Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dsjbd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-26T09:20:55.780Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Legislative Bargaining and the Dynamics of Public Investment

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 May 2012

MARCO BATTAGLINI*
Affiliation:
Princeton University
SALVATORE NUNNARI*
Affiliation:
California Institute of Technology
THOMAS R. PALFREY*
Affiliation:
California Institute of Technology
*
Marco Battaglini is Professor of Economics, Princeton University, Fisher Hall, Princeton NJ 08544 ([email protected]).
Salvatore Nunnari is a PhD Candidate in Social Sciences, California Institute of Technology, MC-228-77, 1200 E. California Boulevard, Pasadena, CA 91125 ([email protected]).
Thomas R. Palfrey is Flintridge Foundation Professor of Economics and Political Science, California Institute of Technology, MC-228-77, 1200 E. California Boulevard, Pasadena, CA 91125 ([email protected]).

Abstract

We present a legislative bargaining model of the provision of a durable public good over an infinite horizon. In each period, there is a societal endowment that can either be invested in the public good or consumed. We characterize the optimal public policy, defined by the time path of investment and consumption. In a legislature representatives of each of n districts bargain over the current period's endowment for investment in the public good and transfers to each district. We analyze the Markov perfect equilibrium under different voting q-rules where q is the number of yes votes required for passage. We show that the efficiency of the public policy is increasing in q because higher q leads to higher investment in the public good and less pork. We examine the theoretical equilibrium predictions by conducting a laboratory experiment with five-person committees that compares three alternative voting rules: unanimity (q = 5), majority (q = 3), and dictatorship (q = 1).

