Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2plfb Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-23T03:16:53.986Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Diffusion technologique et transferts vers un drainage des cerveaux optimal

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 August 2016

Manon Domingues Dos Santos*
Affiliation:
EUREQua, Université de Paris†
Get access

Résumé

Cet article étudie l’impact de l’exode des cerveaux sur le bien-être des travailleurs de la région de départ lorsque celle ci peut bénéficier des avancées technologiques de la région d’accueil, par un processus d’imitation, et que les émigrés envoient une partie de leur revenu à leurs proches demeurés sédentaires. Il est montré qu’il peut être optimal pour la région dont l’activité d’innovation est la moins efficace de laisser émigrer une partie de sa main-d’œuvre qualifiée. L’approche retenue permet, également, de comparer le nombre d’émigrés à l’équilibre décentralisé et à l’optimum. Les conclusions dépendent, en outre, de l’efficacité du processus de copiage, de l’importance accordée aux émigrés dans l’objectif de bien-être de la région de départ et de l’ampleur des transferts financiers.

Summary

Summary

This paper studies the impact of the brain-drain on the welfare of the region of emigration when this region is likely to benefit from the technological discoveries realized in the region of arrival by an imitation process and when emigrants send a part of their income to their region of origine. We show that it can be optimal for the region where the sector of innovation is the less efficient to let emigrate a part of its qualified labor force. We also compare the number of emigrants at the decentralized equilibrium and at the optimum. The conclusions depend on the efficiency of the imitation process, on the way emigrants are taken into account in the welfare objective and on the size of financial transferts.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain, Institut de recherches économiques et sociales 1999 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

Je remercie P.Cahuc, A. Perrot et F. Postel-Vinay pour leurs précieux conseils. Je remercie également deux rapporteurs anomymes pour leur lecture minutieuse et leurs commentaires constructifs.

106-110, boulevard de l’Hôpital 75013 Paris, France, e-mail : [email protected]

References

Bibliographie

Aghion, P., Howitt, P., (1992), A model of growth through creative destruction, Econometrica, 60, pp. 323351.Google Scholar
Atkinson, A., (1973). How progressive schould income tax be? Perkin, M. ed., Essay in modern economics, Longman, Londres.Google Scholar
Barro, R. & Sala-I-Martin, X., (1995), Economic growth, McGraw-Hill Advanced Series in Economics.Google Scholar
Baumol, W., (1982), The income distribution frontier and taxation of migrants, Journal of Public Economics, 18, pp. 343361.Google Scholar
Bhagwati, J., Hamada, D., (1974), The brain drain, international integration of markets for professionals and unemployment: a theoritical analysis, Journal of Development Economics, 1, pp. 1924.Google Scholar
Bhagwati, J., Hamada, D., (1982), Tax policy in the presence of emigration, Journal of Public Economics, 18, pp. 291317.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O., (1985), Debt, deficits, and finite horizons, Journal of Political Economy, 93, pp. 223247.Google Scholar
Blitz, R., (1977), A benefit-cost analysis of foreign workers in West germany, 1957–1973, Kyklos, 30, pp. 479502.Google Scholar
Brezis, E., Krugman, P., Tsiddon, D., (1993), Leapfrogging in international competition: a theory of cycles in national technological leadership, Journal of Political Economy, 83, pp. 12111219.Google Scholar
Burda, M., Wyplosz, C., (1992), Human capital and migration in an integrated Europe, European Economic Review, 36, pp. 677684.Google Scholar
Cashin, P., Loaysa, N., (1995), Paradise lost? Growth, convergence and migration in the south pacific, International Monetary Staff Papers, vol 42, n° 3.Google Scholar
Domingues Dos Santos, M., (1997), Is the unskilled workers immigration necessarily harmful for the unskilled natives?, document de travail.Google Scholar
Domingues Dos Santos, M., Postel-Vinay, F., (1998), Migration as a source of convergence, mimeo.Google Scholar
Grossman, G., Helpman, E., (1991), Innovation and growth in the global economy, MIT Press.Google Scholar
Grossman, G., Helpman, E., (1991), Quality ladders and product cycles, Quaterly Journal of Ecomonics, 106, pp. 557586.Google Scholar
Grubel, H., Scott, A., (1966), The international flow of human capital, American Economic Review, 56, pp. 268274.Google Scholar
Haque, N., Kim, S., (1995), Human capital flight: impact of migration on income and growth, IMF Staff Papers, 42, pp. 577607.Google Scholar
Hoddinott, J., (1994), A model of migration and remittances applied to western Kenya, Oxford Economic Papers.Google Scholar
Krugman, P., (1979), A model of innovation, technology transfert, and the world distribution of income, Journal of Political Economy, 87, pp. 681716.Google Scholar
Lai, E., (1995), The product cycle and the world distribution of income: a reformulation, Journal of International Economics, 39, pp. 369382.Google Scholar
Lebon, A., (1993), Aspects de l’immigration et de la présence étrangère en France, 19911992, La Documentation française.Google Scholar
Lucas, R., Stark, O., (1985), Motivations to Remit: evidence from Botswana, Journal of Political Economy, 93, pp. 901918.Google Scholar
Mansfield, E., Schwartz, M., Wagner, S., (1981), Imitation costs and patents: an empirical study, Economic Journal, 91, pp. 907918.Google Scholar
Mirlees, J., (1971), An exploration in the theory of optimal income taxation, Review of Economic Studies, 38, pp. 175208.Google Scholar
Miyagiwa, K., (1991), Scale economies in education and the brain drain problem, International Economic Review, 32, pp. 743759.Google Scholar
Mountford, A., (1997), Can brain drain be good for growth in the source economy?, Journal of Development Economics, 53, pp. 287303.Google Scholar
Nelson, R., Phelps, E., (1966), Investment in humans, technological change and economic growth, American Economic Review, 56, pp. 6975.Google Scholar
Rivera-Batiz, L., Romer, P., (1991), Economic integration and endogenous growth, Quaterly Journal of Ecomonics, 106, pp. 531555.Google Scholar
Romer, P., (1990), Endogenous technological change, Journal of Political Economy, 98, vol 5, October, part II, S71S102.Google Scholar
Segerstrom, P., (1991), Innovation, imitation, and economic growth, Journal of Political Economy, 99, pp. 807827.Google Scholar
Stark, O., Helmenstein, C Prskawetz, A., (1998), A brain drain with a brain gain, Economics Letters, 55, pp. 227234.Google Scholar
Swamy, G., (1981), International migrant workers’remittances: issues and prospects, World Bank Staff Working Paper, n° 481.Google Scholar
Teece, D., (1977), Technological transfert by multinational firms:the ressource cost of transferring technological know-how, Economic Journal, 87, pp. 242261.Google Scholar
Vidal, J.P, (1998), The effect of emigration on human capital formation, Journal of Population Economics, pp. 589600.Google Scholar
Wilson, J., (1982), Optimal income taxation and migration, Journal of Public Economics, 18, pp. 381397.Google Scholar
World Bank, (1998), World developement indicators, World Bank.Google Scholar