Published online by Cambridge University Press: 09 August 2023
INTRODUCTION
“I had a growing feeling in the later years of my work at the subject that a good mathematical theorem dealing with economic hypotheses was very well unlikely to be good economics.”
Alfred Marshall, letter to Arthur Bowley, 1906“Though a skilled mathematician, he [Marshall] used mathematics sparingly. He saw that excessive reliance on this instrument might lead us astray in pursuit of intellectual toys, imaginary problems not conforming to the conditions of real life.”
Arthur Cecil Pigou, Marshall’s successor as Professor of Political Economy at Cambridge, Memorials of Alfred MarshallAlfred Marshall spent most of his academic career at the University of Cambridge, eventually retiring as Professor of Political Economy there in 1908 after more than forty years’ academic service within the UK. He was an important theorist in his own right, but he is perhaps best remembered today as a brilliant synthesizer of existing ideas, bringing flashes of insight from various parts of the literature into a single theoretical system (Hodgson 2001). More than anybody else, he was responsible for fleshing out the contributions that various marginalist techniques could be expected to make to economic theory as if they had all come from the same hand (Maloney 1991). The ideas on which he drew were therefore by no means all his own, although he did put his distinctive gloss on them in his renowned book, The Principles of Economics. It went through eight editions, eventually totalling 870 pages, and it was quickly seized upon as the authoritative text for learning about the market concept in what I have called its analytical form. For a number of decades it was as if economics in its orthodox Anglophone guise was specifically Marshallian. George Stigler published his Theory of Price in 1946 and Paul Samuelson his Economics in 1948 in an attempt to dislodge Marshall’s Principles of Economics as the dominant teaching text. Their aim was that they might showcase the work of a newer generation of neoclassical economists.
So great were Marshall’s skills as a synthesizer that theoretical discoveries were often attributed to him retrospectively, even when they had appeared earlier in their original form in someone else’s writings.
To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.