Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dzt6s Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T16:42:50.427Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Optimal commissions and subscriptions in mutual aid platforms

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 July 2023

Yixing Zhao
Affiliation:
School of Finance, Guangdong University of Foreign Studies, Guangzhou 510006, PR China
Yan Zeng*
Affiliation:
Lingnan College, Sun Yat-sen University, Guangzhou 510275, PR China
*
Corresponding author: Yan Zeng; Email: [email protected]
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This paper investigates an operation mechanism for mutual aid platforms to develop more sustainably and profitably. A mutual aid platform is an online risk-sharing platform for risk-heterogeneous participants, and the platform extracts revenues by charging participants commission and subscription fees. A modeling framework is proposed to identify the optimal commissions and subscriptions for mutual aid platforms. Participants are divided into different types based on their loss probabilities and values derived from the platform. We present how these commissions and subscriptions should be set in a mutual aid plan to maximize the platform’s revenues. Our analysis emphasized the importance of accounting for risk heterogeneity in mutual aid platforms. Specifically, different types of participants should be charged different commissions/subscriptions depending on their loss probabilities and values on the platform. Participants’ shared costs should be determined based on their loss probabilities. Adverse selection occurs on the platform if participants with different risks pay the same shared costs. Our results also show that the platform’s maximum revenue will be lower if the platform charges the same fee to all participants. The numerical results of a practical example illustrate that the optimal commission/subscription scheme and risk-sharing rule result in considerable improvements in platform revenue over the current scheme implemented by the platform.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of The International Actuarial Association

1. Introduction

This paper investigates the operation mechanism for the sustainability and profitability of mutual aid platforms. Mutual aid platforms, as innovations of insurance and finance based on the internet and InsurTech, have attracted more than 300 million participants in China and have become the third most-popular choice for healthcare coverage after social health insurance and commercial health insurance. Platforms facilitate the process of risk exchange among participants by charging a commission (a percentage of the claim benefit), a subscription (a fixed fee that people pay to participate in the platform), or both. Most platforms implement simple payment schemes and charge the same fees to all participants. For example, Xianghubao charges an 8% commission to all participants, while participants in Waterdrop Mutual Aid pay a 9-yuan subscription fee to join the platform. Furthermore, participants in platforms share their risks by paying the same shared costs. However, most platforms do not consider the risk heterogeneity of participants when designing payment schemes and risk-sharing rules. For instance, people aged 59 years or younger are all eligible to be enrolled in Xianghubao. However, the loss probability of a person aged 59 years can be 47 times greater than that of a 19-year-old person. Charging the same fees to participants of different risk levels or setting the same shared costs can result in adverse selection and platform revenue loss. Because of the inappropriate payment schemes and risk-sharing rules, most mutual aid platforms are in deficit and face the risk of bankruptcy. Therefore, the objective of this paper is to find a better operation mechanism for the sustainable and profitable growth of mutual platforms and to offer guidelines to mutual aid platforms on establishing more sophisticated commission/subscription schemes and risk-sharing rules. Specifically, this paper aims to investigate the optimal design of commission rates and subscription fees, as well as a fair risk-sharing rule for mutual aid platforms to maximize their revenues by considering different types of participants in platforms.

In our opinion, the contribution of this paper is threefold. The first main contribution is that we propose a better operation mechanism for the sustainability and profitability of mutual aid platforms. The mechanism is based mainly on the establishment of commission/subscription schemes and risk-sharing rules. Mutual aid platforms can increase their revenues and be more sustainable by applying this mechanism. To achieve this goal, we propose a mathematical model to analyze mutual aid platforms by capturing the main features of these platforms and their participants. The second contribution is that we shed light on the design of commission/subscription schemes, based on our platform’s revenue maximum problem. Previous papers studying mutual aid platforms have mainly focused on the risk exchange problem among participants (e.g., Denuit, Reference Denuit2019, Reference Denuit2020; Abdikerimova and Feng, Reference Abdikerimova and Feng2022). In our work, we study the implications of commissions and subscriptions charged by mutual aid platforms and the effects of commissions/subscriptions on risk exchange process. To the best of our knowledge, this paper might be the first studying mutual aid platforms from the perspective of the payment scheme of the platform. The third contribution is that we emphasize the importance of accounting for risk heterogeneity when determining commissions and subscriptions. The importance of accounting for risk heterogeneity is neglected in the current mechanism of mutual aid platforms. We show that adverse selection occurs if all of the participants share the costs equally. Furthermore, charging the same fee to all participants can result in platform revenue loss.

Our work relates to models of risk-sharing mechanisms. Risk-sharing mechanisms, especially peer-to-peer (P2P) risk-sharing mechanisms, have been studied intensively in recent years since the emergence of P2P insurances and mutual aid platforms. Denuit (Reference Denuit2019, Reference Denuit2020) and Denuit and Robert Reference Denuit and Robert(2020) studied the risk-sharing rule and proposed a risk-sharing model in P2P insurance. The model has been extended to study the three business models in P2P insurance (Denuit and Robert, Reference Denuit and Robert2021b), pure premiums for a large number of heterogeneous losses (Denuit and Robert, Reference Denuit and Robert2021a) and the P2P insurance scheme where the higher layer is transferred to a reinsurer (Denuit and Robert, Reference Denuit and Robert2021c). Boyle et al. (Reference Boyle, Pesic, Jevtic and Boscovic2021) studied the application of blockchain technique on P2P insurance. Abdikerimova and Feng (Reference Abdikerimova and Feng2022) and Feng et al. (Reference Feng, Liu and Taylor2020) proposed a risk-sharing rule called fair risk exchange, in which the variance in shared costs is minimal. Li et al. (Reference Li, Fang, Nie and Chen2022) put forward an optimal design for the mutual aid platform. Our work is an extension of models in previous literature by incorporating payment method and platform’s revenues.

Our work is also related to literature in platforms. In particular, mutual aid platforms are analogous to P2P service platforms, which include personal and professional services, such as product sharing, transportation, and food delivery. Such platforms have been studied intensively in the recent literature. Benjaafar et al. (Reference Benjaafar, Kong, Li and Courcoubetis2019) described a P2P product sharing model in which each individual decides on whether to own, rent from others who own or neither. They found that consumers always benefit from collaborative consumption. Jiang and Lin (Reference Jiang and Lin2018) studied the strategic and economic impacts of product sharing among consumers and found that sharing of products is a win-win situation for both the firm and consumers if the firm’s marginal costs are high. Other research topics on online service platforms have included the pricing, profits, and efficiency of platforms (see, e.g., Carlin, Reference Carlin2009; Bellos et al., Reference Bellos, Ferguson and Toktay2017; Bimpikis et al., Reference Bimpikis, Candogan and Saban2017), the performance of medical crowdfunding platform (Liu et al., Reference Liu, Cheng and Wang2020), the impact of online inquiry services on gatekeeping systems (Li et al., Reference Li, Huang, Chen and Zhou2019) and the behavior equilibrium model with mode choice (Wang et al., Reference Wang, Qi, Xu and Ryu2020). Different from other P2P service platforms, mutual aid platforms provide risk-sharing services to participants. We extend the horizon of online platform research topics by incorporating risk-sharing features into the platform.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents an overview of the development, advantages and the mechanism of a mutual aid plan. Section 3 proposes a framework to model the main features of mutual aid plans and constructs the optimization problem to maximize platform revenues. The impact of adverse selection on mutual aid platforms is studied in Section 3 as well. Section 4 obtains optimal solutions to the optimization problem and considers a special case in which the platform charges the same fees to all participants. Section 5 presents a numerical example. Finally, noteworthy conclusions are summarized in Section 6.

2. Mutual aid platform

In this section, we provide a brief discussion of the development and the mechanism of the mutual aid platform.

2.1. Development of the mutual aid platform

With the development of internet technology and InsurTech, conventional insurance companies have shifted their focus to online insurance. Many insurance innovations specifically designed for online selling have been proposed. An online insurance platform has advantages over conventional insurance in a few aspects, such as convenience, efficiency, and ease of access. Along with the development of online insurance, a new type of online platform, the online mutual aid platform, has emerged in China. The online mutual aid platform is an innovation of both insurance and finance, and it is an internet-based platform adopting InsurTech during its entire operation process. In an online mutual aid platform, participants can share the risk of becoming critically ill and bear the medical expenses of patients collectively. Mutual aid platforms have quickly become popular because of their lower barriers to entry. An individual can pay a small fee to participate in a mutual aid plan provided by a platform and receive a considerable benefit if she is diagnosed with a critical illness covered by the plan. Mutual aid platforms typically provide participants with basic health plans covering more than 100 types of critical illnesses, including cancer, heart attack, critical brain injury, and acute myocardial infarction. Since the outbreak of COVID-19 (coronavirus disease 2019) worldwide, many mutual aid platforms have extended their coverage to include COVID-19.

Approximately 300 million members had enrolled in mutual aid platforms by early 2020 (See Figure 1). The annual growth rate of numbers of participants exceeded 100%. By 2025, the number of participants in China’s online mutual aid platforms is expected to reach 450 million or nearly 32% of the country’s population, according to Research Institute of Ant Group (2020).

Figure 1. Number of participants in mutual aid platforms in China (in millions).

According to Research Institute of Ant Group (2020), users of online mutual aid programs in China are primarily from low-income or middle-income households. Among more than 58,000 mutual aid platform users who were surveyed, 80% earn less than 8333 yuan per month, while 72% come from third or lower-tier cities and rural areas. Therefore, mutual aid platforms are an alternative health coverage program for developing countries. The survey also indicated that online mutual aid platforms serve as a complement by further reducing out-of-pocket expenses accrued in the treatment of critical illnesses, bringing it from 40% to less than 20% for patients solely dependent on public healthcare coverage. While nearly 70% of online mutual aid participants surveyed by Research Institute of Ant Group (2020) said that they were not covered by commercial health insurance, more than 42% said they intend to purchase such insurance products in the future. This finding suggests mutual aid platform can increase awareness of the importance of insurance. The survey showed that the mutual aid platform is a complement of the insurance market and provides low-cost health protection to lower income households.

The costs of mutual aid plans are much lower than commercial insurance premiums. For instance, the cost of a mutual aid plan offering 500,000 yuan in coverage is usually less than 100 yuan per year, while the premiums for commercial critical illness insurance are approximately 4000 yuan. This lower price is possible and the reasons are as follows. First, mutual aid platforms are based on the internet, and costs such as operating and administrative expenses are much lower than those incurred in conventional insurance. Second, for conventional insurance, insurers have to rely on insurance agents and insurance brokers to sell insurance products. The commission fees of insurance agents and insurance brokers increase premiums of conventional insurance. Third, there are waiting periods in mutual aid plans. During the waiting periods, participants only pay the shared costs but cannot apply for benefits. As the participant populations of mutual aid platforms increase sharply in these years, many participants are still in the waiting period. There are more participants to share the costs of benefits and hence the shared costs are much lower.

