Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-r5fsc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T11:38:26.536Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

MIGRATION AND THE EQUILIBRIUM PREVALENCE OF INFECTIOUS DISEASES

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  29 February 2016

Alice Mesnard
Affiliation:
City University London and Institute for Fiscal Studies Email: [email protected].
Paul Seabright
Affiliation:
Toulouse School of Economics (IAST)
Get access

Abstract:

This paper models how migration both influences and responds to differences in disease prevalence between cities and shows how the possibility of migration away from high-prevalence areas affects long-run steady state disease prevalence. We develop a dynamic framework where migration responds to the prevalence of disease, to the costs of migration and to the costs of living. The model explores how pressure for migration in response to differing equilibrium levels of disease prevalence generates differences in city characteristics such as land rents. Competition for scarce housing in low-prevalence areas can create segregation, with disease concentrated in high-prevalence “sinks”. We show that policies affecting migration costs affect the steady-state disease prevalences across cities. In particular, migration can reduce steady-state disease incidence in low-prevalence areas while having no impact on prevalence in high-prevalence areas. This suggests that, in some circumstances, public health measures may need to avoid discouraging migration away from high-disease areas.

Type
Research Papers
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain 2016 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Acemoglu, Daron, Simon, Johnson and Robinson, James (2001) Colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review 91, 13691401.Google Scholar
Auld, M.C. (2003) Choice, beliefs, and infectious disease dynamics. Journal of Health Economics 22 (3), 361377.Google Scholar
Bauch, C., Onofrio, A.d. and Manfredi, P. (2013) Behavioral epidemiology of infectious diseases: An overview. In Onofrio, A.d. and Manfredi, P. (eds.), Modeling the Interplay between Human Behavior and Spread of Infectious Diseases. New York: Springer.Google Scholar
Barreca, Alan, Fishback, Price and Kantor, Shawn (2011) The impact of migration on malaria deaths in the early 20 century United States. mimeo, University of Tulane.Google Scholar
Bell, Clive, Devarajan, Shantayanan and Gersbach, Hans (2006) The long-run economic costs of AIDS: A model with an application to South Africa. World Bank Economic Review 20, 5589.Google Scholar
Bell, Clive and Gersbach, Hans (2006) Growth and enduring epidemic diseases. CESifo Working Paper Series, CESifo GmbH.Google Scholar
Bénabou, Roland (1996a) Equity and efficiency in human capital investment: The local connection. Review of Economic Studies 63, 237–64.Google Scholar
Bénabou, Roland (1996b) Heterogeneity, stratification, and growth: Macroeconomic implications of community structure and school finance. American Economic Review 86, 584609.Google Scholar
Boily, Marie-Claude (2002) The impact of migration patterns of female sex workers on a slow spreading HIV epidemic: Implications for prevention. Meeting on “Phase Specific Aspects of STD and HIV epidemiology and Prevention”.Google Scholar
Chen, Frederik and Toxvaerd, Flavio (2014) The economics of vaccination. Journal of Theoretical Biology 363, 105117.Google Scholar
Crosby, Alfred (1986) Ecological Imperialism: The Biological Expansion of Europe 900–1900, New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Duncan, G.J., Daly, M.C., McDonough, P. and Williams, D.R. (2002) Optimal indicators of socioeconomic status for health research. American Journal of Public Health 92 (7), 11511157.Google Scholar
Dupas, Pascaline, Duflo, Esther and Kremer, Michael (2015) Education, HIV, and early fertility: Experimental evidence from Kenya. American Economic Review Vol. 105 (9), pp. 2257–97.Google Scholar
Ellickson, Bryan (1971) Jurisdictional fragmentation and residential choice. American Economic Review 61, 334–39.Google Scholar
Epple, Dennis (2003) Modeling population stratification across locations : An overview. International Science Review 26 (2), 189196.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fenichel, E.P. (2013) Economic considerations for social distancing and behavioral based policies during an epidemic. Journal of Health Economics 32 (2), 440451.Google Scholar
