Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-t5tsf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-09T07:07:50.450Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 August 2021

Martin Paldam
Affiliation:
Aarhus Universitet, Denmark
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2021

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J. A., 2005. Institutions as the fundamental cause of long-run growth. Chapter 6, 385–472 in Aghion and Durlauf (2005)Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J. A., Yared, P., 2008. Income and democracy. American Economic Review 98, 808–42Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Naidu, S. Restrepo, P., Robinson, J. A., 2019. Democracy does cause growth. Journal of Political Economy 127, 47100CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, P., Durlauf, S., eds., 2005, 2014. Handbook of Economic Growth. Four volumes. North-Holland, AmsterdamGoogle Scholar
Aidt, T. S., 2003. Economic analysis of corruption: A survey. Economic Journal 113 (491), 632–52. Also Chapter 3 in Dutta and Aidt (2016)Google Scholar
Aidt, T. S., Franck, R., 2015. Democratization under the threat of revolution: Evidence from the great reform act of 1832. Econometrica 83, 505–47Google Scholar
Aidt, T. S., Jensen, P. S., 2014. Workers of the world, unite! Franchise extensions and the threat of revolution in Europe, 1820–1938. European Economic Review 72, 5275Google Scholar
Aisen, A., Veiga, J. F., 2013. How does political instability affect economic growth? European Journal of Political Economy 29, 151–67Google Scholar
Aizenman, J., Marion, N., 1993. Policy uncertainty, persistence, and economic growth. Review of International Economics 1, 145–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, A., Özler, S., Roubini, N., Swagel, P., 2006. Political instability and economic growth. Journal of Economic Growth 1, 189211Google Scholar
Andersen, T. B., Jensen, P. S., 2019. Preaching democracy. Journal of Comparative Economics 47(3), 525–40Google Scholar
Andvig, J. C., Moene, K. O., 1990. How corruption corrupts. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 13, 6376. Also Chapter 16 in Dutta and Aidt (2016)Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J., 1963. Social Choice and Individual Values (2nd ed.). Yale University Press, New Haven, CTGoogle Scholar
Åslund, A., 2002. Building Capitalism. The Transformation of the Former Soviet Bloc. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
Azariadis, C., Stachurski, J., 2005. Poverty traps. Chapter 5, 295–384 in Aghion and Durlauf (2005)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Azzi, C., Ehrenberg, R., 1975. Household allocation of time and church attendance. The Journal of Political Economy 83, 2756Google Scholar
Barro, R. J., Sala-i-Martin, X., 1995, 2004. Economic Growth. MIT Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
Basu, S., Bundick, A., 2017. Uncertainty shocks in a model of effective demand. Econometrica 85, 937–58Google Scholar
Berger, H., Spoerer, M., 2001. Economic crises and the European revolutions of 1848. Journal of Economic History 61, 293326Google Scholar
Binswanger, H. P., Deininger, K., Feder, G. 1995. Power, distortions, revolt and reform in agricultural land relations. Chapter 42, 26592772 in Behrman, J., Srinivasan, T. N., eds., Handbook of Development Economics, Vol 3B. North Holland, AmsterdamGoogle Scholar
Bjørnskov, C., 2010. How does social trust lead to better governance? An attempt to separate electoral and bureaucratic mechanisms. Public Choice 144, 323–46Google Scholar
Bjørnskov, C., Paldam, M., 2012. The spirits of capitalism and socialism. A cross-country study of ideology. Public Choice 150, 469–98Google Scholar
Blaug, M., 1997. Economic Theory in Retrospect, 5th ed. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
Bloom, N., 2009. The impact of uncertainty shocks. Econometrica 77, 623–85Google Scholar
Blume, L., Müller, J., Voigt, S., 2009. The economic effects of direct democracy: A first global assessment. Public Choice 140, 431–61Google Scholar
Bond, S. R., Eberhardt, M., 2013. Accounting for Unobserved Heterogeneity in Panel Time Series Models. Mimeo, Oxford and NottinghamGoogle Scholar
Borner, S., Brunetti, A., Weder, B., 1995. Political Credibility and Economic Development. Macmillan, LondonGoogle Scholar