2.2. Mechanism of the mutual aid platform

The organizational structure of a mutual aid platform is illustrated in Figure 2. Unlike conventional insurance companies that adopt a centralized model, mutual aid platforms apply noncentralized systems. Participants in the plan do not need to pay premiums in advance to pool their resources to pay for those who suffer critical illnesses. They collaboratively share the costs of benefits paid to those claimants at the end of each mutual aid plan period. The platform facilitates transfers between participants but is not allowed to take possession of participants’ payments. According to the regulation issued by the China Insurance Regulatory Commission (CIRC), a mutual aid platform is not allowed to commit to risk insurance liability or use the word “guarantee” in any way. Furthermore, a mutual aid platform is not allowed to collect insurance premiums or establish pools of funds. As a result, a mutual aid platform does not guarantee the settlement of claims and does not incur the risk that a conventional insurance company takes. Therefore, the platform is not an insurer but acts as an intermediary and facilitator that provides participants with a risk-sharing platform and other related services.

Figure 2. A graphic illustration of a mutual aid platform.

The mutual aid plan operates as depicted in Figure 3. In general, there are two stages of a mutual aid plan: the beginning of the plan ( $t=0$ ) and the end of the plan ( $t=1$ ). At time $t=0$ , the mutual aid platform launches a mutual aid plan and releases the necessary information to the public. This information typically includes the rules of the mutual aid plan, benefit amount, how the costs of benefits are shared, and what critical illnesses are covered, among other factors. Individuals gather the information from the platform and decide whether to join the plan based on their own characteristics and valuations. People who decide to join the plan sign a contract and pay a subscription fee. These individuals form a risk-sharing community through the mutual aid plan. At time $t=1$ , some participants in the plan are diagnosed with a covered critical illness and claim benefits to cover their medical expenses. Their cases are subject to reviews by third-party investigation groups appointed by the platform. The platform checks the eligibility of every applicant to ensure that no applicant is cheating. The application information is also released to other participants, and they are part of the committee that makes the judgment. After all applications have been approved, the total benefits paid to claimants and the corresponding costs carried by the remaining participants in the plan are determined. Finally, all of the participants in the plan make the payments needed to share the costs of benefits paid to those who suffered losses, and the claimants receive benefits from the platform. The platform charges commissions when transfers are made between participants.

Figure 3. Sequence of events.

Having summarized the features of mutual aid plans, we conclude that there are two main factors that the platform must consider when designing a mutual aid plan, which are the risk-sharing rule and the payment scheme. The risk-sharing rule determines how participants share their risks. At the end of a period, participants share the costs of benefits used for claimants. In most platforms, participants pay the same shared costs, which is the total benefits divided by the number of participants. The payment scheme is comprised of commissions and subscription fees as follows.

  • The commission, which is also called the management fee, is charged as a percentage (commission rate) of the shared costs paid by participants. Recall that participants’ shared costs are for the benefits paid to those who suffer losses. Therefore, the commission is charged upon the occurrence of loss. More claims lead to more commissions. Commissions can be used to cover the costs and expenses incurred during the payment process. The excess portion of the commission can be viewed as part of the income of the platform. Without loss of generality, we assume that the transaction cost is 0 in this paper.

  • The subscription fee, which is also called the member fee, is the fee that participants pay for entering the mutual aid plan. Some platforms waive the subscription fee to attract more individuals. Other platforms charge a small entrance fee. Unlike the commission, the subscription fee is independent of the shared costs paid by participants. Note that the subscription fee is different from an insurance premium because it is not used for claims reserves.

Some examples of mutual aid plans provided by different platforms in China are presented in Table 1. Xianghubao and Kangai Gongshe allow individuals to join the mutual aid plan for free and only charge commissions. In contrast, e Mutual Aid charges a high subscription fee, but there is no commission. The policies of mutual aid plans are adjusted constantly. For instance, the commission rate of Xianghubao was 10% in 2019 but decreased to 8% in 2020.

Table 1. Some examples of mutual aid platforms

3. Modeling framework

In this section, a modeling framework is proposed to describe the main features of the mutual aid platform and participants. The impact of adverse selection on mutual aid platforms is also studied. An optimization problem is constructed for the platform to obtain its maximum revenue by setting the optimal commission rates and subscription fees.

3.1. Participants

We consider a monopolistic mutual aid platform that offers a general mutual aid plan for people to share their risks. People who have the potential to participate in the plan are all referred to as participants in this paper. We assume that participants are divided into finitely many types, denoted by $\mathcal{N}=\{1,\ldots,n\}$ . We further suppose that participants of each type are infinitesimal, for example, there are a continuum of participants. We denote the total number of type-i potential participants by $m_{i}\gt0$ , $i\in \mathcal{N}$ . Participants of type i have the probability $p_{i}$ of being diagnosed with a critical illness and faced with a loss $X_{i}$ . $p_{i}$ is regarded as the loss probability of type-i participants. If participants are critically ill, they can receive the benefit $I_{i}$ from the mutual aid platform. We assume that the loss is fully covered by the mutual aid plan, that is, $I_{i}=X_{i}$ . If participants are not diagnosed with a critical illness, they must pay the shared cost $S_{i}$ plus a commission to the platform. $S_{i}$ is the cost of claim benefits carried by a type-i participant. The platform collects $S_{i}$ from all healthy participants and pays the benefits to the claimants. $S_{i}$ is endogenous and uncertain, and it depends on the total amount of benefits, total participant population in the plan and the risk level of each participant type. In our model assumptions, participants of each types are infinitesimal. This is a reasonable assumption when the number of participants is typically large enough and this assumption has been extensively used in economic models. As discussed by Lucas (Reference Lucas1980) and Prescott and Townsend (Reference Prescott and Townsend1984a,b), with a continuum of participants, the loss probability $p_{i}$ of type-i participants is also the fraction of type-i participants that will suffer a loss. Let $s_{i}$ be the limit value of $S_{i}$ for all i. As we consider the limiting case, we use $s_{i}$ as the shared cost in the model. The calculation of $s_{i}$ and the expression for $s_{i}$ will be discussed in detail later. Since the costs of benefits paid to claimants are all carried by the rest of the participants in the plan, the total amount of fees collected from participants is equal to the amount of benefits paid to claimants. In our modeling setting, different types of participants have different risk levels (i.e., loss probability), benefits, and shared costs.

Suppose that participants’ valuation of participating in the mutual aid plan is denoted by v. This assumption is motivated by the work of Birge et al. (Reference Birge, Candogan, Chen and Saban2021), in which sellers and buyers derive values from transacting with each other. Similar assumptions have been made by, for instance, Bellos et al. (Reference Bellos, Ferguson and Toktay2017) and Taylor (Reference Taylor2018). v is used to measure participants’ willingness to participate in a mutual aid plan. The participant value v may be explained by the following three terms. The first term is the value for which the participant can receive compensation for a potential loss. The second term is the value that comes from the satisfaction that the participant derives from being able to help others who are critically ill. The third term is the value derived from other related services offered by the platform. However, we do not specify how the participant value is expressed by these three terms. The participant value is the combination of all the personal factors those will affect the willingness to participate in the mutual aid plan. Thus, we only focus on the participant value. v is an exogenous variable in our model assumption and the value v is assumed to be a constant value for a specific participant. However, we assume that the values that participants of the same type derive from participating in the plan are heterogeneous. The distribution of v among type-i participants is described by the cumulative distribution function $F_{i}:[0,\bar{v}_{i}]\rightarrow[0,1]$ . Such assumption has been adopted in many literature on platforms, such as Taylor (Reference Taylor2018), Bellos et al. (Reference Bellos, Ferguson and Toktay2017), Jiang and Lin (Reference Jiang and Lin2018), and Birge et al. (Reference Birge, Candogan, Chen and Saban2021). $\bar{v}_{i}\in \mathbb{R}^{+}\cup \{\infty\}$ is the upper bound of the value derived from the plan by type-i participants. Suppose that $F_{i}(v)$ , for all $i \in \mathcal{N}$ , is continuously differentiable and strictly increasing in $v \in [0, \bar{v}_{i}]$ with respect to v. Under these assumptions, functions $F_{i}$ are invertible. Let $F_{i}^{-1}:[0,1]\rightarrow [0,\bar{v}_{i}]$ be the corresponding inverse function; we have $F_{i}^{-1}(F_{i}(v))=v$ for $v\in [0,\bar{v}_{i}]$ . For ease of convenience, we extend the domain of $F_{i}$ to $\mathbb{R}$ , that is, $F_{i}(v)=0$ for $v\leq 0$ and $F_{i}(v)=1$ for $v\geq \bar{v}_{i}$ .

The platform can charge additional fees to participants to facilitate the processes of the mutual aid plan and provide services to participants. We assume that the platform chooses commission rates (a percentage of the total benefits) and subscription fees (lump-sum transfers to participate in the plan independent of total indemnity benefits). Suppose that the commission rates and subscription fees are the same for all participants of the same type but can be different for different types of participants. Let $\alpha_{i}$ represent the commission rate for type-i participants and $\beta_{i}$ represent the subscription fee for type-i participants. We assume that the set of feasible commission rates is $\alpha_{i}\in [0,\infty),\forall i \in \mathcal{N}$ , and the set of feasible subscription rates is $\beta_{i}\in [0, \infty),\forall i \in \mathcal{N}$ . We denote by $(\boldsymbol{\alpha},\boldsymbol{\beta})$ with $\boldsymbol{\alpha}=(\alpha_{1},\ldots,\alpha_{n})$ and $\boldsymbol{\beta}=(\beta_{1},\ldots,\beta_{n})$ the platform’s commission and subscription vectors, respectively.

We next study behaviors of participants. Participants’ decisions to join the mutual aid platform are based on their expected profits. Suppose that a participant of type $i\in \mathcal{N}$ with value $v\in[0,\bar{v}_{i}]$ decides to participate in the plan. Then, the participant pays the subscription fee $\beta_{i}$ at time $t=0$ and obtains the value v. At time $t=1$ , the participant will be faced with the loss $X_{i}$ and receive the benefit $I_{i}$ and if she is diagnosed with a critical illness (with probability $p_{i}$ ). In this case, the expected profit is $U_{i,c}(v)=v-\beta_{i}+I_{i}-X_{i}$ . If the participant is healthy (with probability $1-p_{i}$ ), she must pay the shared cost $s_{i}$ plus the commission $s_{i}\alpha_{i}$ to the platform. Then her expected profit is $U_{i,h}(v)=v-\beta_{i}-s_{i}(1+\alpha_{i})$ . Therefore, this participant’s expected profit at time $t=1$ if she joins the platform is

\begin{equation*}U_{i}(v)=pU_{i,c}(v)+(1-p)U_{i,h}(v)=v-(1-p_{i})s_{i}(1+\alpha_{i})-\beta_{i}+p_{i}I_{i}-p_{i}X_{i}.\end{equation*}

If the type-i participant decides not to participate in the mutual aid plan, the corresponding expected profit is $U_{i,n}=-p_{i}X_{i}$ . If $U_{i}(v) \geq U_{i,n}$ , which is $v\geq (1-p_{i})s_{i}(1+\alpha_{i})+\beta_{i}-p_{i}I_{i}$ , the participant has a greater profit if she chooses to join the mutual aid plan. If $v\lt(1-p_{i})s_{i}(1+\alpha)+\beta-p_{i}I_{i}$ , that is, the value v is less than the expected outflow, the participant will choose not to participate in the plan because her expected profit is lower after she joins the plan. We assume that all participants’ behaviors are based on their expected profits and that they are all profit maximizers. Thus, given commission rates and subscription rates, the action undertaken by each participant maximizes her profit. That is, the profit-maximizing participant participates in the mutual aid plan only if the profit is greater after she joins the mutual aid plan.

