Hostname: page-component-7bb8b95d7b-dvmhs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-10-05T20:24:00.093Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

From Development to Democracy: The Transformations of Modern Asia. By Dan Slater and Joseph Wong. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2022. 368 pp. Notes, references, index. Hardcover, $35.00. ISBN: 978-0-69116-760-2.

Review products

From Development to Democracy: The Transformations of Modern Asia. By Dan Slater and Joseph Wong. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2022. 368 pp. Notes, references, index. Hardcover, $35.00. ISBN: 978-0-69116-760-2.

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  08 February 2023

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Type
Book Review
Copyright
Copyright © 2023 The President and Fellows of Harvard College

In January 1989, amid a dramatic political liberalization that would see the Kuomintang (KMT) party submit itself to multiparty elections, a delegation of social scientists visited Taipei for a conference on political change. Boarding in Boston, several Harvard government department faculty members noted that Samuel Huntington seemed to disappear. He later emerged in Taipei, having been spirited away to first class on the flight, to walk a literal red carpet rolled out by the KMT. Huntington would be honored, alongside Seymour Martin Lipset, by the KMT, who were appealing to Taiwanese voters in the 1989 parliamentary elections by touting their record of delivering economic development and social stability to the island.

In the intellectual history of theorizing political modernization, Lipset and Huntington are frequently pitted against each other. Lipset's Political Man (1960) is considered among the preeminent statements of modernization theory, positing that the strength of democracy is highly correlated with the degree of economic development, wealth, education, and urbanization. Huntington's Political Order in Changing Societies (1968), by contrast, famously observed that rapid social change can just as easily generate disorder and that the process of economic development must be contained by strong states with effective institutions, regardless of regime type. Yet one can see why the KMT found vindication in the ideas of both men; Taiwan's ruling party had staved off a Communist threat through capitalist economic growth and also contained the social problems that growth can produce by building a capacious state. Now, their narrative went, they were delivering democracy, and citizens ought to reward the party's successful management of modernization with votes in competitive elections.

Dan Slater and Joseph Wong's new book earns its place in this intellectual canon. The book brings the varied experiences in Asia—the region in which grand economic and political theories have long met with insurmountable evidentiary challenge—to bear on the perennially important discussion of the relationship between development and democracy. As its title suggests, the book's primary contribution is to identify a pathway through which Asian countries effectively democratized “from strength,” first delivering economic development or social stability and then opening to political competition, not because they were weak and conceded to opposition movements they could not repress but rather because they expected to maintain some political power after democratization because they were strong.

Taiwan is indeed the “paradigmatic case,” but this is not a book purporting to generalize from the unique experiences of the East Asian Tigers (p. 89). Slater and Wong group Asian regimes into “clusters” that share developmental and political trajectories. Developmental statist regimes (Japan, Taiwan, Hong Kong) enjoyed high state strength through development and democratized from it; developmental Britannia (Singapore, Malaysia, Hong Kong) enjoy high strength but ruling parties have not conceded democracy; developmental militarism regimes (Indonesia, Thailand, Myanmar) feature regimes of intermediate strength, and all conceded to democracy but Thailand and Myanmar reversed that concession; and the developmental socialism cases (China, Vietnam, Cambodia) are also of intermediate strength but have not conceded.

Among the regimes that have not conceded are some that Slater and Wong identify as “embittered,” ruled by regimes or parties, like the People's Action Party (PAP) in Singapore or the Chinese Communist Party (CCP), that passed a point at which they could have conceded from strength and now avoid democracy, much to society's detriment. Democracy-avoidant regimes—Malaysia, Singapore, China, Cambodia, and Hong Kong—feature ruling parties that either missed their “sweet spots” at which conceding democracy would have benefited the parties and society or have little confidence in their chances for victory or society's chances at stability post-transition. They have different reasons, to be sure. Singapore's PAP and China's CCP are simply too strong to have to consider concession, while Malaysia's United Malays National Organisation (UMNO) misread electoral signals and ended up being deposed in weakness.

The book challenges the idea that authoritarian leaders concede only when demands for redistribution or power sharing overwhelm them. This view is best represented by the political economists Daron Acemoglu and James Robinson's Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy (2005), itself a rejoinder to Barrington Moore's social class approach. Yet the deeper one reads the narratives in Slater and Wong's book, the more its definitions of weakness and strength seem to slide, such that one can come to appreciate elements of the political economy approach. The PAP could concede from strength but is too strong to have to, while the CCP in 1989 judged itself too weak, and is now strong enough but does not have signals of weakness that could persuade its leaders that concessions would be necessary. The experience of democratization in Asia teaches us that democracy can come from development and conscious choices of politically strong elites, but there must be demand for change from society more broadly.

The book is written accessibly for nonspecialists, and its narratives of transformation in Asia render the region legible for those interested in the broad sweep of political and economic change there. It is decidedly theoretical rather than empirical, and the conclusion engages some of the policy implications. There, Slater and Wong present a not-so-subtle critique of how policymakers, particularly in the West, have imagined democratic possibilities. They suggest that perhaps better democracy comes from better authoritarianism—the sort that builds effective institutions and delivers economic development and public welfare—rather than from weakness. These better authoritarians, they argue, should be offered “conditional encouragement,” and democracy-promotion efforts ought to be ones that convince autocrats of their eventual safety rather than “unrelenting pressure” for regime change (p. 297).

Such an exhortation may fall on deaf ears in the West, where political leaders on the left and right prefer to pitch competition with China and conflict with Russia in terms of a struggle between democracy and authoritarianism. But one senses that if Slater and Wong could will their book into the hands of some leaders, it would be those at the helms of the Vietnamese and Chinese Communist Parties, both designated “candidates” to democratizate through strength, although the authors do not suggest that they will. Both are also “tragically” dominant parties, built on revolution, quite strong, and lacking organized opposition groups or movements (p. 299). Ironically, this strength may eventually produce weakness, as ruling parties can no longer receive signals about their legitimacy in society. Slater and Wong may be right that democratization through strength is somehow optimal for society, but most societies do not have optimizers, only humans, with all their fears and desires for self-preservation. For those increasingly repressive regimes, like China, Myanmar, and Cambodia, the prospects for inclusive politics via some peaceful path look bleak indeed.