Borooah, V. K., Paldam, M., 2007. Why is the world short of democracy? A cross-country analysis of barriers to representative government. European Journal of Political Economy 23, 582604Google Scholar
Carmignani, F., 2003. Political instability, uncertainty and economics. Journal of Economic Surveys 17, 154Google Scholar
Cheibub, J. A., 1996. What makes democracies endure? Journal of Democracy 7, 3955Google Scholar
Chenery, H. B., Syrquin, M. 1975. Patterns of Development 1950–1970. Oxford University Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
Chenery, H., Srinivasan, T. N., eds. 1988. Handbook of Development Economics. Two volumes, North-Holland, AmsterdamGoogle Scholar
Christoffersen, H., Beyerler, M., Eichenberger, R., Nannested, P., Paldam, M., 2014. The Good Society. A Comparative Study of Denmark and Switzerland. Springer-Verlag, BerlinGoogle Scholar
Christoffersen, H., Paldam, M., 2006. Privatization in Denmark, 1980–2002. Chapter 4, pp. 117–40 in Köthenburger et al. (2006)Google Scholar
Clark, G., 2007. A Farewell to Alms: A Brief Economic History of the World. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colagrossi, M., Rossignoli, D., Maggioni, M. A., 2019. Does democracy cause growth? A meta-analysis of 2000 regressions. European Journal of Political Economy, https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2019.101824Google Scholar
Coppedge, M., Gerring, J., Knutsen, C. H., Lindberg, S., Teorell, J., Altman, D., Bernhard, M., Fish, M. S., Glyn, A., Hicken, A., Lührmann, A., Marquardt, K. L., McMann, K., Paxton, P., Pemstein, D., Seim, B., Sigman, R., Skaaning, S-E., Straton, J., Cornell, A., Gastaldi, L., Gjerløv, H., Mechkova, V., von Römer, J., Sundström, A., Tzeglov, E., Uberti, L., Wang, Y-t., Wig, T., Ziblatt, D., 2020. V-Dem Codebook v10. Varieties of Democracy (V-Dem Project). University of Gothenburg V-Dem InstituteGoogle Scholar
Diamond, J., 1997. Guns, Germs, and Steel: The Fates of Human Societies. Norton, New YorkGoogle Scholar
Ditzen, J., 2016. XTCD2: module to perform Pesaran’s (2015) test for weak cross sectional dependence in panel data. Available for download in StataGoogle Scholar
Doucouliagos, H., Paldam, M., 2009. The aid effectiveness literature. The sad result of 40 years of research. Journal of Economic Surveys 23, 433–61Google Scholar
Doucouliagos, H., Ulubaşoğlu, M. A., 2008. Democracy and economic growth: A meta-analysis. American Journal of Political Science 52, 6183Google Scholar
Durkin, J. T., Greely, A. M., 1991. A model of religious choice under uncertainty: On responding rationally to the nonrational. Rationality and Society 3, 178–96Google Scholar
Dutta, J., Aidt, T. S. eds., 2016. Corruption and Economic Development. The International Library of Critical Writings in Economics series, vol. 324, Edward Elgar, CheltenhamGoogle Scholar
Easterly, W., Kremer, M., Pritchett, L., Summers, L., 1993. Good policy or good luck? Country growth performance and temporary shocks. Journal of Monetary Economics 32, 459–83Google Scholar
Eberhardt, M., 2012. Estimating panel time series models with heterogeneous slopes. Stata Journal 12, 6171Google Scholar
Ekelund, R. B., Hébert, R. F., Tollison, R. D., 2006. Marketplace of Christianity. MIT Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
Engerman, S. L., Sokoloff, K. L., 2008. Debating the role of institutions in political and economic development: Theory, history, and findings. Annual Review of Political Science 11, 119–35Google Scholar
Fernández-Villaverde, J., Guerrón-Quintana, P., Kuester, K., Rubio-Ramírez, J., 2015. Fiscal volatility shocks and economic activity. American Economic Review 105, 3352–84Google Scholar
Finke, R., Iannaccone, L. R., 1993. Supply-side explanations for religious change. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 527 May, 2739CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frankel, J. A., Romer, D., 1999. Does trade cause growth? American Economic Review 89, 379–99CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fukuyama, F., 1992. The End of History and the Last Man. Many editionsGoogle Scholar
Galor, O., 2011. Unified Growth Theory. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJGoogle Scholar
Gavin, M., Hausmann, R., 1998. Macroeconomic volatility and economic development. Chapter 4, 97116 in Borner, S., Paldam, M., eds., 1998. The Political Dimensions of Economic Growth. Macmillan, London and New York, see also IDB(1995)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gollin, D., 2014. The Lewis Model: A 60-year retrospective. Journal of Economic Perspective 28(3), 7188Google Scholar