Let $ l_{i}$ be the total participant population of type-i participants who participate in the mutual aid plan, that is, the participant population of type-i participants. Given commission rates and subscription fees, all type-i participants who have greater expected profits ( $U_{i}(v)\geq U_{i,n}$ ) will participate in the plan, meaning that the value of a type-i participant in the plan is at least $(1-p_{i})s_{i}(1+\alpha_{i})+\beta_{i}-p_{i}I_{i}$ . Thus, $l_{i}$ is given by

(3.1) \begin{equation}l_{i}=m_{i}\big[1-F_{i}\big((1-p_{i})s_{i}(1+\alpha_{i})+\beta_{i}-p_{i}I_{i}\big)\big],\quad\forall i\in\mathcal{N},\end{equation}

where $m_{i}$ is the total potential population of type-i participants. It is obvious that $0\leq l_{i}\leq m_{i}$ for $i \in \mathcal{N}$ . Note that, in mutual aid plans, benefits paid to claimants all come from other participants. The platform only serves as an intermediary and charges a small amount of fees to participants. Therefore, we assume the total costs paid by all participants (excluding the fees paid to the platform) are equal to the total value of benefits received by claimants.

Suppose $r_{i}$ is the the random percentage of population suffering the illness. The condition described above can be written as

(3.2) \begin{equation}\sum_{i} l_{i}r_{i}I_{i}=\sum_{i}l_{i}(1-r_{i})S_{i}.\end{equation}

We assume that each type-i participant’s shared cost $S_{i}$ is determined through the weight factor $w_{i}$ . $w_{i}$ is exogenous in this paper and is determined before choosing optimal commission rates and subscription fees, while $s_{i}$ is endogenous and is based on the participant populations, subscription fees, and commission rates. Participants of different types are assigned different weights to reflect the different risk levels of different participant types. The relationship between shared costs and weight factors of different participant types is given by

(3.3) \begin{equation} \frac{S_{i}}{S_{j}}=\frac{w_{i}}{w_{j}},\quad\forall i,j\in \mathcal{N}.\end{equation}

Specifically, if we use $S_{1}$ as a basis, the shared cost of a type-i participant can be written as

\begin{equation*} S_{i}=\frac{w_{i}}{w_{1}}S_{1},\quad\forall i\in \mathcal{N}.\end{equation*}

The higher the value of $w_{i}$ is, the higher the risk of type-i participants is; hence, a higher shared cost should be paid by type-i participants. An appropriate way to choose the value of $w_{i}$ is discussed in the next subsection of this paper. From Equations (3.2) and(3.3), we have (for further details, see the Appendix)

(3.4) \begin{equation} S_{i}=\frac{w_{i}\sum_{j\in\mathcal{N}}l_{j}r_{j}I_{j}}{\sum_{j\in\mathcal{N}} l_{j}(1-r_{j})w_{j}},\quad\forall i\in\mathcal{N}.\end{equation}

As mentioned before, participants are assumed to be infinitesimal and therefore our model is under the limiting case. Such simplification is reasonable because the number of participants in mutual aid platforms are large enough. Taking the limit on both sides of (3.2) leads to (for further details, see the Appendix)

(3.5) \begin{equation}\sum_{i} l_{i}p_{i}I_{i}=\sum_{i}l_{i}(1-p_{i})s_{i}.\end{equation}

Similarly, Equation (3.4) can be rewritten as the limiting case, and we have

(3.6) \begin{equation} s_{i}=\frac{w_{i}\sum_{j\in\mathcal{N}} l_{j}p_{j}I_{j}}{\sum_{j\in\mathcal{N}}l_{j}(1-p_{j})w_{j}},\quad\forall i\in\mathcal{N}.\end{equation}

Here, the limit $s_{i}$ of $S_{i}$ is in the sense of convergence almost surely because $r_{i}$ converges to $p_{i}$ almost surely as the number of participants tends to be infinity. In the rest part of this paper, we use Equations (3.5) and (3.6) in the optimization model under the limiting case. It is also worth noting that the shared cost is not predetermined in the mutual aid plan in practice. It is calculated by using Equation (3.6) using the values of $w_{i}$ and $I_{i}$ , which are predetermined by the platform.

We can see that $\boldsymbol{s}=(s_{1},\ldots,s_{n})$ is endogenous and is determined by the populations of different types of participants in the mutual aid plan. Thus, $\boldsymbol{s}$ can be regarded as a function of $ \boldsymbol{l}$ . We have the following proposition to illustrate the relationships between $\boldsymbol{s}=(s_{1},\ldots,s_{n})$ and $ \boldsymbol{l}=(l_{1},\ldots,l_{n})$ .

Proposition 1. The relations between $s_{i}$ and $ l_{j}$ , for $i,j\in\mathcal{N}$ , are given by the following. (1) If $p_{j}I_{j}\geq (1-p_{j})s_{j}$ , $\frac{\partial s_{i}}{\partial l_{j}}\geq 0$ . (2) If $p_{j}I_{j}\lt(1-p_{j})s_{j}$ , $\frac{\partial s_{i}}{\partial l_{j}}\lt 0$ .

Proposition 1 states that $s_{i}$ is increasing in $ l_{j}$ if $p_{j}I_{j}\geq (1-p_{j})s_{j}$ and is decreasing in $l_{j}$ if $p_{j}I_{j}\lt (1-p_{j})s_{j}$ . Proposition 1 reveals the nature of participants’ shared costs. Note that $p_{j}I_{j}$ can be regarded as the expected benefit of type-j participants, and $(1-p_{j})s_{j}$ is the expected outgo in the mutual aid plan. $p_{j}I_{j}\gt (1-p_{j})s_{j}$ indicates that a type-j participant’s expected benefit is higher than her expected outgo. Thus, Proposition 1 implies that, if the expected benefit is higher than the expected outgo of type-j participants in the mutual aid plan, then increasing the population of type-j participants ( $ l_{j}$ ) will raise other participant types’ $s_{i}$ . Similarly, if the expected benefit is lower than the expected outgo of type-j participant in the mutual aid plan, increasing the population of type-j participants ( $ l_{j}$ ) will decrease other participant types’ $s_{i}$ . The main idea of this proposition is that the shared cost $s_{i}$ of type-i participants is affected by populations of other participant types. Additionally, note that a higher $p_{j}I_{j}$ means that type-j participants’ expected benefit is higher. Then, Proposition 1 can also be explained as follows: increasing the population of participants with high expected benefits will increase the costs of participants of all types, while increasing the population of participants with low expected benefits will decrease the costs of participants of all types. We consider a simple mutual aid plan that consists of only two participant types. The value of $s_{1}$ against $l_{1}$ is depicted in Figure 4. We can see that $s_{1}$ increases as $l_{1}$ increases when $p_{1}\gt p_{2}$ and decreases when $p_{1}\lt p_{2}$ . This outcome is consistent with the fact described in Proposition 1.

Figure 4. $s_{1}$ against $l_{1}$ ( $p_{2}=0.005$ , $l_{2}=0.5$ , $I_{1}=I_{2}=100,000$ yuan, $w_{1}=w_{2}=1$ ).

According to Proposition 1, the platform can change the shared costs by adjusting the participant populations. Specifically, the platform can increase or decrease the shared costs by increasing or decreasing the populations of some participant types. However, the platform cannot directly change the participant population since participants decide whether they will participate in the plan by themselves. Participant populations should be adjusted by changing commissions and subscription fees, which are set by the platform. Therefore, it is essential to investigate how participant populations are affected by commission-subscription schemes. The relationship between participant populations and commissions, as well as subscriptions, is given by the following proposition.

Proposition 2. The relations between $ l_{j}$ and $\alpha_{i}$ as well as $\beta_{i}$ are given by

  1. 1. For $i=j$ , $\frac{\partial l_{i}}{\partial \alpha_{i}}\leq 0$ , $\frac{\partial l_{i}}{\partial \beta_{i}}\leq 0$ ;

  2. 2. For $i\neq j$ ,(1) if $p_{j}I_{j}\geq (1-p_{j})s_{j}$ , $\frac{\partial l_{j}}{\partial \alpha_{i}}\leq 0$ and $\frac{\partial l_{j}}{\partial \beta_{i}}\leq 0$ ; (2) if $p_{j}I_{j}\lt (1-p_{j})s_{j}$ , $\frac{\partial l_{j}}{\partial \alpha_{i}}\gt 0$ and $\frac{\partial l_{j}}{\partial \beta_{i}}\gt 0$ .

Proposition 2 states that $l_{i}$ is decreasing in $\alpha_{i}$ and $\beta_{i}$ . For $i\neq j$ , $l_{j}$ is increasing in $\alpha_{i}$ and $\beta_{i}$ if $p_{j}I_{j}\geq (1-p_{j})s_{j}$ and is decreasing in $\alpha_{i}$ and $\beta_{i}$ if $p_{j}I_{j}\lt (1-p_{j})s_{j}$ . From Proposition 2, we know that populations of different types of participants in the plan can be adjusted by changing commission rates and subscription fees. The first part of Proposition 2 is obvious. Increasing commission rates or subscription fees will decrease the expected surplus of participants; thus, fewer participants will join the plan. The second part of Proposition 2 explains the relationships between the population of one participant type and the commission rates (or subscription fees) of other participant types. If the expected benefit is higher than the expected outgo of type-j participant in the mutual aid plan, that is, $p_{j}I_{j}\geq (1-p_{j})s_{j}$ , increasing the commission rates (or subscription fees) for type-i participants will decrease the population of type-j participants. The reason is that increasing the commission rates (or subscription fees) for type-i participants will lower the participant population of type-i participants. Then, there are fewer participants sharing risks with type-j participants, whose expected benefit is greater than the expected outgo. Thus, fewer type-j participants will join the plan. In contrast, if $p_{j}I_{j}\lt (1-p_{j})s_{j}$ , increasing the commission rates (or subscription fees) for type-i participants will increase the population of type-j participants.

From both Propositions 1 and 2, we know that commissions and subscriptions determine participant populations and hence shared costs. Keeping other parameters unchanged, if the population of riskier (i.e., with a high loss probability $p_{i}$ ) participants increases, the shared cost of each participant also increases. This outcome lowers the population of all participants of other types according to Equation (3.1). Similarly, increasing the population of participants of lower risk (i.e., with a low loss probability $p_{i}$ ) will lower the shared cost of each participant and hence raise the population of each type. Therefore, there exists an equilibrium for participant populations in the platform under which the participant populations are stable. If the platform is not in an equilibrium state, participant populations will move toward the equilibrium state. Given a feasible commission-subscription pair $(\boldsymbol{\alpha},\boldsymbol{\beta})$ , weight factors $\boldsymbol{w}=(w_{1},\ldots,w_{n})$ and benefits $\boldsymbol{I}=(I_{1},\ldots,I_{n})$ chosen by the platform, the participant populations will reach equilibrium. This equilibrium must satisfy Equations (3.1) and (3.6). Thus, we have the following definition.

