Audit Report (2014a) Afghanistan’s Banking Sector: The Central Bank’s Capacity to Regulate Commercial Banks Remains Weak, No. SIGAR 14–16 Audit Report, Arlington, VA: Office of the Special Inspector General for Afghanistan Reconstruction.Google Scholar
SIGAR Audit Report (2014b) Support for Afghanistan’s Justice Sector: State Department Programs Need Better Management and Stronger Oversight, No. SIGAR 15–68 Audit Report, Arlington, VA: Office of the Special Inspector General for Afghanistan Reconstruction.Google Scholar
Skully, Michael (1994) “The Development of the Pawnshop Industry in East Asia,” in Bouman, F. J. A. & Hospes, O., eds., Financial Landscapes Reconstructed: The Fine Art of Mapping Development, Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 357–74.Google Scholar
Srinivas, Hari (2016) 14 Reasons Why the Informal Credit Market Is Used by the Poor: Policy Implications for Microcredit Programmes in Developing Countries, No. GDRC Research Output E-111, Kobe: Global Development Research Center.Google Scholar
Srinivas, Hari, & Yoichiro, Higuchi (1996) “A Continuum of Informality of Credit: What Can Informal Lenders Teach Us?” 20 Savings and Development 207–23.Google Scholar
Suhrke, Astri (2011) When More Is Less, New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Suhrke, Astri, & Kaja, Borchgrevink (2009) “Negotiating Justice Sector Reform in Afghanistan.” 51 Crime, Law and Social Change 211–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swenson, Geoffrey (2017) “Why U.S. Efforts to Promote the Rule of Law in Afghanistan Failed.” 42 International Security 114–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thompson, Edwina (2011) Trust Is the Coin of the Realm: Lessons from the Money Men of Afghanistan, Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
TOLOnews (2013) “Report Shows Judiciary is Most Corrupt Institution in Afghanistan,” TOLOnews, 11 July.Google Scholar
Transparency.org (2018) “Corruption Perception Index 2018,” https://www.transparency.org/cpi2018 (accessed 12 February 2019).Google Scholar
Ward, Christopher, Mansfield, David, Oldham, Peter, et al. (2008) Afghanistan: Economic Incentives and Development Initiatives to Reduce Opium Production, Washington, DC: Department for International Development/World Bank.Google Scholar
World Bank (2019) Combined Project Information Documents/Integrated Safeguards Datasheet (PID/ISID), PIDISIDSA24982, Afghanistan Land Administration System Project, Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Yassari, Nadjma, & Mohammad Hamid, Saboory (2010) “Sharia and National Law in Afghanistan,” in Otto, Michiel, ed., Sharia Incorporated: A Comparative Overview of the Legal Systems of Twelve Muslim Countries in Past and Present, Leiden: Leiden University Press, 273318.Google Scholar
Yimer, Gebreyesus Abegaz, Wim, Decock, Mehreteab, Ghebremeskel Ghebregergs, et al. (2018) “The Interplay between Official and Unofficial Laws in Rotating Savings and Credit Associations (Eqqub) in Tigray, Ethiopia.” 50 The Journal of Legal Pluralism and Unofficial Law 94113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
You, Jong-sung (2018) “Trust and Corruption,” in Uslaner, Eric M., ed., The Oxford Handbook of Social and Political Trust, New York: Oxford University Press, 473–96.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. The value of imports and exports for Afghanistan. Source: Based on data from the World Bank.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Imports as a percentage of the GDP. Source: Based on data from the World Bank.