Gross, D., Steinherr, A., 2004, 2009. Economic Transition in Central and Eastern Europe: Planting the Seeds. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gründler, K., Krieger, T., 2016. Democracy and growth: Evidence from a machine-learning indicator. European Journal of Political Economy 45, 85107Google Scholar
Gründler, K., Potrafke, N., 2019. Corruption and economic growth: New empirical evidence. European Journal of Political Economy 60 article 101810CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gundlach, E., Paldam, M., 2009a. A farewell to critical junctures: Sorting out long-run causality of income and democracy. European Journal of Political Economy 25, 340–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gundlach, E., Paldam, M., 2009b. The transition of corruption: From poverty to honesty. Economic Letters 103, 146–48. Also chapter 27 in Dutta and Aidt (2016)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gundlach, E., Paldam, M., 2010. The agricultural, demographic and democratic transitions. Two estimation models with the reverse results. http://martin.paldam.dk/Papers/GT-Main/5-Three-transitions.pdfGoogle Scholar
Gundlach, E., Paldam, M., 2012. A model of the religious transition. Theoretical Economics Letters 2012, 419–22Google Scholar
Gundlach, E., Paldam, M., 2020. A hump-shaped transitional growth path as a general pattern of long-run development. Economic Systems 44(3) article 10825Google Scholar
Gutmann, J., Paldam, M., 2020. Four measures of corruption. Appendix 2 to Paldam (2021a)Google Scholar
Gwartney, J., Lawson, R., Block, W., 1996. Economic Freedom of the World: 1975–1995. Fraser Institute, Vancouver, B.C. First annual publication of the Fraser indexGoogle Scholar
Gwartney, J., Lawson, R., Grubel, H., de Haan, J., Sturm, J.-E., Zandberg, E., 2009. Economic Freedom of the World: 2009 Annual Report. Fraser Institute, VancouverGoogle Scholar
Gwartney, J., Lawson, R., Hall, J., Murphy, R., 2018. Economic Freedom of the World 2018 Annual Report. Fraser Institute, VancouverGoogle Scholar
Haan, J. de, 2007. Political institutions and economic growth reconsidered. Public Choice 131, 281–92Google Scholar
Haan, J.,de, Klomp, J., 2013. Conditional political budget cycles: A review of recent evidence. Public Choice 157, 387410Google Scholar
Hall, R. E., Jones, C. I., 1999. Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? Quarterly Journal of Economics 114, 83116Google Scholar
Harris, J. R., Todaro, M. T., 1970. Migration, unemployment and development: A two-sector analysis. American Economic Review 60, 126–42Google Scholar
Heidenheimer, A. J., Johnson, M., LeVine, V., eds., 1989. Political Corruption: A Handbook. Transaction Publishers, New Brunswick, NJGoogle Scholar
Hibbs, D. A. Jr., Olsson, O., 2004. Geography, biogeography, and why some countries are rich and others are poor. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States (PNAS) 101, 3715–74Google Scholar
Higgins, B., 1959. Economic Development. Principles, Problems, and Policies. Constable and Co., LondonGoogle Scholar
Iannaccone, L. R., 1998. Introduction to the economics of religion. Journal of Economic Literature 36, 1465–95Google Scholar
IDB, 1995. Overcoming volatility. Part 2 pp. 189–258 in Inter-American Development Bank, Economic and Social Progress in Latin America 1995 Report, see also Gavin and Hausmann (1998)Google Scholar
Inglehart, R., Basáñez, M., Díez-Medrano, J, Halman, L., Luijks, R., eds. 2004. Human Beliefs and Values. A Cross-cultural Sourcebook Based on the 1999-2002 Value Surveys. Siglo XXI Editiones, México DFGoogle Scholar
Inglehart, R., Basáñez, M., Moreno, A., eds. 1998. Human Values and Beliefs. A Cross-Cultural Sourcebook. Michigan University Press, Ann Arbor, MICrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, C. I., Vollrath, D., 2013. Introduction to Economic Growth. 3rd ed. WW Norton, New YorkGoogle Scholar
Jong-A-Pin, R., 2009. On the measurement of political instability and its impact on economic growth. European Journal of Political Economy 25, 1529Google Scholar