Fenichel, E.P. and Wang, X. (2013) The mechanism and phenomenon of adaptive human behavior during an epidemic and the role of information. In Onofrio, A.d. and Manfredi, P. (eds.), Modeling the Interplay between Human Behavior and Spread of Infectious Diseases. New York: Springer.Google Scholar
Fernandez, Raquel and Rogerson, Richard (1996) Income distribution, communities, and the quality of public education. Quarterly Journal of Economics 111, 135–64.Google Scholar
Finkelstein, Amy, Luttmer, Enzo F. P and Notowidigdo, Matthew J. (2013) What a good is wealth without health? The effect of health on the marginal utility of consumption. Journal of the European Economic Association 11, 221258.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geoffard, Pierre Yves and Philipson, Thomas (1996) Rational epidemics and their public control. International Economic Review 37 (3), 603624.Google Scholar
Gersovitz, Mark and Hammer, Jeffrey S. (2003) Infectious diseases, public policy and the marriage of economics and epidemiology. World Bank Research Observer 18, 129157.Google Scholar
Gersovitz, Mark and Hammer, Jeffrey S. (2004) The economical control of infectious diseases. Economic Journal 114, 127.Google Scholar
Hurd, Michel, Adams, Peter, McFadden, Daniel, Merill, Angela, and Ribeiro, Tiago (2003) Healthy, wealth and Wise? Tests for direct causal paths between health and socioeconomic status. Journal of Econometrics 112 (1), 356.Google Scholar
Kremer, Michael (2000) Creating markets for new vaccines. Part I: rationale and Part 2: Design Issues. Innovation Policy and the Economy, Volume 1 (2001), Jaffe, Adam B., Lerner, Josh and Stern, Scott, editors (pp. 35118). Published in January 2001 by MIT Press in NBER Book Series Innovation Policy and the Economy.Google Scholar
Lurie, M., Williams, B., Zuma, K., Mkaya-Mwamburi, D., Garnett, G.P., Sweat, M.D., Gittelsohn, J., and Abdool Karim, S.S. (2003) Who infects whom? HIV concordance and discordance among migrant and non-migrant couples in South Africa. AIDS 17, 22452252.Google Scholar
McNeill, William H. (1977) Plagues and people Doubleday, New York.Google Scholar
Marmot, Michael G. (2002) The influence of income on health: Views of an epidemiologis. Health Affairs 21 (2), 3146.Google Scholar
Medlock, J., Luz, P.M., Struchiner, C.J., and Galvani, A.P. (2009) The impact of transgenic mosquitoes on dengue virulence to humans and mosquitoes. The American Naturalist 174 (4), 565577.Google Scholar
Mesnard, Alice and Seabright, Paul (2009) Escaping epidemics through migration? Quarantine measures under asymmetric information about infection risk. Journal of Public Economics 93, 931938.Google Scholar
Montalvo, Jose G. and Reynal-Querol, Marta (2007) Fighting against malaria: prevent wars while waiting for the miraculous vaccines. The Review of Economics and Statistics 89 (1), 165177.Google Scholar
Pattanayak, Subhrendu, Poulos, Christine and Yang, Jui-Chen (2007) Modeling self-protection against infectious disease: Towards the theory of the economics of environmental epidemiology, RTI INternational, mimeo.Google Scholar
Philipson, Thomas (2000) Handbook of Health Economics, Culyer and Newhouse, eds.: North-Holland.Google Scholar
d’Onofrio, A., Manfredi, P. and Salinelli, E. (2013) Vaccinating behavior and the dynamics of vaccine preventable infections. In d’Onofrio, A. and Manfredi, P. (eds.), Modeling the Interplay between Human Behavior and Spread of Infectious Diseases. New York: Springer.Google Scholar
Reluga, T.C. (2010) Game theory of social distancing. PLoS Computational Biology 6 (5), e1000793.Google Scholar
Sethi, S.P. (1978) Optimal quarantine programmes for controlling an epidemic spread. Journal of the Operational Research Society 29, 265268.Google Scholar
Tiebout, Charles M. (1956) A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy 64 (5), 416424.Google Scholar
Timmins, Christopher (2005). Estimable equilibrium models of locational sorting and their role in development economics. Journal of Economic Geography 5, 83100.Google Scholar
Tocqueville, Alexis de (1981) Journey to America, translated by Lawrence, George and edited by Mayer, J.P., revised in collaboration with A.P. Kerr, Greenwood Press Publishers, Westport, CT.Google Scholar
Wong, Grace (2008) Has SARS infected the property market? Evidence from Hong Kong. Journal of Urban Economics 63 (1), 7495.Google Scholar