Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-mlc7c Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-09T08:58:45.434Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

2 - Endogenous growth: lessons for and from economic history

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 January 2013

Kenneth F. Wallis
Affiliation:
University of Warwick
Get access

Summary

INTRODUCTION

In a survey of economic history written in the mid 1980s, I wrote that “economic history has had little influence upon and has been relatively little affected by growth theory of the postwar variety” (Crafts (1987, p. 40)). Clearly, growth accounting had been highly influential for measurement purposes but, at that point, for economic historians keen to understand productivity growth in terms of induced innovation or endogenous technological change, economic theory had little to offer, as the review of the well-known Habakkuk debate in David (1975) had made painfully obvious.

Since the mid 1980s, endogenous growth theory has developed very rapidly and has produced a large volume of theoretical research. At the core of these models is the proposition that investment in a broad sense, including human as well as physical capital and the production of new processes and products through research, is central to growth which can be driven on without being halted by diminishing returns.

One branch of endogenous growth theory obtains results by arguing for constant returns to routine investment in broad capital with the production function, Y = AǨ, as in Rebelo (1991). The key to rapid long-run growth is to be found in cultures, institutions, and tax policies which make a high rate of saving optimal. In this “capital-fundamentalist” approach there is no explicit role for total factor productivity (TFP), growth, or technological change. Despite the initial appeal of ideas of this kind, they are not persuasive as models of long-run growth. For example, cross-sectional regression evidence on the growth of GDP across countries (Mankiw, Romer and Weil (1992), Islam (1995)) and on output across British manufacturing sectors (Oulton and O‘Mahony (1994)) suggests that the sum of the exponents on physical and human capital in the production function is less than one and that there are diminishing returns to routine investment in the long run.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 1997

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×