Definition 1. Given a feasible commission-subscription pair $(\boldsymbol{\alpha},\boldsymbol{\beta})$ , weight factors $\boldsymbol{w}$ and benefits $\boldsymbol{I}$ chosen by the platform, we say that a participant population vector $ \boldsymbol{l}=(l_{1},\ldots,l_{n})$ reaches equilibrium if Equations (3.1) and (3.6) for all $i \in \mathcal{N}$ are satisfied.

Specifically, a commission-subscription pair $(\boldsymbol{\alpha},\boldsymbol{\beta})$ determines a participant population equilibrium. In the rest of this paper, when we refer to participant populations $ \boldsymbol{l}$ corresponding to $(\boldsymbol{\alpha},\boldsymbol{\beta})$ , we mean that $ \boldsymbol{l}$ is under the equilibrium state. Furthermore, if we refer to optimal participant populations, we mean $ \boldsymbol{l}$ is under the equilibrium state given optimal commissions and subscriptions $(\boldsymbol{\alpha}^{*},\boldsymbol{\beta}^{*})$ .

3.2. Risk-sharing rule and adverse selection

Before we construct the platform’s revenue-maximization problem, we first discuss the adverse selection problem and introduce a fair risk-sharing rule of the mutual aid plan under our proposed modeling framework.

The pricing technique of traditional insurance is largely based on the law of large numbers. If policyholders’ losses are independent and identically distributed, and the pool size of policyholders is sufficiently large, the average cost of insurance claims per policy is close to its theoretical expectation, leading to the net premium principle, which states that the expected premiums are equal to expected benefits. Most traditional insurance products are designed for covering homogeneous risks.

In contrast with conventional insurance, mutual aid plans allow participants’ risks to be heterogeneous. For instance, in Xianghubao, participants aged from 1 year old to 60 years old all participate in the same mutual aid plan, which significantly increases the participant population size of risk-sharing groups. The results of our analysis in Appendix A also show that a mutual aid plan allowing participants of various types to join has a lower variance in shared costs than that in a homogeneous risk-sharing group. This outcome supports the idea that the mutual aid platform should enroll all participants of different risk levels in the same mutual aid plan to lower shared costs. However, risk heterogeneity leads to adverse selection problems, which is the major problem that concerns most mutual aid platforms. According to the data from China Insurance Regulatory Commission (2006), a 20-year-old individual’s critical illness probability is 0.000340, while a 59-year-old individual’s probability is 0.016086, which is 47 times greater than the 20-year-old individual’s probability. If the platform set the same shared cost for all different participant types, participants with a higher risk level would benefit more than those with a lower risk level. For instance, if shared costs are the same for all participants, high-risk participants’ expected benefits are higher than their expected costs. Thus, participants with a high loss probability are more willing to join the mutual aid plan. This finding raises the expected total benefits of the plan. The low-risk participants must pay more than their expected benefits, so they will decide to opt out of the plan, raising the expected total benefits again; ultimately, only high-risk participants remain in the plan. Thus, it is important to consider the differences between participant types and to offer them different services and charge them different fees.

Recall that $w_{i}$ , $\forall i\in\mathcal{N}$ , is the weight factor of the shared cost $s_{i}$ of type-i participants. The platform can facilitate transfers between participants by assigning different weight factors to different types of participants. It is notable that the weight factors $w_{i}$ and benefits $I_{i}$ are exogenous variables in the revenue maximization problem and should be determined before finding optimal solutions. The values chosen for $w_{i}$ and $I_{i}$ determine how participants share their risks in the mutual aid platform. Thus, we investigate the risk exchange scheme by finding an appropriate $w_{i}$ or $I_{i}$ so that participants can share their risks fairly.

The actuarial fairness principle we consider in this paper is that the expected value of a participant’s income should be equal to the expected value of her outgo. Such fairness principle is also described by Abdikerimova and Feng Reference Abdikerimova and Feng(2022), who study the fairness issues in mutual aid platforms. This is also in line with the definition in Donnelly Reference Donnelly(2015): each member can expect to get back from the fund the same amount as what they have contributed or put at risk. On one hand, the income of a type-i participant in a mutual aid platform is the benefit he receives when he is critically ill. Thus, the expected value of income is $p_{i}I_{i}$ . On the other hand, the outgo of a participant is shared cost contributed to other participants. The expected value of outgo is $(1-p_{i})s_{i}$ . The fairness principle requires $p_{i}I_{i}=(1-p_{i})s_{i}$ . A mutual aid plan is actuarially fair if the equation $p_{i}I_{i}=(1-p_{i})s_{i}$ is satisfied. Therefore, in a risk exchange scheme in which participants share their risks fairly, the expected value of benefits that a participant receives should equal the expected value of costs under the equivalence principle:

(3.7) \begin{equation} p_{i}I_{i}=(1-p_{i})s_{i}=\frac{(1-p_{i})w_{i}\sum_{j\in\mathcal{N}} l_{j}p_{j}I_{j}}{\sum_{j\in\mathcal{N}} l_{j}(1-p_{j})w_{j}},\quad\forall i\in\mathcal{N}.\end{equation}

We say the platform chooses the fair risk exchange scheme if Equation (3.7) is satisfied. This terminology was first introduced into the mutual aid platform by Abdikerimova and Feng (Reference Abdikerimova and Feng2022). In our work, we use a simpler version, in which the expected shared cost $s_{i}$ only need to satisfy Equation (3.7), while Abdikerimova and Feng (Reference Abdikerimova and Feng2022) account for the minimum variance in the shared cost.

To have concise expressions for $w_{i}$ , let the sum of type $w_{i}$ be normalized to 1, that is, $\sum_{i\in\mathcal{N}}w_{i}=1$ , and from Equation (3.7), we have

(3.8) \begin{equation} w_{i}=\frac{p_{i}I_{i}/(1-p_{i})}{\sum_{j\in\mathcal{N}}p_{j}I_{j}/(1-p_{j})},\quad\forall i\in\mathcal{N}.\end{equation}

Equation (3.8) implies that, under the fair risk exchange scheme, the weight factor $w_{i}$ is independent of participant population $l_{i}$ , and it can be preset before the plan starts.

To understand the impact of adverse selection on the mutual aid platform, we elaborate on how participant populations change due to the effect of adverse selection. We consider two simple mutual aid plans in the rest of this subsection. (1) In the first mutual aid plan, participants’ shared costs are based on the fair risk exchange scheme. (2) In the second mutual aid plan, participants’ shared costs are the same. Suppose that there are only two participant types in these two mutual aid plans and $p_{1}\lt p_{2}$ , $m_{1}=m_{2}=1$ . Benefits, commission rates, and subscription fees are the same for these two participant types, that is, $I_{1}=I_{2}=I$ , $\alpha_{1}=\alpha_{2}=\alpha$ and $\beta_{1}=\beta_{2}=\beta$ . The value distributions of the two participant types are identical and uniformly distributed, that is, $F(v)=\frac{v}{\bar{v}}$ . Suppose that $(l_{1,1},l_{1,2})$ is the equilibrium participant population vector under the first plan. From Equations (3.1) and (3.8), we have

(3.9) \begin{equation} l_{1,1}=1-\frac{p_{1}I\alpha+\beta}{\bar{v}},\quad l_{1,2}=1-\frac{p_{2}I\alpha+\beta}{\bar{v}}.\end{equation}

Suppose that $(l_{2,1},l_{2,2})$ is the equilibrium population vector under the second plan. From Equation (3.1), we have

(3.10) \begin{equation}\begin{cases} l_{2,1}=\frac{-b_{1}+\sqrt{b_{1}^2-4a_{1}c_{1}}}{2a_{1}},\quad l_{2,2}=\frac{-b_{2}+\sqrt{b_{2}^2-4a_{2}c_{2}}}{2a_{3}}&,\quad(1-p_{2})s(1+\alpha)+\beta-p_{2}I\leq\bar{v},\\[1em] l_{2,1}=\frac{-b_{3}+\sqrt{b_{3}^2-4a_{3}c_{3}}}{2a_{3}},\quad l_{2,2}=1&, \quad\textrm{otherwise},\end{cases}\end{equation}

where the expressions of $a_{i}$ , $b_{i,}$ and $c_{i}$ for $i=1,2,3$ are listed in the Appendix. To compare the total participant populations of these two plans, we consider the following numerical example.

Example 1. Suppose that $I=100,000$ yuan, $\bar{v}=500$ , $\alpha=0.05$ , $\beta={12}$ , and $p_{1}=0.001$ in both plans. We vary the value of $p_{2}$ from 0.001 to 0.005 to determine how adverse selection affects the population in the plan. Figure 5 displays the populations of two participant types for two plans. In the left panel of Figure 5, we see that the population of type-1 participants does not change as $p_{2}$ increases because the loss probability of type-2 participants does not affect the type-1 participant population. The decreasing trend of the type-2 population occurs because, as the loss probability increases, type-2 participants must pay more commissions and hence lower the marginal value. In the right panel of Figure 5, observe that the population of type-2 participants increases and reaches 1 as $p_{2}$ increases. The higher that the loss probability is, the more benefits that type-2 participants obtain from the platform and type-1 participants. However, since the expected value of costs is higher than the expected value of benefits, some type-1 participants choose to opt out of the plan. The higher that the loss probability is, the fewer type-1 participants that want to join the plan. Figure 6 depicts the total population of the two plans. We can see that the total population of plan 1 is higher than that of plan 2. As $p_{2}$ increases, the total population of plan 1 tends to be flat, while the total population of plan 2 sharply decreases. This finding implies that risk heterogeneity does not affect the plan if the shared cost’s weight factor is set to satisfy fair risk exchange. In the plan in which participants share the costs equally, risk heterogeneity affects the total population of the plan and causes adverse selection problems.

Figure 5. Population of two participant types in plans.

Figure 6. Total participant population in plans.

From the discussion above, we know that the mutual aid plan can cause adverse selection problems because of risk heterogeneity. If the risk exchange is unfair, high-risk-level participants will benefit from the low-risk-level participants. This outcome will increase the population of high-risk-level participants and decrease the population of low-risk-level participants and hence increase the cost of each participant. To reduce the impact of adverse selection, fair risk exchange is introduced into the plan. Under the fair risk exchange scheme, each participant type has her own weight factor, and she needs only bear the costs that are related to her risk levels. Therefore, in the following sections, we assume that the platform adopts the fair risk exchange scheme when maximizing its revenue. The fees play an important role on adverse selection as well. If the fees are not fairly priced (e.g., charge the same fees to all participants), participants with lower values or lower loss probability will choose to opt out of the mutual aid plan while those with higher values of higher loss probability will join in the plan. We will also point out that charging different fees to different types of participants can increase platform’s revenues in succeeding sections.