Kiszewski, A., Mellinger, A., Malaney, P., Spielman, A., Ehrlich, S., Sachs, J. D., 2004. A global index of the stability of malaria transmission based on the intrinsic properties of anopheline mosquito vectors. American Journal of Tropical Medicine and Hygiene 70, 486–98Google Scholar
Knack, S., 2002. Social capital and the quality of government: Evidence from the States. American Journal of Political Science 46, 772–85Google Scholar
Knack, S., Keefer, P., 1995. Institutions and economic performance: Cross-country tests using alternative institutional measures. Economics and Politics 7, 207–27Google Scholar
Köthenburger, M., Sinn, H.-W., Whalley, J., eds., 2006. Privatization Experiences in the European Union. MIT Press, Cambridge, MAGoogle Scholar
Kroeze, R., Vitória, A., Geltner, G., eds., 2018. Anticorruption in History. From Antiquity to the Modern Era. Oxford University Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
Krueger, A. O., 1974. The political economy of the rent-seeking society. The American Economic Review 64(3), 291303Google Scholar
Krueger, A. O., 1990. Government failures in development. Journal of Economic Perspectives 4(3), 923Google Scholar
Kuznets, S., 1965. Economic Growth and Structure. Essays 1954–64. Norton, New YorkGoogle Scholar
Kuznets, S., 1966. Modern Economic Growth. Yale University Press, New Haven, CTGoogle Scholar
Kuznets, S., 1968. Towards a Theory of Economic Growth. Yale University Press, New Haven, CTGoogle Scholar
Lambsdorff, J. G., 2007. Institutional Economics of Corruption and Reform. Theory, Evidence and Policy. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laursen, K., Paldam, M., 1982. The dynamics of the world’s income distribution 1955–2000. Nationaløkonomisk Nationaløkonomisk Tidsskrift, special issue, 135–46Google Scholar
Leff, N. H., 1964. Economic development through bureaucratic corruption. American Behavioral Scientist 8, 8-14, and in Heidenheimer et al. (1989), Chapter 24, 389–403, and Chapter 23, 553–59 in Dutta and Aidt (2016)Google Scholar
Lewandowski, P., 2007. ‘PESCADF’: Module to perform Pesaran’s CADF panel unit root test in presence of cross section dependence. Warsaw School of Economics, Institute for Structural Research, Poland.Google Scholar
Lewis, A., 1954. Economic development with unlimited supply of labour. The Manchester School 22, 139–91CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leys, C., 1965. What is the problem about corruption? Journal of Modern African Studies 3, 215–30, and in Heidenheimer et al. (1989), Chapter 5, 51–66Google Scholar
Lipford, J., McCormick, R. E., Tollison, R. D., 1993. Preaching matters. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 21, 235–50Google Scholar
Lipset, S. M., 1959. Some social requisites of democracy: Economic development and political legitimacy. American Political Science Review 53, 69105Google Scholar
Lipset, S. M., 1994. The social requisites of democracy revisited: 1993 presidential address. American Sociological Review 59, 122Google Scholar
Lucas, R. E. Jr., 2009. Trade and the diffusion of the Industrial Revolution. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 1, 125Google Scholar
Lundahl, M., Silé, R., 2005. Haiti: Nothing but failure. Chapter 14, 272301 in Lundahl, M., Wyzan, M. L., eds., 2005. The Political Economy of Reform Failure. Routledge, LondonGoogle Scholar
Maddison Project Database, version 2018. ggdc.net/maddison/maddison-project/home.htmGoogle Scholar
Maddison, A., 2001. The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective. OECD, ParisGoogle Scholar
Maddison, A., 2003. The World Economy: Historical Statistics. OECD, ParisCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malthus, T. R., 1798. An Essay on the Principle of Population. Many editions and reprintsGoogle Scholar
Marshall, M. G., Gurr, T. R., Jaggers, K., 2018. PolityTM IV project. Political Regime Characteristics and Transition. Dataset Users’ Manual. Center for Systemic Peace. Regular updates available from the Polity home pageGoogle Scholar
Masters, W. A., McMillan, M. S., 2001. Climate and scale in economic growth. Journal of Economic Growth 6, 167–86Google Scholar
McArthur, J. W., Sachs, J. D., 2001. Institutions and geography: Comment on Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson 2000. NBER Working Paper no. W8114.Google Scholar
McCleary, R. M., Barro, R. J., 2006. Religion and economy. Journal of Economic Perspectives 20, 4972Google Scholar