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 2012

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Austen-Smith, David, and Banks, Jeffrey S.. 1996. “Information Aggregation, Rationality, and the Condorcet Jury Theorem.” American Political Science Review 90 (1): 3445.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aumann, Robert J. (1959). “Acceptable Points in General Cooperative Q-person Games.” In Contributions to the Theory of Games IV, Annals of Mathematics Study 40, eds, Luce, R. D. and Tucker, A. W., Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 287324.Google Scholar
Baron, David P. 1996. “A Dynamic Theory of Collective Goods Procedures.” American Political Science Review 90: 316–30.Google Scholar
Baron, David P., and Ferejohn, John. 1989. “Bargaining in Legislatures.” American Political Science Review 83: 11811206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, David P., Diermeier, D., and Fong, P.. 2012. “A Dynamic Theory of Parliamentary Democracy.” Economic Theory 49 (3): 703–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barry, Brian. 1965. Political Argument. London: Routledge and Kegan.Google Scholar
Barseghyan, Levon, Battaglini, Marco, and Coate, Stephen. 2011. “Fiscal Policy over the Real Business Cycle: A Positive Theory.” Cornell University. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Battaglini, Marco, and Coate, Stephen. 2006. “Inefficiency in Legislative Policymaking: A Dynamic Analysis.” American Economic Review 97: 118–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Battaglini, Marco, and Coate, Stephen. 2008. “A Dynamic Theory of Public Spending, Taxation and Debt.” American Economic Review 98: 201–36.Google Scholar
Battaglini, Marco, Nunnari, Salvatore, and Palfrey, Thomas. 2010. “Political Institutions and the Dynamics of Public Investment.” Caltech Social Science Working Paper 1318.Google Scholar
Battaglini, Marco, Nunnari, Salvatore, and Palfrey, Thomas. 2012. “The Free Rider Problem: A Dynamic Analysis.” Princeton University. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Battaglini, Marco, and Palfrey, Thomas. 2012. “The Dynamics of Redistributive Politics.” Economic Theory 49 (3): 739–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boylan, Richard T., Ledyard, John, and McKelvey, Richard D.. 1996. “Political Competition in a Model of Economic Growth: Some Theoretical Results.” Economic Theory 7 (2): 191205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boylan, Richard T., and McKelvey, Richard D.. 1995. “Voting over Economic Plans.” American Economic Review 85 (4): 860–71.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M., and Tullock, Gordon. 1962. The Calculus of Consent. Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Choi, Syngjoo, Gale, Douglas, and Kariv, Shachar. 2008. “Sequential Equilibrium in Monotone Games: A Theory-based Analysis of Experimental Data.” Journal of Economic Theory 143 (1), 302–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Choi, Syngjoo, Gale, Douglas, Kariv, Shachar, and Palfrey, Thomas. 2011. “Network Architecture, Salience and Coordination.” Games and Economic Behavior 73 (1): 7690.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Condorcet, Marquis de. 1785. Essai sur l'Application de L’ Analyse à la Probabilite des Decisions Rendues à la Pluraliste des Voix. Paris.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary. 1987. “Electoral Equilibria under Alternative Voting Institutions.” American Journal of Political Science 31: 82108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dal Bo, Pedro. 2005. “Cooperation under the Shadow of the Future: Experimental Evidence from Infinitely Repeated Games.” American Economic Review 95 (5): 1591–604.Google Scholar
Dal Bo, Pedro, and Frechette, Guillame. 2011. “The Evolution of Cooperation in Infinitely Repeated Games: Experimental Evidence.” American Economic Review 101 (1): 411–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diermeier, Daniel, and Gailmard, Sean. 2006. “Self-interest, Inequality, and Entitlement in Majoritarian Decision-making.” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 1: 327–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diermeier, Daniel, and Morton, Rebecca. 2006. “Experiments in Majoritarian Bargaining.” In Social Choice and Strategic Decisions: Essays in Honor of Jeffrey S. Banks, eds. Austen-Smith, D. and Duggan, J.. Springer: Heidelberg, 201–26.Google Scholar
Duggan, John, and Kalandrakis, Tasos. N.d. “Dynamic Legislative Policy Making.”Journal of Economic Theory. Forthcoming.Google Scholar
Duffy, John, and Ochs, Jack. 2009. “Cooperative Behavior and the Frequency of Social Interaction.” Games and Economic Behavior 66 (2): 785812.Google Scholar
Duffy, John, Ochs, Jack, and Vesterlund, Lise. 2007. “Giving Little by Little: Dynamic Public Good Games.” Journal of Public Economics 91: 1708–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferejohn, John., Forsythe, Robert E., Noll, Roger G., and Palfrey, Thomas R.. 1982. “An Experimental Examination of Auction Mechanisms for Discrete Public Goods.” In Research in Experimental Economics 2, ed. Smith, Vernon. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, 175–99.Google Scholar
Frechette, Guillaume, Kagel, John H., and Lehrer, Steven F.. 2003. “Bargaining in Legislatures: An Experimental Investigation of Open versus Closed Amendment Rules.” American Political Science Review 97: 221–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frechette, Guillaume, Kagel, John H., and Morelli, Massimo. 2012. “Pork versus Public Goods: An Experimental Study of Public Good Provision within a Legislative Bargaining Framework.” Economic Theory 49 (3): 779800.Google Scholar
Guth, Werner, Schmittberger, Rolf, and Schwarze, Bernd. 1982. “An Experimental Analysis of Ultimatum Bargaining.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 3: 367–88.Google Scholar
Harrison, G., and Hirshleifer, J.. 1989. “An Experimental Evaluation of Weakest Link/Best Shot Models of Public Goods.” Journal of Political Economy 97: 201–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harstad, Bard. 2005. “Majority Rules and Incentives.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 120 (4): 535–68.Google Scholar
Kagel, John H., Sung, Hankyoung, and Winter, Eyal. “Veto Power in Committees: An Experimental Study.” Experimental Economics 13 (2): 167188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalandrakis, Tasos. 2004. “A Three Player Dynamic Majoritarian Bargaining Game.” Journal of Economic Theory 16 (2): 294322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalandrakis, Tasos. 2009. “Minimum Winning Coalitions and Endogenous Status-quo.” International Journal of Game Theory 39 (4): 617–43.Google Scholar
Ledyard, John O. 1997. “Public Goods: A Survey of Experimental Research.” In The Handbook of Experimental Economics, eds. Kagel, J. H. and Roth, A. E.. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press 111–94.Google Scholar
McGuire, Martin C., and Olson, Mancur. 1996. “The Economics of Autocracy and Majority Rule: The Invisible Hand and the Use of Force.” Journal of Economic Literature 34 (1): 7296.Google Scholar
McKelvey, Richard D. 1991. “An Experimental Test of a Stochastic Game Model of Committee Bargaining.” In Laboratory Research in Political Economy, ed. Palfrey, T.. Ann Arbor University of Michigan Press, 139–69.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1993. “Dictatorship, Democracy, and DevelopmentAmerican Political Science Review 87 (3): 567–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor, Gardner, Roy, and Walker, James, 1994. Rules, Games, and Common-pool Resources. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palfrey, Thomas, and Rosenthal, Howard. 1994. “Repeated Play, Cooperation and Coordination: An Experimental Study.” Review of Economic Studies 61: 545–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Penn, Elizabeth M. 2009. “A Model of Farsighted Voting.” American Journal of Political Science 53 (1): 3654.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rauch, James. 1995. “Bureaucracy, Infrastructure, and Economic Growth: Evidence from U.S. Cities during the Progressive Era.” American Economic Review 85 (4): 968–79.Google Scholar
Roth, Alvin, and Murnighan, Keith. 1978. “Equilibrium Behavior and Repeated Play of the Prisoner's Dilemma.” Journal of Mathematical Psychology 17: 189–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rousseau, Jean-Jacques. [1762] 1988. On Social Contract or Principles of Political Right. New York. W.W. Norton.Google Scholar
Smith, Vernon. 1977. “The Principle of Unanimity and Voluntary Consent in Social Choice.” Journal of Political Economy 85 (6): 1125–39.Google Scholar
Stokey, N., Lucas, R., and Prescott, E.. 1989. Recursive Methods in Economic Dynamics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Volden, Craig, and Wiseman, Alan E.. 2007. “Bargaining in Legislatures over Particularistic and Collective Goods.” American Political Science Review 101: 7992.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walker, James M., Gardner, Roy, Herr, Andrew, and Ostrom, Elinor. 2000. “Collective Choice in the Commons: Experimental Results on Proposed Allocation Rules and Votes.” Economic Journal 110 (460): 212–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wicksell, Knut. [1896] 1967. “Ein neues Prinzip der gerechten Besteurung.” Finanztheoretische Undersuchungen Jena: iv–vi, 76–87, 101–59. Trans., Buchanan, James reprinted as “A New Principle of Just Taxation” in Classics. In the Theory of Public Finance. New York: St. Martin's Press, 72118.Google Scholar
Yared, Pierre. 2010. “Politicians, Taxes, and Debt.” Review of Economic Studies 77: 806–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Battaglini et al. supplementary material

Appendix

Download Battaglini et al. supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 798 KB
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.