3.3. Revenue maximization

In Subsection 3.2, we provided analytical results and examples to show that, when shared costs are the same for all participants, there is an adverse selection problem in the mutual aid platform, resulting in participant population loss and hence the platform’s revenue loss. Therefore, we assume that the platform adopts the fair risk exchange scheme and discuss the commission/subscription scheme under the fair risk exchange scheme. That is, we select $w_{i}$ to satisfy Equation (3.8) and allow the expected cost of a participant to equal her expected benefit. Then, the expected shared cost $s_{i}$ is given by $s_{i}=p_{i}I_{i}/(1-p_{i})$ , and the expression for Equation $ l_{i}$ can be rewritten as

(3.11) \begin{equation} l_{i}=m_{i}\big[1-F_{i}\big(\alpha_{i} p_{i}I_{i}+\beta_{i}\big)\big],\quad \forall i\in\mathcal{N}.\end{equation}

We assume that all participants and the platform have full information about the features of all of the participants and the platform. Therefore, no information asymmetry exists in our modeling framework. Thus, the participants’ and the platform’s behaviors are not affected by any information frictions. In practice, participants know all shared costs, which are released to public by the platform in each period. The shared cost reflects the information of each type of participants. As describe in Section 3.1, there are an equilibrium state of the mutual aid plan. Participant populations will eventually reach the equilibrium state where participant populations and share costs are stable. In our model, we consider the participant populations under the equilibrium state. Therefore, the information friction and the priori distribution are not incorporated in our model. Moreover, platforms such as Xianghubao have already adopted blockchain techniques in mutual aid plans. Claimants can submit their supporting documents on the blockchain, and investigation firms are able to obtain immediate access to this information. All of the participants in the platform can see the entire process, rendering the information in the plan more transparent and reducing information asymmetry.

The information disclosure mechanism in mutual aid platforms ensures that the platform cannot declare more claims. The detailed information of every approved claims is disclosed to public and other participants can check the eligibility of each claimant. For example, Xianghubao posts patients’ information including their names, ages, illness information reports, medical bills, investigation reports and other related documents. Participants can challenge patients’ eligibility if they find out some claimants do not meet the requirements. Therefore, the platform is supervised by all participants, and it is difficult for the platform to declare more claims. In conclusion, there is an incentive for the platform to declare more claims but the information disclosure mechanism makes the platform difficult to do that. It is a good point to consider that the loss probabilities are endogenous. However, as discussed above, it is difficult for the platform to declare more claims. Furthermore, since less claims lead to less commissions, there are no incentive for the platform to declare less claims. Thus, the loss probability will not either increase or decrease due to the platform’s behaviors. Therefore, we assume that the mutual aid platform’s behaviors do not affect participants’ probabilities in the model.

The platform chooses commission rates and subscription fees to maximize its revenue. Recall that, given commission rates and subscription fees, a participant population equilibrium can be determined. Thus, when the platform chooses commission rates and subscription fees, a participant population equilibrium is also chosen. The platform’s revenue maximization problem is given by

(3.12) \begin{align}\textrm{(P1)}\quad V_{opt}=\max_{(\boldsymbol{\alpha},\boldsymbol{\beta})} \quad &\sum_{i\in \mathcal{N}} \alpha_{i} l_{i}p_{i}I_{i}+\sum_{i\in \mathcal{N}}\beta_{i}l_{i},\end{align}
(3.13) \begin{align}\text{s.t.} \quad &l_{i}=m_{i}\big[1-F_{i}\big(\alpha_{i}p_{i}I_{i}+\beta_{i}\big)\big],&\quad\forall i\in\mathcal{N},\end{align}
(3.14) \begin{align}& \alpha_{i}\geq 0,&\forall i\in\mathcal{N},\end{align}
(3.15) \begin{align}& \beta_{i} \geq0,&\forall i\in\mathcal{N}.\end{align}

In problem (P1), $\boldsymbol{\alpha}$ and $\boldsymbol{\beta}$ are regarded as decision variables, and $ \boldsymbol{l}=(l_{1},\ldots, l_{n})$ can be derived when $(\boldsymbol{\alpha},\boldsymbol{\beta})$ is determined. The first term in the objective function (3.12) is the revenue from commissions, and the second term is the revenue from subscription fees. Constraint (3.13) comes from Equation (3.1), which means that $\boldsymbol{l}$ is an equilibrium participant population vector corresponding to the optimal solution $(\boldsymbol{\alpha},\boldsymbol{\beta})$ . Constraints (3.14) and (3.15) ensure that the solution $(\boldsymbol{\alpha},\boldsymbol{\beta})$ is a feasible commission-subscription vector.

4. Optimal solution

In this section, we first find the optimal solutions to problem (P1). Then, we consider a special commission/subscription scheme, under which commission rates and subscription fees are the same for different participant types. We find the optimal solutions to a revised problem.

4.1. A general case

In this subsection, we find the optimal commission rates and subscription fees for problem (P1) and the corresponding population. The optimal solutions can be analytically derived by implementing the Karush–Kuhn–Tucker (KKT) condition. Therefore, we have the following theorem.

Theorem 1. Suppose that $(\boldsymbol{\alpha}^{*},\boldsymbol{\beta}^{*})$ is the optimal solution to problem (P1), and $\boldsymbol{l}^{*}$ is the corresponding equilibrium population given $(\boldsymbol{\alpha}^{*},\boldsymbol{\beta}^{*})$ . Under the fair risk exchange scheme, the optimal commission-subscription vector $(\boldsymbol{\alpha}^{*},\boldsymbol{\beta}^{*})$ for problem (P1) is not unique, and the relation is given by

(4.1) \begin{equation} \alpha_{i}^{*}p_{i}I_{i}+\beta_{i}^{*}=F^{-1}_{i}\left(1-\frac{ l_{i}^{*}}{m_{i}}\right),\quad\forall i \in \mathcal{N},\end{equation}

where $ \boldsymbol{l}^{*}$ is determined by solving the following equation:

(4.2) \begin{equation} F^{-1}_{i}\left(1-\frac{l_{i}^{*}}{m_{i}}\right)+ l_{i}^{*}\frac{\textrm{d}F^{-1}_{i}\left(1-\frac{ l^{*}_{i}}{m_{i}}\right)}{\textrm{d} l_{i}^{*}}=0,\quad\forall i \in \mathcal{N}.\end{equation}

The platform’s maximum revenue is

(4.3) \begin{equation} V_{opt}=\sum_{i\in \mathcal{N}}l_{i}^{*}F_{i}^{-1}\left(1-\frac{ l_{i}^{*}}{m_{i}}\right).\end{equation}

From Theorem 1, we know that the optimal commission rate and subscription fee for each participant type depend on their own characteristics, such as loss probabilities, benefits, and value distributions. Thus, to obtain the maximum revenue, the platform treats participants differently with respect to their types. Note further that, although $\boldsymbol{l}$ depends on $(\boldsymbol{\alpha},\boldsymbol{\beta})$ , Equation (4.2) implies that the optimal equilibrium participant population vector $\boldsymbol{l}^{*}$ is independent of optimal solution $(\boldsymbol{\alpha}^{*},\boldsymbol{\beta}^{*})$ and only depends on its own population size and value distribution. Platforms can first determine the participant populations of each participant type using Equation (4.2) and target the optimal participant population by choosing appropriate commission rates and subscription fees according to Equation (4.1). Furthermore, a platform’s maximum revenue depends on the total potential participant population size of each participant type and their value distribution. This outcome implies that the maximum revenue is determined by participant type features and that the optimal participating population size is achieved by setting optimal commission rates and subscription fees.

We see that the optimal commission/subscription scheme is not unique. However, a platform might prefer a less complicated method to charge participants fees. Hence, the platform can charge only commissions or subscriptions to achieve the maximum revenue. It is straightforward to have the following results from Theorem 1.

Proposition 3. A simpler case of the optimal solution to problem (P1) can be obtained as follows:

  • Setting $\beta_{i}^{*}=0$ yields

    (4.4) \begin{equation} \alpha^{*}_{i}=\frac{F_{i}^{-1}\left(1-\frac{ l_{i}^{*}}{m_{i}}\right)}{p_{i}I_{i}},\quad\forall i\in\mathcal{N};\end{equation}
  • Setting $\alpha_{i}^{*}=0$ yields

    (4.5) \begin{equation} \beta^{*}_{i}=F_{i}^{-1}\left(1-\frac{ l_{i}^{*}}{m_{i}}\right),\quad\forall i\in\mathcal{N},\end{equation}
    where $ l_{i}^{*}$ is given by Equation (4.2).

In Proposition 3, $\beta_{i}^{*}=0$ means that the platform only charges participants via commission rates. Some platforms, such as Xianghubao and Kangai Gongshe, employ this method. The subscription fee is waived in this method; hence, participants do not pay any upfront fee to participate in the plan. $\alpha_{i}^{*}=0$ corresponds to the situation in which the platform only charges participants via subscription fees. This method is implemented by platforms such as Waterdrop Mutual Aid and Qingsong Mutual Aid. In this method, the fees paid to the platform are fixed, and participants need not vary fees. Therefore, the platform does not need to consider a complex method to charge both commissions and subscription fees.

Next, we study the relationship between optimal solutions and exogenous variables $p_{i}$ and $I_{i}$ . We obtain the following results.

Corollary 1. The relationships between optimal solutions $\alpha_{i}^{*}$ and $\beta_{i}^{*}$ and $p_{i}$ and $I_{i}$ are given by the following.

  1. 1. If the platform only charges commissions, $\alpha_{i}^{*}$ is decreasing in $p_{i}$ and $I_{i}$ ;

  2. 2. If the platform only charges subscriptions, $\beta_{i}^{*}$ is independent of $p_{i}$ and $I_{i}$ ; and

  3. 3. If the platform charge both commissions and subscriptions, both $\alpha_{i}^{*}$ and $\beta_{i}^{*}$ are decreasing in $p_{i}$ and $I_{i}$ .

Corollary 1 explains the differences between $\alpha_{i}^{*}$ and $\beta_{i}^{*}$ . When charging only one type of fee, the optimal commission rate depends on the loss probability and benefit, while the optimal subscription rate is independent of them. This finding provides two different ways for the platform to charge fees to participants. These two methods each have advantages and disadvantages. Subscription fees are charged at time $t=0$ , and the total value is fixed, while commissions are charged at time $t=1$ , and they are based on the loss probability and benefit. Also note that the interest rate is not incorporated into our framework. Participants might prefer commissions if the interest rate is considered because they need not make any upfront payments.

We consider a special case of problem (P1) in which we are able to obtain explicit expressions for $ \boldsymbol{l}$ and $\boldsymbol{\alpha}$ , as well as $\boldsymbol{\beta}$ . We assume there are only two types of participants in the plan, that is, $\mathcal{N}=\{1,2\}$ , and the value distributions follow the uniform distribution. The uniform distribution assumption for a continuum of individuals has been widely used in economic literature. For example, Belleflamme et al. (Reference Belleflamme, Lambert and Schwienbacher2014) consider a unit mass of individuals and assume their marginal utilities are uniformly distributed. These assumptions facilitate the calculations but still maintain the main features of mutual aid plans. Then, we have the following corollary.

Corollary 2. Suppose there are only two types of participants in the plan, and their value distributions follow the uniform distribution, that is, $\displaystyle F_{i}(v)=v/\bar{v}_{i}$ for $i=1,2$ , where $\bar{v}_{i}$ is the maximum value of type-i participants. Then, we have analytically optimal solutions to problem (P1). The optimal solution is given by the following.