Megginson, W. L., Netter, J. F., 2001. From state to market: A survey of empirical studies on privatization. Journal of Economic Literature 49, 321–89Google Scholar
Méon, P.-G., Sekkat, K., 2005. Does corruption grease or sand the wheels of growth? Public Choice 122, 6997Google Scholar
Méon, P.-G., Weil, L., 2010. Is corruption an efficient grease? World Development 38, 244–59. Also chapter 24 in Dutta and Aidt (2016)Google Scholar
Murtin, F., Wacziarg, R., 2014. The democratic transition. Journal of Economic Growth 19, 141–81Google Scholar
Nannestad, P., Paldam, M., 1994. The VP-function: A survey of the literature on vote and popularity functions after 25 years. Public Choice 79, 213–45Google Scholar
Nannestad, P., Paldam, M., 1997. The grievance asymmetry revisited: A micro study of economic voting in Denmark, 1986–92. European Journal of Political Economy 13, 8199CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. C., 2005. Understanding the Process of Economic Change. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJGoogle Scholar
Nove, A., 1977. The Soviet Economic System. Allen & Unwin, LondonGoogle Scholar
Olsson, O., Hibbs Jr, D. A., 2005. Biogeography and long-run economic development. European Economic Review 49, 909–38CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Opfinger, M., 2011. Religious market theory vs. secularization: The role of religious diversity revisited. Department of Economics. Working paper, Leibniz University, HanoverGoogle Scholar
Paldam, E., Paldam, M., 2018. The political economy of churches in Denmark, 1300–2015. Public Choice 172, 443–63Google Scholar
Paldam, M., 1997. Dansk U-Landshjælp. Altruismens Politiske Økonomi. Aarhus Universitetsforlag, AarhusGoogle Scholar
Paldam, M., 2001. Corruption and religion. Adding to the economic model. Kyklos 54, 383414Google Scholar
Paldam, M., 2002a. The cross-country pattern of corruption: Economics, culture and the seesaw dynamics. European Journal of Political Economy 18, 215–40Google Scholar
Paldam, M., 2002b. Udviklingen i Rusland, Polen og Baltikum. Lys Forude efter Ændringen i det Økonomiske System. Aarhus University Press, AarhusGoogle Scholar
Paldam, M., 2009a. An essay on the Muslim Gap. Religiosity and the political system. Chapter 10, 213–42 in Wintrobe, R., Ferrero, M., eds. The Political Economy of Theocracy. Palgrave, New YorkGoogle Scholar
Paldam, M., 2009b. The macro perspective on generalized trust. Chapter 21, 354–78 in Svendsen, G. T., Svendsen, G. L. H., eds., 2009. Handbook of Social Capital. The Troika of Sociology, Political Science and Economics. Edward Elgar, CheltenhamGoogle Scholar
Paldam, M., 2013. The political economy of Dutch Disease – a survey. Chapter 10, 179–96 in Cabrillo, F., Puchades, M., eds., Constitutional Economics and Public Institutions. Edward Elgar, CheltenhamGoogle Scholar
Paldam, M., 2017a. The cycle of development in Africa: A story about the power of economic ideas. 497525 in Christensen, B. J., Kowalczyk, C., eds. Globalization. Strategies and Effects. Springer, BerlinGoogle Scholar
Paldam, M., 2017b. An economic perspective on the Reformation and the downscaling of the Church in Denmark, 1450–1650. Working paper available from martin.paldam.dk/GT-Religion.phpGoogle Scholar
Paldam, M., 2018. A model of the representative economist, as researcher and policy advisor. European Journal of Political Economy 54, 615Google Scholar
Paldam, M., 2020a. A study of triggering events. When do political regimes change? Public Choice 182, 181–99CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paldam, M., 2020b. The Democratic Transition – the Story of the Long run. Conference paper. Available from http://martin.paldam.dk/Papers/GT-Main/14-DemTrans.pdfGoogle Scholar
Paldam, M., 2021a. The transition of corruption. Institutions and dynamics. European Journal of Political Economy 67(2), article 101952Google Scholar
Paldam, M., 2021b. Measuring democracy. How Different Is the Polity and the V-Dem Indices? Pt. working paper. Available from http://martin.paldam.dk/Papers/GT-Main/15-V-Dem-Polity.pdfGoogle Scholar
Paldam, M., Gundlach, E., 2008. Two views on institutions and development: The Grand Transition vs the Primacy of Institutions. Kyklos 61, 65100Google Scholar
Paldam, M., Gundlach, E., 2012. The democratic transition: Short-run and long-run causality between income and the Gastil index. The European Journal of Development Research 24, 144–68Google Scholar
