Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-g8jcs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-26T10:56:40.808Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Bureaucratic Development And Bureaucratization: The Case of Japan

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 January 2016

Bernard S. Silberman*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, The University of Chicago

Extract

One of the aspects of Japanese political development most puzzling to historians and political scientists is the seemingly rapid pendulum change from bureaucratic oligarchy to parliamentary cabinet to civil-military bureaucratic forms of government in the period between 1868 and 1945. Generally the argument that has been presented at least by Western observers is that, as Japan proceeded through the modernization process, each major stage of that process was reflected in a political transformation. One recent description states:

…the Japanese have experienced a variety of political systems over the past hundred years. They began their emergence from traditionalism under the direction of an oligarchy of bureaucrats whose power was sanctioned by imperial restoration. They adopted a limited kind of parliamentarism in 1890 (the Meiji Constitution) that came to a brief flowering in the immediate post-World War I years. Military authoritarianism was in the ascendancy in the 1930’s and became dominant in World War II.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Social Science History Association 1978 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Notes

1 Baerwald, Hans, “The Foreign Policy of Japan,” in Rosenau, James N., Thompson, Kenneth W., and Boyd, Gavin, eds., World Politics (New York, 1976), 133Google Scholar.

2 Silberman, Bernard S., “Ringi-sei—Traditional Values or Organizational Imperatives in the Japanese Upper Civil Service: 1868-1945,” Journal of Asian Studies, 32:2 (1973), 251–64CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

3 By a bureaucratic polity I mean a system distinguished by “rules of the game” that possess at least three characteristics:

1 That any given legal norm may be established by agreement or by imposition on the grounds of expediency (utility) or rational values or both with a claim to obedience on the part of the members of the polity.

2 Agreement that the prerequisite for evaluating (judging) utility and/or rationality is expertise.

3 Agreement that expertise is based on a career structure combining extended education and service in the public bureaucracy.

The end result of these rules is to give the civil servant a monopoly on the legitimate formulation of public policy regardless of the existence of other structures of politics.

Based on Weber, Max, The Theory of Social and Economic Organization, ed., Parsons, T. (Glencoe, Illinois, 1947), 329–30Google Scholar.

4 See Stinchcombe, Arthur L., “Social Structure and Organizations,” in March, James G., ed., Handbook of Organizations (Chicago, 1965)Google Scholar; Cyert, Richard M. and March, James G., A Behavioral Theory of the Firm (Englewood Cliffs, N.J., 1963) especially 99101Google Scholar; Emery, F. E. and Trist, E. L., “The Causal Texture of Organizational Environment,” Human Relations, 18 (1965), 2131CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Lawrence, Paul and Lorsch, Jay, Organization and Environment (Cambridge, Mass., 1967)Google Scholar.

5 See Terreberry, Shirley, “The Evolution of Organizational Environments,” Administrative Sciences Quarterly, 12 (1968), 590613CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Emery and Trist, op cit; Katz, D. and Kahn, R. L., The Social Psychology of Organizations (New York, 1966), 71109Google Scholar; Miller, J. G., “Living Systems: The Organization,” Behavioral Science, 17(1972), 1182CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed.

6 For these aspects generally see: Katz and Kahn, op cit; on differentiation, Lawrence and Lorsch, op cit; on succession, Grusky, Oscar, “Administrative Succession in Formal Organizations,” Social Forces, 39:2 (1960), 105–15CrossRefGoogle Scholar; on authority, Max Weber, op cit; Aldrich, Howard, “Organizational Boundaries and Interorganizational Conflict,” Human Relations, 24 (1971), 279–93CrossRefGoogle Scholar; French, Wendell, “Process vis-a-vis Systems: Toward a Model of the Enterprise and Administration,” Academy of Management Journal, 6 (1963), 4557CrossRefGoogle Scholar; March, James G. and Simon, Herbert A., Organizations (New York, 1958), 164169Google Scholar; on procurement and implementation, Yuchtman, Ephraim and Seashore, Stanley, “A System Resource Approach to Organizational Effectiveness,” in Baker, Frank, ed., Organizational Systems: General Systems Approaches to Complex Organizations (Homewood, Illinois, 1973), 439506Google Scholar.

7 Schmitter, Philippe C., “Still the Century of Corporatism,” Review of Politics, 36 (1974), 85131CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Shonfield, Andrew, Modern Capitalism (London, 1965)Google Scholar.

8 Silberman, Bernard S., Ministers of Modernization: Elite Mobility in the Meiji Restoration, 1868-1873 (Tucson, Arizona, 1964)Google Scholar.

9 Ibid., 38-107.

10 Junnosuke, Masumi, Nihon seitoshi ron (Tokyo, 1965), 1: 115341Google Scholar; Eiichi, Horie and Shigeki, Toyama, eds., Jiyū minkengo no kenkyū (Tokyo, 1959), vols. 1 and 4Google Scholar.

11 Gouldner, Alvin W., “The Problem of Succession in Bureaucracy,” in Gouldner, Alvin W., ed., Studies in Leadership and Democratic Action (New York, 1959), 341Google Scholar.