  • If the platform only charges subscription fees, then

    \begin{equation*} \alpha^{*}_{i}=\frac{\bar{v}_{i}}{2p_{i}I_{i}},\quad\beta^{*}_{i}=0,\quad \textrm{for }i=1,2.\end{equation*}
  • If the platform only charges commissions, then

    \begin{equation*} \alpha^{*}_{i}=0,\quad\beta^{*}_{i}=\frac{\bar{v}_{i}}{2},\quad \textrm{for } i=1,2.\end{equation*}

The optimal participant population $ l^{*}_{i}$ is given by

\begin{equation*} l^{*}_{i}=\frac{m_{i}}{2},\quad \textit{for } i=1,2.\end{equation*}

The corresponding maximum revenue is

\begin{equation*} V_{opt}=\frac{m_{1}\bar{v}_{1}}{4}+\frac{m_{2}\bar{v}_{2}}{4}.\end{equation*}

Under the uniform distribution, commission rates and subscription fees are considerably easier to compute. Optimal commission rates and subscription fees depend on the maximum values $\bar{v}_{i}$ . The optimal participant population depends on the total potential participant populations $m_{i}$ and maximum values $\bar{v}_{i}$ . The platform’s revenue is determined by $m_{i}$ and $\bar{v}_{i}$ .

In this subsection, we know that maximizing the platform’s revenue by choosing subscription fees and commission rates is essentially achieved by choosing the optimal population of participants. The optimal solution is found by first finding the optimal population. Commission rates and subscription fees are determined through this optimal population. However, note further that the optimal revenue is achieved only if commission rates and subscription fees are allowed to differ for different participant types. If commission rates and subscription fees are the same for all participant types, as observed in many mutual aid platforms, the platform’s optimal revenue in problem (P1) might not be achieved. This situation is discussed in the next subsection.

4.2. Same commissions and subscriptions

Note that the optimal commission/subscription scheme in problem (P1) typically requires treating participant types differently in terms of their commissions and subscription fees. However, in practice, many mutual aid platforms still charge the same commissions and subscriptions to all participants. That is, platforms charge the same commissions and subscriptions to all participants. Thus, we have $\alpha_{1}=\alpha_{2}\ldots=\alpha_{n}=\alpha$ and $\beta_{1}=\beta_{2}\ldots=\beta_{n}=\beta$ . Then, the platform’s revenue is revised to $\alpha\sum_{i\in \mathcal{N}} l_{i}p_{i}I_{i}+\beta\sum_{i\in \mathcal{N}}l_{i}$ . Charging the same commissions and subscriptions makes it easier for the platform to manage the mutual aid plan and easier for participants to understand. Constraint (3.13) can be rewritten as

(4.6) \begin{equation} l_{i}=m_{i}\left[1-F_{i}(\alpha p_{i}I_{i}+\beta)\right].\end{equation}

Therefore, the optimization problem (P1) can be redefined as

(4.7) \begin{align}\textrm{(P2)}\quad V_{opt}=\max_{(\alpha,\beta)} \quad &\alpha\sum_{i\in \mathcal{N}} l_{i}p_{i}I_{i}+\beta\sum_{i\in \mathcal{N}} l_{i},\end{align}
(4.8) \begin{align}\text{s.t.} \quad & l_{i}=m_{i}\left[1-F_{i}(\alpha p_{i}I_{i}+\beta)\right],\quad &\forall i\in\mathcal{N},\end{align}
(4.9) \begin{align}& \alpha\geq 0,\end{align}
(4.10) \begin{align}& \beta \geq 0.\end{align}

The optimal solution to problem (P1) no longer applies in problem (P2). It is not possible to obtain an explicit solution to problem (P2) because of the restrictions $\alpha_{1}=\alpha_{2}\ldots=\alpha_{n}=\alpha$ and $\beta_{1}=\beta_{2}\ldots=$ $\beta_{n}=\beta$ . More specifically, in the constraint $l_{i}=m_{i}\left[1-F_{i}(\alpha p_{i}I_{i}+\beta)\right]$ in problem (P2), $F_{i}$ contains the same $\alpha$ and $\beta$ for all i. Unlike problem (P1), the n constraints are dependent and the optimal solution $\alpha$ and $\beta$ are related to all $l_{i}$ , for $i\in \mathcal{N}$ . We need to solve out a system of nonlinear equations. It is not possible to solve $\alpha$ and $\beta$ as well as $l_{i}$ analytically if the distribution $F_{i}$ is not given. Thus, an explicit expression for the optimal solution to problem (P2) is not attainable. An approximately optimal commission and subscription can be obtained numerically by defining a grid over the two decision variables $(\alpha,\beta)$ , computing participant populations using constraint (4.8) for each tuple of $(\alpha,\beta)$ and calculating corresponding platform revenues. Despite not being able to obtain an explicit solution, it is straightforward to have the following proposition from problem (P2).

Proposition 4. Suppose that $V_{opt}^{(1)}$ is the maximum revenue in problem (P1) and $V_{opt}^{(2)}$ is the maximum revenue in problem (P1); then, $V_{opt}^{(1)}\geq V_{opt}^{(2)}$ .

The implication of Proposition 4 is intuitive. The feasible set of $\boldsymbol{\alpha}$ and $\boldsymbol{\beta}$ in problem (P2) is a subset of $\boldsymbol{\alpha}$ and $\boldsymbol{\beta}$ in problem (P1). Therefore, the maximum platform revenues in problem (P1) are higher than those in problem (P2). Thus, charging the same commissions/subscriptions is only suboptimal and leads to lower revenues than those under the payment scheme in which the platform charge different commissions/subscriptions.

To illustrate the differences between problems (P1) and (P2), we consider a special case for problem (P2). Suppose that there are two participant types, and their value distributions are uniform distributions. Let $\mathcal{N}=\{1,2\}$ , $F_{1}(v_{1})=v_{1}/\bar{v}_{1}$ and $F_{2}(v_{2})=v_{2}/\bar{v}_{2}$ . Then, we have optimal solutions to problem (P2), the corresponding participant populations and platform revenues. as described in Theorem 2.

Theorem 2. Suppose that a mutual aid plan consists of two participant types, that is, $\mathcal{N}=\{1,2\}$ . Further, we assume that the value distribution is a uniform distribution. Specifically, $F_{1}(v_{1})=v_{1}/\bar{v}_{1}$ and $F_{2}(v_{2})=v_{2}/\bar{v}_{2}$ .

  1. 1. The optimal solution to optimization problem (P2) is given by

    • If $(\bar{v}_{1}-\bar{v}_{2})(p_{1}I_{1}-p_{2}I_{2})\gt 0$ and $(p_{1}I_{1}/\bar{v}_{1}-p_{2}I_{2}/\bar{v}_{2})(p_{1}I_{1}-p_{2}I_{2})\gt 0$ ,

      (4.11) \begin{equation} \alpha^{*}=\frac{1}{2}\frac{\bar{v}_{1}-\bar{v}_{2}}{p_{1}I_{1}-p_{2}I_{2}},\quad \beta^{*}=\frac{1}{2}\frac{p_{1}I_{1}\bar{v}_{2}-p_{2}I_{2}\bar{v}_{1}}{p_{1}I_{1}-p_{2}I_{2}};\end{equation}
    • If $(\bar{v}_{1}-\bar{v}_{2})(p_{1}I_{1}-p_{2}I_{2})\leq 0$ or $(p_{1}I_{1}/\bar{v}_{1}-p_{2}I_{2}/\bar{v}_{2})(p_{1}I_{1}-p_{2}I_{2})\leq 0$ ( $p_{1}I_{1}\neq p_{2}I_{2}$ ),

      (4.12) \begin{equation} \alpha^{*}=0,\quad \beta^{*}=\frac{\bar{v}_{1}\bar{v}_{2}}{2}\frac{m_{1}+m_{2}}{m_{1}\bar{v}_{2}+m_{2}\bar{v}_{1}}; \end{equation}
    • If $p_{1}I_{1}=p_{2}I_{2}$ ,

      (4.13) \begin{equation} \alpha^{*}p_{1}I_{1}+\beta^{*}=\frac{\bar{v}_{1}\bar{v}_{2}}{2}\frac{m_{1}+m_{2}}{m_{1}\bar{v}_{2}+m_{2}\bar{v}_{1}}. \end{equation}

  2. 2. Given the optimal solution $(\alpha^{*},\beta^{*})$ , the corresponding participant population is given by

    • If $(\bar{v}_{1}-\bar{v}_{2})(p_{1}I_{1}-p_{2}I_{2})\gt 0$ and $(p_{1}I_{1}/\bar{v}_{1}-p_{2}I_{2}/\bar{v}_{2})(p_{1}I_{1}-p_{2}I_{2})\gt 0$ ,

      (4.14) \begin{equation} l^{*}_{1}=\frac{m_{1}}{2},\quad l^{*}_{2}=\frac{m_{2}}{2};\end{equation}
    • Otherwise,

      (4.15) \begin{equation} l^{*}_{1}=\frac{m_{1}}{2}\left(1+\frac{m_{2}(\bar{v}_{1}-\bar{v}_{2})}{m_{1}\bar{v}_{2}+m_{2}\bar{v}_{1}}\right),\quad l^{*}_{2}=\frac{m_{2}}{2}\left(1+\frac{m_{1}(\bar{v}_{2}-\bar{v}_{1})}{m_{1}\bar{v}_{2}+m_{2}\bar{v}_{1}}\right). \end{equation}

  3. 3. Given the optimal solution $(\alpha^{*},\beta^{*})$ , the corresponding platform revenue is given by

    • If $(\bar{v}_{1}-\bar{v}_{2})(p_{1}I_{1}-p_{2}I_{2})\gt 0$ and $(p_{1}I_{1}/\bar{v}_{1}-p_{2}I_{2}/\bar{v}_{2})(p_{1}I_{1}-p_{2}I_{2})\gt 0$ ,

      \begin{equation*} V_{opt,1}=\frac{m_{1}\bar{v}_{1}}{4}+\frac{m_{2}\bar{v}_{2}}{4};\end{equation*}
    • Otherwise,

      \begin{equation*} V_{opt,2}=\frac{\bar{v}_{1}\bar{v}_{2}}{4}\frac{(m_{1}+m_{2})^2}{m_{1}\bar{v}_{2}+m_{2}\bar{v}_{1}}. \end{equation*}

We have $V_{opt,1}\geq V_{opt,2}$ .

Recall that $p_{i}I_{i}$ is the expected benefit of type-i participants. The condition $(\bar{v}_{1}-\bar{v}_{2})(p_{1}I_{1}-p_{2}I_{2})\gt 0$ in case 1 in the first part of Theorem 2 implies that (1) $\bar{v}_{1}\lt \bar{v}_{2}$ and $p_{1}I_{1}\gt p_{2}I_{2}$ or (2) $\bar{v}_{1}\lt \bar{v}_{2}$ and $p_{1}I_{1}\lt p_{2}I_{2}$ . Thus, the optimal solution in case 1 is under the condition that participant types with higher values have higher expected benefits. If the participant type with a higher value has a lower expected benefit (e.g., case 2 of the first part of Theorem 2), the optimal $\alpha$ and $\beta$ are negative, and the optimal solution in case 1 does not apply. Thus, optimal subscription fee and commission rate are different under different conditions. From Theorem 2, we observe that charging the same fees has less capacity to control the participant population because, unlike heterogeneous fees, the platform cannot target the population of a specific participant type. Furthermore, unlike heterogeneous fees, the optimal commission-subscription solution to problem (P2) is unique in some cases. Thus, there are fewer choices for the platform to design the mutual aid plan.