Paldam, M., Gundlach, E., 2013. The religious transition. A long-run perspective. Public Choice 156, 105–23Google Scholar
Paldam, M., Gundlach, E., 2018. Jumps into democracy. Integrating the short and long run in the democratic transition. Kyklos 71, 456–81Google Scholar
Parker, D., Saal, D., eds., 2003. International Handbook on Privatization. Edward Elgar, LondonGoogle Scholar
Pejovich, S., ed., 1997. The Economic Foundations of Property Rights. Selected Readings. Edward Elgar, CheltenhamGoogle Scholar
Pesaran, M. H., 2006. Estimation and inference in large heterogeneous panels with a multifactor error structure. Econometrica 74, 9671012Google Scholar
Pesaran, M. H., 2015. Testing weak cross-sectional dependence in large panels. Econometric Reviews 34, 10891117Google Scholar
Pesaran, M. H., Shin, Y., Smith, R. P., 1999. Pooled mean group estimation of dynamic heterogeneous panels. Journal of the American Statistical Association 94, 621–34Google Scholar
Pesaran, M. H., Smith, R. P., 1995. Estimating long-run relationships from dynamic heterogeneous panels. Journal of Econometrics 68, 79113Google Scholar
Pipes, R., 1999. Property & Freedom. Harvill Press, London Polity home page www.systemicpeace.org/polityproject.htmlGoogle Scholar
Pope, H., Pope, N., 2011 3rd ed. Turkey Unveiled: A History of Modern Turkey. Overlook Duckworth, New YorkGoogle Scholar
Puchades-Navarro, M., Montoro, J. D., 2009. Religious decline and public expenditure. Presented at the European Public Choice Society Meeting, AthensGoogle Scholar
Ranis, G., Fei, J. C. H., 1961. A theory of economic development. American Economic Review 51, 533–65Google Scholar
Rostow, W. W., 1960. The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
Solow, R. M., 1956. A contribution to the theory of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 70, 6594Google Scholar
Solow, R. M., 1970, 2000. Growth Theory. An Exposition. Oxford University Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
Soto, H. de, 2000. The Mystery of Capital. Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else. Black Swan Books, LondonGoogle Scholar
Stark, R., Iannaccone, L. R., 1994. A supply-side reinterpretation of the “secularization” of Europe. Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion 33, 230–52Google Scholar
Tanzi, V., 2018. Argentina, from Peron to Macri: An Economic Chronicle. Jorge Pinto Books, Bethesda, MDGoogle Scholar
Terwiel, B. J., 2011. Thailand’s Political History. From the 13th Century to Recent Times. 2nd ed., River Books, BangkokGoogle Scholar
Transparency International, the TI index www.transparency.org/Google Scholar
Treisman, D., 2000. The causes of corruption: A cross-national study. Journal of Public Economics 76, 399457Google Scholar
Ugur, M., 2014. Corruption’s direct effects on per‐capita income growth: A meta‐analysis. Journal of Economic Surveys 28(3), 472–90Google Scholar
Uslaner, E. M., 2002. The Moral Foundation of Trust. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
Weber, M., 1904/05. Die Protestantische Ethik und der “Geist” des Kapitalismus. Archiv für Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik 20, 154 and 21, 1–110. Many reprints and translationsGoogle Scholar
Wilson, C. A., 2000. Policy regimes and policy changes. Journal of Public Policy 20, 247–77Google Scholar
World Bank, 1995. Bureaucrats in Business: The Economics and Politics of Government Ownership. Oxford University Press, Washington, DCGoogle Scholar
WVS, World Values Survey, www.worldvaluessurvey.orgGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Martin Paldam, Aarhus Universitet, Denmark
  • Book: The Grand Pattern of Development and the Transition of Institutions
  • Online publication: 07 August 2021
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009025898.022
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Martin Paldam, Aarhus Universitet, Denmark
  • Book: The Grand Pattern of Development and the Transition of Institutions
  • Online publication: 07 August 2021
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009025898.022
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Martin Paldam, Aarhus Universitet, Denmark
  • Book: The Grand Pattern of Development and the Transition of Institutions
  • Online publication: 07 August 2021
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009025898.022
Available formats
×