12 Silberman, Bernard S., “Bureaucratic Development and the Structure of Decision-Making in the Meiji Period: The Case of the Genrō,” Journal of Asian Studies, 26 (1967), 8194CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

13 Silberman, Bernard S., “Structural and Functional Differentiation in the Political Modernization of Japan,” in Ward, Robert E., ed., Political Development in Modern Japan (Princeton, New Jersey, 1968), 337–86Google Scholar.

14 Downs, Anthony, Inside Bureaucracy (Boston, 1967), 6788CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Rubenstein, Albert H. and Haberstroh, Chadwick J., eds., Some Theories of Organization (Homewood, Illinois, 1960), 229322Google Scholar; Babchuck, Nicholas, “Work Incentives in a Self-Determined Group,” American Sociological Review, 16 (1951), 679–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

15 Spaulding, Robert M. Jr., Imperial Japan’s Higher Civil Service Examinations (Princeton, New Jersey, 1967)Google Scholar; Silberman, Bernard S., “Bureaucratic Development and the Structure of Decision-Making in Japan, 1868-1925,” Journal of Asian Studies, 29:3 (1970), 347–62CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

16 Silberman, , “Bureaucratic Development and the Structure of Decision-Making in Japan.Google Scholar

17 Ibid.; Silberman, Bernard S., “The Bureaucratic Role in Japan, 1900-1945: The Bureaucrat as Politician,” in Silberman, Bernard S. and Harootunian, H. D., eds., Japan in Crisis (Princeton, New Jersey, 1974), 198200Google Scholar.

18 Silberman, , “Bureaucratic Development and the Structure of Decision-Making in the Meiji PeriodGoogle Scholar.”

19 Kumakichi, Uzaki, Choya no godaibatsu (Tokyo, 1912)Google Scholar.

20 Duus, Peter, Party Rivarly and Political Change in Taishō Japan (Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1968), 1314CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

21 Najita, Tetsuo, Hara Kei in the Politics of Compromise (Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1967), 511Google Scholar.

22 Silberman, , “The Bureaucratic Role in Japan,” 203Google Scholar.

23 Kenzō, Takayanagi, “A Century of Innovation: The Development of Japanese Law, 1868-1961,” in von Mehren, Arthur I., ed., Law in Japan (Cambridge, Massachusetts, 1963), 540Google Scholar. Hideo, Wada, “Gyosei Saiban,” in Kiyoaki, Tsuji, et al, eds., Nihon kindaihō hattatsushi (Tokyo, 1958), 3:85170Google Scholar.

24 Takeshi, Ishida, “The Development of Interest Groups and the Pattern of Political Modernizaton in Japan,” in Ward, Robert E., ed., Political Development in Modern Japan (Princeton, New Jersey, 1968), 293336Google Scholar; Masaaomi, Nagata, Keizai dantai hatten shi (Tokyo, 1956), ch. 1 and 2Google Scholar; Mamoru, Satō, Kindai Nihon seinen dantaishi kenkyū (Tokyo, 1970), 116, 79103, 535–40Google Scholar; Smethurst, Richard, A Social Basis for Prewar Japanese Militarism: The Armyand the Rural Community (Berkeley, California, 1974)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Kohen, Teikoku Nokai Shi, eds., Teikoku nōkai shi kō, 2 vols. (Tokyo, 1972)Google Scholar; Nōgyōkyodobu, Nōseikyoku, eds., Nihon no nōgyō dantai to nōgyōkyodō kumiai (Tokyo, 1952)Google Scholar; Gōrō, Yamazaki, Nihon rōdōundōshi (Tokyo, 1966)Google Scholar.

25 Kankokai, Shōkō Gyōseishi, eds., Shōkōgyōsheishi (Tokyo, 1955)Google Scholar.

26 Yoshio, Kanazawa, “The Regulation of Corporate Enterprise: The Law of Unfair Competition and the Control of Monopoly Power,” in von Mehren, Arthur T., ed., Law in Japan, 482Google Scholar.

27 Ibid.; Kojima Seiichi, Nihon senji sanhyō tosei ron (Tokyo, 1941)Google Scholar.

28 See Crowley, James B., Japan’s Quest for Autonomy: National Security and Foreign Policy 1930-38 (Princeton, New Jersey, 1966)Google Scholar and Ikuhito, Hata, Gun fuashizumu undōshi (Tokyo, 1962)Google Scholar for description of this period.

29 Gouldner, Alvin W., “Reciprocity and Autonomy in Functional Theory,” in Gross, Llewellyn, ed., Symposium on Sociological Theory (Evanston, Illinois, 1959)Google Scholar; Aldrich, Howard, “Organizational Boundaries and Interorganizational Conflict”; Gideon Sjoberg, “Contradictory Functional Requirements and Social Systems,” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 4 (1960), 198208Google Scholar.

30 Linz, Juan, “An Authoritarian Regime: The Case of Spain,” in Allard, Erik and Rokkan, Stein, eds., Mass Politics (New York, 1970), 255Google Scholar.