The second part of Theorem 2 implies that the optimal participant population varies under different cases. The optimal participant population is the same as that in problem (P1) in case 1, while it is different in case 2. The participant population of the participant type with higher maximum value in case 2 is larger than the participant population in case 1. Furthermore, note that the sum of total participant populations are the same in the two cases, that is, $ l^{*}_{1}+ l^{*}_{2}=\frac{m_{1}+m_{2}}{2}$ . Although the total participant populations under different conditions are the same, the corresponding platform revenues are different. We can see that the maximum revenues are different under different cases from the third part of Theorem 2. It shows that charging the same fees does not always achieve the best maximum revenue. By comparing Corollary 2 and Theorem 2, we find that the maximum revenues in the second case of the third part of Theorem 2 are less than those in Corollary 2 because the feasible region of $\alpha_{i}$ and $\beta_{i}$ in problem (P2) is smaller than that in problem (P1). In problem (P2), $\alpha_{i}$ and $\beta_{i}$ are restricted to $\alpha_{1}=\alpha_{2}\ldots=\alpha_{n}=\alpha$ and $\beta_{1}=\beta_{2}\ldots=\beta_{n}=\beta$ . Furthermore, the platform cannot target the optimal participant populations of all participant types when charging the same fees. Therefore, charging the same fees might only have suboptimal solutions and result in revenue losses. However, mutual aid platforms are still charging the same fees to all participants. A simple payment scheme in which the platform charges the same fees is easier for participants to understand and for platforms to implement. Platforms must balance complexity and profitability when designing mutual aid plans.

5. Numerical illustration

In this section, we use Xianghubao as an example to illustrate the implementation of our proposed model. Xianghubao is operated by Ant Financial, which is a financial services company of the internet giant Alibaba. The rise of Xianghubao has been remarkable in the mutual aid market. Xianghubao was introduced in October 2018 and had gained 10 million users by the ninth day after its introduction. As shown in Figure 7, more than 100 million people had participated in the plan by 2020, and it has become the largest mutual aid platform in the market. We implement the model proposed in our paper to analyze the optimal commission/subscription scheme for Xianghubao.

Figure 7. Number of participants in Xianghubao (in millions).

Xianghubao only charges commissions, which are also known as administrative fees, and it requires no upfront payment. Any Alipay user is qualified to join the plan for free if she meets basic health requirements, and her Zhima Credit Score, which is a credit system designed by Ant Financial, is 600 or greater. Alipay is a third-party payment platform established by Alibaba and has been the world’s largest mobile payment platform since 2013. After claims are filed and confirmed at the end of the mutual plan, all of the participants evenly share the costs of claim benefits. Alipay automatically deducts the amount from participants’ accounts. Participants in the mutual aid plan provided by Xianghubao are characterized as two types. The first type consists of participants aged younger than 39 years old, and the second type consists of participants aged between 40 and 59 years. Xianghubao charges the same commission rates to all participant types. Furthermore, the shared costs are the same for all participants in Xianghubao. The benefit amount is 300,000 yuan for the first type of participant and 100,000 yuan for the second type of participant. The current design of commission/subscription schemes does not consider the diversity of participants in the plan. Thus, we use the model proposed in this paper to revise the current mutual aid design of Xianghubao.

We assume that all Alipay users are potential users of Xianghubao. Alipay has a 54.5% share of the third-party payment market in mainland China. Therefore, it is reasonable to use the total population share of internet users in China as the total potential participant population share in the model, that is, $m_{i}$ . The data on the internet user population can be found at China Internet Network Information Center (2019). Similarly, we use the data from China Insurance Regulatory Commission (2006) as the critical illness probability. People are characterized into 7 different types by age. We use the mean values of the critical illness probabilities of people of the same type to represent the critical illness probability of this type. Table 2 displays the critical illness probability and total population share of internet users for different age groups.

Table 2. Critical illness probability and total internet user population share

From the table, we find that the differences in critical illness probabilities between age groups are large. Therefore, it is better to divide participants into more than 2 types. Note that Xianghubao only allows participants younger than 60 to participate in the plan. Thus, we divide participants into 5 types accordingly. The total potential participant population is normalized to 1. For instance, the population of potential participants younger than 19 is $m_{1}=\frac{23.2}{23.2+21.5+20.8+17.6+10.2}=0.2487$ . We keep the benefit amount the same as in the current plan provided by Xianghubao. The weight factor is calculated using Equation (3.8). Table 3 summarizes the parameter values used in the model.

Table 3. Critical illness probability and total internet user population share

Table 4. Current mutual aid plan design ( $\alpha=0.08$ ) if the value distribution is $F_{i}(x)=\frac{x}{\bar{v}_{i}}$

We use the current mutual aid plan offered by Xianghubao as a benchmark. As illustrated above, Xianghubao charges an 8% commission rate to all participants. We assume that all participant types’ value distributions follow the uniform distribution $F_{i}(x)=\frac{x}{\bar{v}_{i}}$ but have various values of $\bar{v}_{i}$ . The parameter value $\bar{v}_{i}$ of the distribution can be estimated using a questionnaire survey. The questionnaire method has been used widely for determining individual’s risk preference. For example, a simple hypothetical gambling with 50% chance of gaining 1000 and 50% chance of loss X is adopted by Handel et al. (Reference Handel, Hendel and Whinston2015) and Breer and Novikov (Reference Breer and Novikov2015). X can be used to determine the risk preference. In our manuscript, we can determine participant’s value v in a similar way. More specifically, participants can choose a maximum payment X they are willing to afford in a mutual aid platform. Then X can be used to determine v. Three scenarios are considered here: (1) $\bar{v}_{i}=10$ for $i=1,2,3$ and $\bar{v}_{i}=15$ for $i=4,5$ ; (2) $\bar{v}_{i}=50$ for $i=1,2,3$ and $\bar{v}_{i}=75$ for $i=4,5$ ; and (3) $\bar{v}_{i}=100$ for $i=1,2,3$ and $\bar{v}_{i}=150$ for $i=4,5$ . The results are shown in Table 4. $ \boldsymbol{l}$ is calculated by solving a system of nonlinear equations comprising of Equation (3.1) for different participant types. We can see that, when $\bar{v}_{i}$ is small, participants with a high loss probability do not join the plan because the commission rate is too high for them. When $\bar{v}_{i}$ increases, participants with a high loss probability are able to tolerate the commission rate and participate in the plan. As a result, participants with a low loss probability choose to opt out of the plan because of adverse selection problems. Note that the results in Table 4 are different from those in reality. There are several reasons for this outcome. First, there are waiting periods in mutual aid plans. During the waiting periods, participants must bear the costs of claim benefits but cannot apply for benefits. Therefore, there are more participants to share the cost; hence, the actual shared cost is lower than expected. Second, some claimants’ applications might be rejected because of strict regulations, lowering the loss probability and hence lower the shared cost. Third, the population share of younger people in platforms is much larger than that on the entire internet. Thus, the actual shared cost is lower than our results. However, as participants in platforms grow older and more older people join the platforms, the population share of older people will increase, and the shared cost will be higher than the current one.

We next consider the case in which the fair risk exchange scheme is adopted, while the platform still charges the same fees to all participants. We assume the platform only charges commissions or subscription fees. To compare platform revenues between same commissions/subscriptions schemes and different commissions/subscriptions schemes, we assume different types of participants have different value distributions. We choose the same parameter values as those in scenario (1) in the current mutual aid plan example. The value distribution for participants of types 1, 2, and 3 is $F_{i}(x)=\frac{x}{10}$ , while the value distribution for participants of types 4 and 5 is $F_{i}(x)=\frac{x}{15}$ . By solving optimization problem (P2) numerically by restricting $\beta=0$ , we have the optimal commission rate $\alpha^{*}=0.0186$ when only charging commissions. Similarly, we can have $\beta^{*}=5.6$ when only charging subscriptions. The results are displayed in Table 5. Note that both schemes have improvements in the total revenue compared to current mutual aid plan (0.6034). We further find that only charging commission results in a larger population of low-risk participants and smaller population of high-risk participants. Same commission rates under the fair risk exchange scheme lead to a higher commission for high-risk participants; thereby, fewer high-risk participants choose to participate in the plan. Therefore, the participant populations cannot reach the optimal ones. As a result, the total revenue of the only commission scheme is lower than that of the only subscription scheme.

Table 5. Optimal mutual aid plan design if charging the same commission/subscription ( $F_{i}(x)=\frac{x}{\bar{v}_{i}}$ )

Next, we propose a more sophisticated design of the commission/subscription scheme for mutual aid plans. The platform adopts the fair risk exchange scheme and charges different fees to different types of participants as illustrated in problem (P1). We use the parameter values in scenario (1) as described above. Additionally, to compare the results between different value distributions, we also adopt exponential distributions $F_{i}(x)=1-e^{-x/\kappa_{i}}$ for the value distribution here. $\kappa_{i}$ is the parameter value of type-i participants’ value distribution. The exponential distribution is used by Birge et al. (Reference Birge, Candogan, Chen and Saban2021) to describe the value of hosts. Here, we assume that $\kappa_{i}=5$ for $i=1,2,3$ and $\kappa_{i}=7.5$ for $i=4,5$ . The optimal mutual aid plan under the uniform distribution is shown in Table 6. According to Theorem 1, the optimal solution is not unique. We consider two special cases: only commission and only subscription. The second column corresponds to the optimal solution, in which only a commission is applied, and the third column corresponds to the optimal solution, in which only a subscription fee is applied. The corresponding optimal participant populations, shared costs, and revenues are listed in the fourth, fifth, and sixth column, respectively. The optimal mutual aid plan under the exponential distribution is shown in Table 7.

Table 6. Optimal mutual aid plan design ( $F_{i}(x)=\frac{x}{\bar{v}_{i}}$ )

Table 7. Optimal mutual aid plan design ( $F_{i}(x)=1-e^{x/\kappa_{i}}$ )

By comparing the results in Tables 4 and 6, we see that the platform’s total revenue under the optimal commission/subscription scheme (2.8725) is 475% greater than that under the current mutual aid design (0.6043). Thus, charging different commissions/subscriptions can significantly improve the platform’s revenues. Additionally, by comparing Tables 5 and 6, we observe that the total revenue of charging different fees is greater than that of charging the same commissions (1.9566) or subscriptions (2.7755). This finding means that using both the optimal commission/subscription scheme and the fair risk exchange scheme is better than only using the fair risk exchange scheme in mitigating the impact of risk heterogeneity. Thus, only using the fair risk exchange scheme, which has been adopted by some platforms, is not sufficient to reach the platform’s maximum revenue. Along with the fair risk exchange scheme, charging different commissions and subscriptions to different types of participants can target the optimal participant population and maximize the platform’s revenue.

From the results in Tables 6 and 7, we find that the participant populations under the exponential distribution are lower than those under the uniform distribution. The reason is that the exponential distribution is right skewed; hence, there are fewer participants with lower values. Note further that, subscription fees and commission rates as well as the shared costs under the exponential distribution are the same as those under the uniform distribution. Although maximum revenues are different, the optimal strategy for commissions and subscriptions may not be affected by the choice of $F_{i}$ . We can also note that the commissions and subscriptions are based on the expectation of distributions in our cases. This also implies that optimal solutions are less affected by the choice of distributions.

In order to further investigate the effect to $F_{i}$ on the maximum revenue, we calculate the maximum revenue by varying values of parameters in $F_{i}$ . More specifically, we change values of $\bar{v}_{1}$ and $\bar{v}_{4}$ when $F_{i}(x)=\frac{x}{\bar{v}_{i}}$ and values of $\kappa_{1}$ and $\kappa_{4}$ $F_{i}(x)=1-e^{x/\kappa_{i}}$ in the example we discuss above. Numerical results are depicted in Figure 8. Note that parameters $\bar{v}$ and $\kappa$ can be regarded as the maximum value and the average value of participants, respectively. From the plot, we can see that the maximum revenue is increasing in the maximum value or the average value. This suggests that the platform can get higher profits if participants have higher value on the platform. Furthermore, the changing percentages of the maximum revenue with respect to the four parameter values are 61%, 30%, 61%, and 30%, respectively. This means parameter values of $F_{i}$ have a strong influence on the maximum revenue. Thus, the parameter estimation of $F_{i}$ is important for determining the maximum revenue. Therefore, optimal solutions and the corresponding maximum revenues depend on distribution parameters.

Figure 8. Maximum revenue against parameter values in $F_{i}$ .

In this section, we provide new commission/subscription schemes for Xianghubao according to the results of our proposed model. Compared to the current commission/subscription scheme, the new schemes divide participants into more than two types because we consider the importance of risk heterogeneity in the mutual aid plan. The expected shared cost $s_{i}$ varies across different types and relates to the risk level of the participant type, which is different from the current scheme, in which participants make equal payments. Furthermore, participants pay different fees based on their types under the new scheme, also reducing the effect of risk heterogeneity and increasing platform revenue. Therefore, although the new scheme is much more complicated than the current scheme, the new scheme has many advantages over the current scheme.

6. Conclusion

In this paper, we propose a modeling framework to describe the commission/subscription scheme of mutual aid platforms. Participants are divided into different types with respect to their loss probability and value distribution. Participants of the same type are heterogeneous in terms of their valuations of the plan. Participants’ decisions about whether to participate in the plan depend on their profits. The platform facilitates risk exchanges between participants and charges commissions and subscriptions to participants. The shared costs used to pay benefits to claimants are borne by all of the participants and are determined endogenously. We construct an optimization problem on how to charge commissions and subscriptions to maximize the platform’s revenues. There are three key takeaways that we conclude from our analysis results.

  • We show that, in general, the platform obtains its maximum revenue by choosing different commission rates/subscription fees for different participant types depending on their total populations and value distributions. Furthermore, charging the same commissions can result in revenue loss. These results emphasize the importance of accounting for risk heterogeneity when designing the commission/subscription scheme in a mutual aid platform.

  • Our results show that increasing the population of higher risk participants will raise the shared costs of all participants, and increasing the population of lower risk participants will decrease the shared costs. Changing the proportions of participant types in the plan leads to different shared costs. Moreover, the participant population is affected by commission rates and subscription fees; hence, the platform can control the participant population by setting appropriate commission rates and subscription fees. The optimal commission rates and subscription fees are affected by participants’ loss probabilities and value distributions, while the corresponding optimal participant populations depend on participants’ total potential participant populations and value distributions.

  • Adverse selection has a strong influence on mutual aid plans. Risky participants benefit from less-risky participants if participants pay the same shared costs. A fair risk-sharing rule, which is called the fair risk exchange scheme, was developed to avoid adverse selection problems. Our example results show that fair risk exchange can effectively decrease the influence of adverse selection.

We shed light on how commissions and subscriptions should be set in mutual aid plans. Our proposed modeling framework and numerical results provide mutual aid platforms, insurance companies, and other online platforms with guidelines on how to establish a commission/subscription scheme, as well as a fair risk-sharing rule for a risk-sharing platform. Our results also underscore the importance of accounting for the risk differences between participant types, while many mutual aid platforms do not place notable emphasis on such considerations.

Since we are interested in the optimal design of mutual aid plans in terms of how to charge fees, we neglect other important issues that affect mutual aid plans, such as transaction costs, information friction, default risk, and other externalities. Externalities of individual activities that are not internalized in our proposed model can lead to different results. Furthermore, we focus on a monopolistic mutual aid platform. The optimal design in our model is restricted to the maximum revenue of a monopolistic mutual aid platform. We could extend our model in several ways in the future.

Acknowledgments

This paper was supported by the Major Program of the National Social Science Foundation of China (No. 21&ZD113), the China Postdoctoral Science Foundation (No. 2020M672913), and the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Nos. 71721001 and 71771220), The Excellent Young Team Project Natural Science Foundation of Guangdong Province of China (No. 2023B1515040001), Philosophy and Social Science Programming Foundation of Guangdong Province (No. GD22CYJ17), and the Nature Science Foundation of Guangdong Province of China (No. 2022A1515011472).

Supplementary Material

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/asb.2023.21.

References

Abdikerimova, S. and Feng, R. (2022) Peer-to-peer multi-risk insurance and mutual aid. European Journal of Operational Research, 299(2), 735749.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belleflamme, P., Lambert, T. and Schwienbacher, A. (2014) Crowdfunding: Tapping the right crowd. Journal of Business Venturing, 29(5), 585609.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bellos, I., Ferguson, M. and Toktay, L.B. (2017) The car sharing economy: Interaction of business model choice and product line design. Manufacturing and Service Operations Management, 19(2), 185201.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benjaafar, S., Kong, G., Li, X. and Courcoubetis, C. (2019) Peer-to-peer product sharing: Implications for ownership, usage, and social welfare in the sharing economy. Management Science, 65(2), 477493.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bimpikis, K., Candogan, O. and Saban, D. (2017) Spatial pricing in ride-sharing networks. Operations Research, 67(3), 744769.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Birge, J., Candogan, O., Chen, H. and Saban, D. (2021) Optimal commissions and subscriptions in networked markets. Manufacturing and Service Operations Management, 23(3), 547730.Google Scholar
Boyle, E., Pesic, S., Jevtic, P. and Boscovic, D. (2021) Peer-to-peer insurance: Blockchain implications. Technical report, Society of Actuaries.Google Scholar
Breer, V.V. and Novikov, D.A. (2015) Threshold models of mutual insurance. Automation and Remote Control, 76(5), 897908.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlin, B.I. (2009) Strategic price complexity in retail financial markets. Journal of Financial Economics, 91(3), 278–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
China Insurance Regulatory Commission (2006) China Life Insurance Experienced Critical Illness Table (2006–2010). Data retrieved from http://bxjg.circ.gov.cn/web/site0/tab5225/info3891919.htm.Google Scholar
China Internet Network Information Center (2019) The 45th China Statistical Report on Internet Development. Data retrieved from http://www.cnnic.net.cn/hlwfzyj/hlwxzbg/hlwtjbg/202004/t20200428_70974.htm.Google Scholar
Denuit, M. (2019) Size-biased transform and conditional mean risk sharing, with application to P2P insurance and tontines. Astin Bulletin, 49(3), 591617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Denuit, M. (2020) Investing in your own and peers’ risks: The simple analytics of P2P insurance. Technical report.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Denuit, M. and Robert, C.Y. (2020) From risk sharing to risk transfer: The analytics of collaborative insurance. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Denuit, M. and Robert, C.Y. (2021a) From risk sharing to pure premium for a large number of heterogeneous losses. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 96, 116126.Google Scholar
Denuit, M. and Robert, C.Y. (2021b) Risk sharing under the dominant peer-to-peer property and casualty insurance business models. Risk Management and Insurance Review, 24, 181205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Denuit, M. and Robert, C.Y. (2021c) Stop-loss protection for a large P2P insurance pool. Technical report.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Donnelly, C. (2015) Actuarial fairness and solidarity in pooled annuity funds. ASTIN Bulletin, 45, 4974. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feng, R., Liu, C. and Taylor, S. (2020) Peer-to-peer risk sharing with an application to flood risk pooling. Working paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Handel, B., Hendel, I. and Whinston, M.D. (2015) Equilibria in health exchanges: Adverse selection versus reclassification risk. Econometrica, 83(4), 12611313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jiang, B. and Lin, T. (2018) Collaborative consumption: Strategic and economic implications of product sharing. Management Science, 64(3), 11711188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, J., Fang, Z., Nie, C. and Chen, S. (2022) Optimal design for network mutual aid. Probability in the Engineering and Informational Sciences, 37(2), 567597.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, X., Huang, W., Chen, Y. and Zhou, W. (2019) The effects of an online inquiry service on gatekeeping systems with heterogeneous patients. Journal of Management Science and Engineering, 4(4), 211227.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liu, S., Cheng, T. and Wang, H. (2020) Effects of attention and reliability on the performance of online medical crowdfunding projects: The moderating role of target amount. Journal of Management Science and Engineering, 5(3), 162171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lucas, R.E. (1980) Equilibrium in a pure currency economy. Economic Inquiry, 18(2), 203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prescott, E.C. and Townsend, R.M. (1984a) General competitive analysis in an economy with private information. International Economic Review, 25(1), 120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prescott, E.C. and Townsend, R.M. (1984b) Pareto optima and competitive equilibria with adverse selection and moral hazard. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 52(1), 2145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Research Institute of Ant Group (2020) Online Mutual Aid Industry White Paper.Google Scholar
Taylor, T.A. (2018) On-demand service platforms. Manufacturing and Service Operations Management, 20(4), 704720.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, G., Qi, H., Xu, H. and Ryu, S. (2020) A mixed behaviour equilibrium model with mode choice and its application to the endogenous demand of automated vehicles. Journal of Management Science and Engineering, 5(4), 227248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Number of participants in mutual aid platforms in China (in millions).

Figure 1

Figure 2. A graphic illustration of a mutual aid platform.

Figure 2

Figure 3. Sequence of events.

Figure 3

Table 1. Some examples of mutual aid platforms

Figure 4

Figure 4. $s_{1}$ against $l_{1}$ ($p_{2}=0.005$, $l_{2}=0.5$, $I_{1}=I_{2}=100,000$ yuan, $w_{1}=w_{2}=1$).

Figure 5

Figure 5. Population of two participant types in plans.

Figure 6

Figure 6. Total participant population in plans.

Figure 7

Figure 7. Number of participants in Xianghubao (in millions).

Figure 8

Table 2. Critical illness probability and total internet user population share

Figure 9

Table 3. Critical illness probability and total internet user population share

Figure 10

Table 4. Current mutual aid plan design ($\alpha=0.08$) if the value distribution is $F_{i}(x)=\frac{x}{\bar{v}_{i}}$

Figure 11

Table 5. Optimal mutual aid plan design if charging the same commission/subscription ($F_{i}(x)=\frac{x}{\bar{v}_{i}}$)

Figure 12

Table 6. Optimal mutual aid plan design ($F_{i}(x)=\frac{x}{\bar{v}_{i}}$)

Figure 13

Table 7. Optimal mutual aid plan design ($F_{i}(x)=1-e^{x/\kappa_{i}}$)

Figure 14

Figure 8. Maximum revenue against parameter values in $F_{i}$.

Supplementary material: PDF

Zhao and Zeng supplementary material

Zhao and Zeng supplementary material

Download Zhao and Zeng supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 231.8 KB